A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE FACULTY OF GRADUATE STUDIES IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY calibrate PROGRAMME IN POLITICAL SCIENCE YORK university TORONTO, ONTARIO april 2005
THE make OF CUPE : STRUCTURE, DEMOCRACY AND CLASS FORMATION by
STEPHANIE ROSS
a dissertation submitted to the Facult
y of Graduate Studies of York Univer
sity in partial fulfillment of the
requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY © permission has been granted to : a ) YORK UNIVERSI
TY LIBRARIES to lend or sell copies of
this dissertation in newspaper, microfilm or elevation
ectronic formats, and b)
LIBRARY AND ARCHIVES
CANADA to reproduce, lend, distribute, or sell
copies of this dissertation anywhere in the
earth in microform, newspaper or electronic phase
ats and to authorize or procure the reproduction,
lend, distribution or sale of copes of this
dissertation anywhere in the world in microform,
paper or electronic formats. The author reserves early publication rights,
and neither the dissertation nor extensive
extracts from it may be printed or otherwi
se reproduced without the author’s written
permission .
v abstract This dissertation explores the nature and challenges
of democracy within unions through an historical
interrogation of the emergence and early years of the Canadian Union of Public Employees ( CUPE ). Formed by a amalgamation of two preexistent unions in
1963, CUPE casts new light on the Marxist, Michelsian
and Institutionalist theoretical approaches to union democ
racy. The thesis calls into question the narrow
and ahistorical link made between centralization,
oligarchy and effectiveness on the one hand, and
decentralization, democracy and ineffectiveness on the
other. Instead, the case of CUPE shows that
unions are subject to contradictory pressures and
that neither centralizat
ion nor decentralization is
inherently more democratic. Union democracy is separate of
an historical process of class formation, in which
both union purposes and the boundaries of the democratic
community (which can ma
ke legitimate claims
on members ’ solidarity and self-discip
line) are struggled over. As such, it is possible that decentralizing
forces can place narrow and sectionalist priorities over
the interests of the broader community. Moreover,
the thesis argues that the use of amalgamation as a method acting of forging greater
class unity is itself problematic.
The fusion which created CUPE involved a prolong struggle over which exemplar of union would prevail. The compromise which was reached entrenched a southeast
lf-reinforcing cycle of autonomy-seeking by union
locals which, over the long term, prevented the
development of an effective national union capable of
carrying out the democratic will of the membership as
a whole. As such, through an historical excavation of
the roots of contemporaneous crises in
CUPE, the thesis points to the im
portant way in which the outcomes of
past decisions come to structure future political
possibilities for unions and other social justice
organizations .
united states virgin islands dedication This thesis is dedicated to my father, John Ross.
A pipefitter and union member for most of his working
biography, he taught me more than he knows about the measure of
hard work and workers’ solidarity. Like so many
men of his generation, he spent his best energies work
ing for a better life for his child, and for that I am
everlastingly grateful. This thesis is par
tly the result of that better life, and
is therefore his achievement as well
as mine .
seven Acknowledgements A doctoral dissertation is thought of as an individual achiev
ement. Many hours are indeed spent
alone, facing the work and one
’s
own ambitions and fears. But like all such
endeavours, this dissertation was created in a social context of intellectual, political and
personal support, and for that many must be thanked. My supervisory committee, with whom I besides
took courses, made an enormous
contribution to my intellectual growth while at York
University. George Comninel, Graduate Director in my early y
ears in the Programme, provided
me with personal and institutional
subscribe at a time when I was distillery diffident whether I should be department of the interior
ng a Ph.D. Greg Albo skilfully helped navigate my immersion i
n
the trade coupling literature and kept me from
drowning in it. Leo Panitch, my supervisor, always expressed a boundless faith in
my
capacity to pull off this daunt visualize. That confidence wa
s at times dizzying, pointing to
apparently unachievable heights,
but
besides steadying, motivating me to work through the most difficu
lt times. I thank Leo not only
for an incredibly rigorous academi
c
prepare, but besides for modelling what it is to be a working-
class intellectual. His impact on the course of my life has been
boundlessly valuable to me. York University ’ south Graduate Programme in Political Science
provided a unique context in which to engage with debates about the
contemporary left, and the students and profe
ssors are amongst the most challengi
ng, sophisticated, and politically engaged
people I ’ ve touch. It was that rare cerebral community one
longs for in academia, against which I will measure all future
university experiences, and for that I am grateful. That community was besides extended to me at McMaster University ’ s Labour Studies Programme, where, while teaching, I wrote the last
several versions of the dissertation and received mentoring and
confirm. At both these institutions, I ’ d like to thank julian
Ammirante, Donna Baines, Marlea Clarke, Euan Gibb, Sam Gindin,
Deepika Grover, Peter Graefe, Shane Gunster, Steve and Judy
Hellman, Paula Hevia-Pacheco, Dann Hoxsey, Angela Joya,
Matina Karvellas, Geoff Kennedy, Samuel Knafo, Fuyuki
Kurasawa, Wayne Lewchuk, Roddy Loeppky, Marnie Lucas, Sara
Mayo, Di Paprica, Ginette Peters, Dennis Pilon, Chris R
oberts, John Saul, Mark Thomas
, Leandro Vergara-Camus, Sam
Vrankulj, Don Wells, Charlotte Yates, Noah Zerbe, all who m
ade real contributions to my
growth as a scholar and person.
At both York and McMaster University, Marlene Quesenberry and
Delia Hutchinson each provided
crucial support and resources,
and represent the way that administrative staff are the spinal column of the university. I thank metric ton
hem both warmly and unreservedly.
In the path of both union activism and research, I came in
to contact with many in CUPE whose experience and insight were
very important to me, and whose desire to
see CUPE’s history written down kept me goi
ng. In particular, thanks go to Gay Bell,
Fred Hahn, Helen Kennedy, David Kidd, Mary Catherine McCarthy
, and Steve Seaborn. As well, without the support of Morna
Ballantyne and Jane Stinson, and particularly Gil Levine, in helping me gain access to CUPE ’ mho documents in the National Archives of Canada, this dissertation could
never have been written, and I am appreciative.
Doctorates are personal journeys as we
ll, testing endurance and self-esteem. I have luckily always been surrounded by loving
friends and syndicate, who in countless ways gave me the inner force to continue. Pam Scholey and Michael Aylward ’ sulfur friendship has nourished me profoundly through thursday
is long process. Ernie Hrynyshyn
and Else Thorst, Maggie and Hugh-Derrick
Hiscocks have welcomed me into their syndicate and treated me
as their daughter. My own parents, Denise and John Ross,
sacrificed much to make this dissertation potential. T
heir unconditional love is my touchstone, and I thank them.
finally, thanks go to my collaborator, Derek Hrynyshyn. We me
t as graduate students and union activists, and the values and goals
we share sustain me. He has seen me through the entire proc
ess of researching and writing with great patience, wisdom, and
loving care. I am a better person with him in my
life, and for that I am profoundly grateful.
eight postpone of Contents abstract commitment Acknowledgements tilt of Abbreviations insertion : I. A narrative of Two Conventions II. Why CUPE ? The importance of Public Sector Unionism III. Why Public Sector Unionism ? New U
nderstandings of Democracy, Structure and
class formation IV. The structure of the argument V. Note on Method and Sources chapter 1 : Rethinking Union Democracy I : The Role of Leaders and Members I. The Union Democracy Literature : Lots of
Answers, but to the Right Questions?
II. Union democracy : subject to Definition ? III. Leaders : Representatives of the Workers ? IV. Members : The Font of Democracy ? V.
Conclusion: The Contradictory Pressures on Leaders and Members
chapter 2 : Rethinking Union Democracy
II: Union Functions, Structures and Class
constitution I. The Structuring Effects of Union Functions II. Union Structures : Built for democracy ? III. majority rule for Whom ? Defining and Creating the democratic Community IV. Conclusions chapter 3 : Contextualizing the Origins
of Canadian Public Sector Unionism
I. Canada ’ s ‘ Urban Boom ’ and the Emer
gence of Municipal Employment
II. municipal Workers in a Divided Labour Movement III. World War One and the Emergence of Municipal and Hydro Unionism IV. Depression, War, and the Evoluti
on of the Canadian Public Sector, 1929-1945
V. conclusion : The Ambivalent Ident
ities of Public Sector Workers
chapter 4 : The Emergence of National Unions in the canadian Public Sector I. The Post-War context : State, Law, and the Labour movement II. From CETU to NUPSE : The Dream of Expansion III. Courting the OHEU : autonomy comes to NUPSE IV. Locals Create a National Union : NUPE ’ s Municipal Unions and Local Autonomy page four vanadium six ten 1 1 6 9 13 17 21 21 26 39 45 49 57 57 67 77 83 87 89 103 107 129 139 142 145 152 164 170
nine V. ending : NUPSE and NUPE on the Eve of the Merger chapter 5 : The Merger Process and Union Democracy I : The Initial Blockages, 1956-1959 I. first Steps and Opening Positions : The foremost year of Merger Talks, 1956-57 II. jurisdictional Battles : Organizing
Hospital and Provincial Workers
III. OHEU and the Entrenchment of Autonomy IV. conclusion chapter 6 : The Merger Process and Union Democracy II : Establishing CUPE, 1960-1963 I. NUPE Does Some Soul Searching II. Shots Across the Bow : The Merger Talks of 1960-1962 III. Into the Home reach : 1962-1963 IV. Concluding the fusion : The 1963 CUPE Convention chapter 7 : The Limits and Contradictions
of CUPE Democracy I: Consolidating the
amalgamation, 1963-1967 I. “ A Dozen Praying Mantises ” : National Office Factionalism and Local Discontent, 1963-1965 II. Holding It All together : The 1965 conventionality III. exit Rintoul, Enter Hartman IV. conclusion chapter 8 : The Limits and Contradict
ions of CUPE Democracy II: The 1967 and 1969
Conventions I. Preparing for a Showdown II. CUPE ’ s ‘ Test of Fire ’ : The 1967 Convention and its consequence III. A Union or a Federation ? The National Defence Fund and Renewed Tensions over centralization, 1967-1969 IV. The 1969 convention : growth, Profe
ssionalization and Democratic Backlash
II. conclusion chapter 9 : Can the Union Make Us Str
ong? The Contradictions of Growth, 1969-1975
I. Servicing Union or Organizing Union ? II. “ Expecting the Per Capita to Perform
Miracles”: The Dilemmas of Balancing
Organizing and Servicing III. Feminizing CUPE : gender Challenges to Identity and Structure IV. The Problem of Democracy : Accountab
ility and Participation in a Growing Union
V. Financing Militancy : strike Waves,
Fight Backs, and the National Defence Fund
VI. New Members, New Structures, New I
dentities: Rethinking the Balance Between
local and Centre VII. stopping point : CUPE : Equipped to Face the Future ?
conclusion
I. Understanding CUPE II. Understanding Union Democracy, Uni
on Structure, and Class Formation
182 185 187 205 216 235 237 240 248 265 280 285 289 302 309 323 326 328 337 351 360 371 374 376 379 390 397 403 406 420 423 423 432
ten III. Understanding the political Implications bibliography 437 440
eleven list of Abbreviations AFL
american Federation of Labor ARTEC
Association of Radio and Television Employees of Canada BSEIU
Building Service Employees International Union CETU
Canadian Electrical Trade Union CCF
Cooperative Commonwealth Federation CCL
Canadian Congress of Labour CCS
Council of Chief Stewards CFCE
Canadian Federation of Civic Employees CFL
Canadian Federation of Labour CIO
Committee / Congress of Industrial Organizations CMA
Canadian Manufacturers ’ Association CPC
Communist Party of Canada ERP
Employee Representation Plan ( Ont
ario Hydro-Electric Power Commission)
GVP
General Vice-President HEPC
Ontario Hydro-Electric Power Commission BCHEU or HEU
British Columbia Hospital Employees ’ Union IBEW
International Brotherhood of Electrical Workers IDIA
Industrial Disputes Investigation Act IWW
Industrial Workers of the World JCC
Joint Consultation Committee LPP
Labour Progressive Party NDF
National Defence Fund NEB
National Executive Board NEC
National Executive Committee NOCUEW
National Organization of Civi
c, Utility and Electrical Workers
NUPE
National Union of Public Employees NUPSE
National Union of Public Service Employees OBU
One Big Union OCHU
Ontario Council of Hospital Unions OHEA or EA
Ontario Hydro Employees Association OHEU
Ontario Hydro Employees Union PSOC
Public Service Organizing Committee PUC
Public Utilities Council ( Toronto ) RVP
Regional Vice-President SPD
Sozialdemokratische Partei Deutschlands
/ Social Democratic Party of Germany
SWOC
Steelworkers ’ Organizing Committee
TLC
Trades and Labor Congress of Canada UAW
United Auto Workers USCS
Union of Saskatchewan Civil Servants VCEU
Vancouver Civic Employees Union
1 introduction I.
A Tale of Two Conventions
On the weekend of September 24, 1963, the Fo
rt Garry Hotel in Winnipeg was pervaded by a
palpable sense of history being made. Delegates a
ttending the founding convention of the Canadian Union
of Public Employees felt that what they were to decide over the next three days would forever transform the canadian labour campaign. Everything that surrounded
them pointed to this conclusion. Huge placards
and banners proclaimed that CUPE was to be ‘ one big
union’ representing an enormous array of public
sector workers. fraternal delegates from around the worl
d were present to witness the birth of a significant
new organization, the solution of what was hailed as deoxythymidine monophosphate
he first major post-war union merger in North America of
any significance. The speeches were steeped in the terminology of advancement and might, reflecting expectations of what would come through union of
the country’s two rival public sector unions, the
National Union of Public Employees ( NUPE ) and
the National Union of Public Service Employees
( NUPSE ), who had put aside sectionalism in the serv
ice of a broader vision of public sector workers’
interests. The choice of placement was no accident ei
ther. Winnipeg, the scene of
one of the most dramatic
events in canadian labor history and crucial in the development of municipal unionism, was a potent symbol of worker combativeness, one, and solidarity. T
he leaders of the new CUPE hoped that deliberating in a
place of such significance would aid in fosteri
ng a common identity amongst workers from disparate
occupational groups, who had built different coupling cultures and disconnected organizations, and who remained divided on their attitudes regarding lambert
abour-management relations and the type and role of
leadership and membership participati
on appropriate to the post-war era.
such ceremony at the founding consequence in an organi
zation’s history is not atypical, but in CUPE’s
encase it was possibly more necessity than usual. Given the astuteness and telescope of the differences between the two rear organizations, it was not a waive stopping point that the amalgamation would hold. An appreciation
2 of how flimsy the amalgamation was in 1963 can be gleaned from
how difficult it was to produce. The seven
years of negotiations were painstakingly slow and
often acrimonious, and had ground to halt on several
occasions between 1956 and 1963. The discussions were fraught with misinterpretation, intuition and shroud agendas. bankruptcy remained a possibility as delegates
were to vote on whether to accept the merger
agreement, with no possibility of amendment. several
important groups threatened to – and did – walk out
of the convention and the new marriage if the fusion
agreement could not be changed to accommodate their
needs. This discontent was merely the dramatic and
visible manifestation of a simmering dissatisfaction
with a amalgamation that seemed besides centralizing for thus
me, too decentralist for others, and that left open the
interview of precisely how compete visions of majority rule and potency would be balanced. For the architects of the fusion, it could not have been obv
ious that CUPE would eventually become the largest
coupling in Canada, and one of the most powerful, progr
essive and militant organizations of the Canadian
labor movement. I knew nothing of this history, of the fractious
basis of CUPE’s birth, when I attended my first CUPE
National Convention, held in Toronto in 1997. After five
years as an activist in the Ontario university sector,
and much like the delegates in 1963, I was intoxicated
with the potential of workers’ collective action and
thrilled to engage in an exert of multitude participator
y democracy. With over 2000 other local delegates
from across Canada in attendance, who shared my
commitment to unionism, I was overwhelmed and
proud, particularly when Bob White referred in his south
peech to a demonstration against cuts to unemployment
insurance in my home town in northerly New Brunswick. Another source of pride was my impression that CU
PE, unlike many other unions in North America,
afforded much quad for local enterprise, participati
on, and ultimate control by members via a democratic
commitment to local autonomy. For the most part, my
initial experiences in the teaching assistants’ Local
2323 at Carleton University confirm
ed these impressions: while national staff representatives assigned to
3 us advised a cautious dicker strategy, the local anesthetic was free to embark on a autonomous and unprecedented mobilization around what was, for the
early 1990s, a fairly radical bargaining agenda tying
wage increases to tuition increases. The National may
not have approved, but they did not indicate either a
desire or capacity to interfere with the local ’ s
internal decision-making process. Local autonomy,
understood as democratic control by the membership, wa
s to be respected. My warm feelings for CUPE
remained intact and were reinforced during my partici
pation in a training session for ‘member-organizers’,
in which we were explicitly instructed that CU
PE’s commitment to local autonomy was its ‘competitive
advantage ’ in organizing the unorganized. The National O
ffice, we as CUPE boosters were to proclaim to
prospective members, doesn ’ thyroxine tell anyone what to do,
since “we are not like Steel”. Nothing in my
feel in the union had yet led me to question these claims. Events at the 1997 National Convention disturbed
the assumptions I had internalized about the
democratic superiority of decentralized structures. It
became clear to me that the equation of localism with
democracy was debatable for many. Two notions of
democracy emerged in a conflict over raising the per
caput dues payment to the National, a conflict which, I was subsequently to learn, had been much rehearsed over the years. Those who advocated an increase in per
capita argued that the National Office would be
incapable of fulfilling the mandate democratically allocat
ed to it by the delegates without greater financial
resources. This miss of funds had dangerous implicati
ons for those newer, smaller, or more vulnerable locals
in especial, as they lacked the local resources to
carry out effective economic and political action and were
consequently more dependant on the National for suppor
t and services. These arguments struck me as
perfectly consistent with a notion of redistributiv
e democracy, or to quote Marx, “from each according to
their abilities, to each according to their needs. ”
For the most part, however, such appeals fell on the deaf
ears of an influential minority who maintained that any
attempt to centralize resources for whatever purpose
was to interfere with the autonomy and persuasiveness of loca
ls, and to risk “losing the money” in the labyrinth of
4 1
The original proposal was to increase per
capita from 0.7% of wages to 0.9%. The first vote was 1194 in favour, 718 opposed;
with only 62.4 % of the delegates assenting, the count was refe
rred back to the Constitution Committee. The proposal returned
with per head to be set at 0.85 % of wages, which passed
with 67.6% of the vote. The support of Local 1000, a strong
advocate of local autonomy, was pivotal : John Murphy, triiodothyronine
he local’s president, who had hotly argued against the original
increase, gave his local ’ mho accept to the lower measure. Ho
wever, the debate’s outcome was to have no impact on Local 1000
itself–its per head level has always been set by target
negotiation with the National, and not by National Convention.
an unaccountable bureaucracy. interestingly, this oppos
ition to centralization emanated from more self-
sufficient sections of the union, whose membersh
ip numbers and wage levels were able to support a
relatively effective local unionism for their members.
By preventing the attainment of the two-thirds majority
needed to make a constitutional change, this minority wa
s ultimately able to reduce the amount of (but not
stop wholly ) the per caput increase.
1
In the wake of this decision, and after hotly resisting the increase,
the Quebec delegating caucused to discuss whether it w
ould remain in CUPE, and the threat of a split hung
over the union. A second controversy at the 1997 Convention reveal
ed other differences not only over the meaning
of union democracy, but besides the institutional loca
tion of its defenders. Debates over whether CUPE’s
decision-making structures accurately represented the interests of a divers membership, and in particular of groups historically discriminated against, were comi
ng to a head. These concerns took the form of a
proposed built-in amendment to designate two s
eats on the National Executive Board, one for an
aboriginal Vice-President and another for a Visibl
e Minority Vice-President. Proponents, amongst whom
were big members of the home leadership and staff, argued that democracy required direct representation of distinct interests by mem
bers of underrepresented groups
themselves. Opponents,
including provincial leaders from the Maritimes and
leaders of large locals particularly defensive of
autonomy, argued that such measures
would violate norms of meritocra
cy. It struck me as particularly
ironic that those local leaders, who had earlier in the workweek positioned themselves as the guardians of majority rule, immediately vehemently opposed measures which woul
d, in some way at least, better reflect the
5 diversity of interests in the marriage, while the ‘ pitile
ss centralists’, national leaders, were fighting to expand
access to the highest levels of the union. Despite
the backing of powerful leader
s, the amendment failed to
get the needed two-thirds majority adenine well. Both these conventions partake a common storyline.
In each, a large, powerful minority made claims
rooted in a narrow-minded understand of the democratic consti
tuency to which they are accountable, in order to
stop to some extent decisions which would satisf
y the democratic will of a much larger community of
workers. In that sense, the 1963 Convention pref
igured the key political question to reappear in every
subsequent CUPE meet. The ever-present issue of wh
ich level of the union’s structure is most effective
and best expresses the democratic will of public southeast
ctor workers had been embedded in the substratum of
every conventionality debate, policy decision, or corporate
action. From its inception, CUPE’s structure has
been based on the principle that locals have ultimate c
ontrol over their own affairs, and that the power of
more central levels of the unions should be limited
to an absolute minimum. CUPE’s debates therefore
constantly pass through the prism of organizational exponent
– who has it, who doesn’t, who should and should
not. indeed, how a particular policy will affect the
relative distribution of power within CUPE – and in
particular the autonomy of locals – is a central criteri
on of decision-making in the union. Since a high level
of decentralization is equated with majority rule in CUPE, po
licies which involve centralization of any kind are
regarded with suspicion. While such debates are
not unique to CUPE, in few other unions are policy
questions so frequently determined by structural considerations. Whatever the cosmopolitan merits of the idea that
decentralization permits members to have direct
command over their immediate leaders and participate in decision-making, several things about the practice of union democracy became net to me in the run
of that week in 1997. First, a commitment to
decentralized structure could be sectionalist and frankincense more concern with protecting the relative prerogative of the few against the many than with preserve or
expanding ‘democratic control’. Second, one’s support
6 for ‘ democracy ’ could not plainly be read off one ’ s placement within the union structure. finally, there was more than one means to understand what constituted an ‘ effective ’ and ‘ democratic ’ union. With these counterfactuals in bridge player, I began to
explore the nature of union democracy and its
relationship to structure and to union potency at a
more theoretical level. My questions proliferated.
local anesthetic autonomy was surely a constraint on
the central leadership, but was it always a
democratic
constraint ? Was it truly the sheath that decent
ralized unions like CUPE were more ‘democratic’ than
relatively centralized ones ? Were ‘ effective ’ unions doomed to develop centralized, bureaucratic, and consequently undemocratic tendencies, and
decentralized, ‘democratic’ unions fated to be ineffective? Did
leaders inescapably act to maintain these oligarchies
against the interests of the members? Were these
members truly the repository of democracy, molarity
ilitancy, and progressiveness? What did democracy and
potency actually mean in a union context, anyhow ?
Was there some kind of transcendent criteria that
could be used to determine whether a union was democrati
c or effective, and if there was, would it be of
any virtual manipulation ? II. Why CUPE ? The importance of Public Sector Unionism I decided to pursue a detail examination of CU
PE’s origins in order to determine how the union
had developed both its social organization and cultural assumptions about the associate between decentralization and democracy. This seemed an important project for bot
h historical and theoretical reasons. First, public
sector unions like CUPE transformed the landscape of thymine
he labour movements in their respective countries.
In many respects, populace sector unions over the past
30 years have been at the centre of a politics that had
made the Canadian labour campaign active and progre
ssive. The dramatic growth of union membership
in public employment has kept union concentration far above the
levels it would be at if the movement’s centre of
gravity had remained in secret puerto rico
imary and secondary manufacturing. As such, public sector unionism,
7 2
Robert Laxer,
Canada’s Unions
(Toronto: James Lorimer and Company, 1976).
peculiarly in Canada, has helped labour movements stave off institutional collapse and maintain a meaning measure of social burden. second, the membership of public sector unions re
flects the large-scale feminization of the labour
military unit which occurred during the 1960s and 70s. As a result, they have provided thousands of women with their first major and sustained have of unionism and have become significant advocates for feminist and equity struggles in the workplace, political mho
phere, and the personal / cultural realm. CUPE in
particular was early on on a leader in the development
of a collective bargaining and legislative agenda aimed
at addressing the interests of women workers, and washington
s notable for its election in 1975 of Grace Hartman as
the first female president of a union on the north american continent. CUPE frankincense may have something authoritative to say about the processes by which the
“new working class” emerged and forged a collective
identity and feel of common interests, and about the ways in which unions can transform themselves to accommodate both oneness and deviation within their memberships. Third, in shifting the center of the canadian lambert
abour movement away from US-based international
unions, CUPE was cardinal to the emergence of a wave
of progressive, left nationalism in the 1970s which
put forward a democratic socialistic case for domesti
c control of both capital and the labour movement.
CUPE in particular was involved in struggles within the Canadian Labour Congress to impose significant guarantees of autonomy for canadian sect
ions of international unions.
2
As CUPE’s size and proportion of
organized workers grew, its advocacy within the CLC as a voice for mugwump canadian unionism leave subscribe for those wishing to escape the central control of internationals and prosecute strategies which addressed the needs of canadian workers. last, and linked to what distinguishes canadian
from US unionism, CUPE, like many other public
sector unions, has been all-important to the support and extens
ion of social unionism, in which unions struggle
8 3
Sam Gindin,
The Canadian Auto Workers: The Birth and Transformation of a Union
(Toronto: James Lorimer & Company
Publishers, 1995 ), 266 ; Ian Robinson, “ E
conomistic Unionism in Crisis: The
Origins, Consequences, and Prospects of
divergence in Labour-Movement
Characteristics,” in
The Challenge of Restructuring:
North American Labor Movements
Respond
, eds. J. Jenson and R. Mahon (Philadelphia: Temple U P, 1993), 21.
4
Robinson, 28-33.
5
Paul Johnston,
Success While Others Fail : Social Movement Unionism and the Public Workplace
(Ithaca, NY: ILR Press,
1994 ), 31, 40-1 ; Robinson, 32. 6
Robinson, 31-2.
7
Stephen Tufts, “Community Unionism in
Canada and Labor’s (Re)Organi
zation of Space,”
Antipode
30, no. 3 (1998): 228.
for the interests not only of their contiguous
membership but also the broader working class.
3
Ian Robinson
attributes the sustenance of social unionism in depart
to Canadian workers’ more active and lengthy struggle
for institutionalized labor rights during the Second Worl
d War, but also to the more important and dynamic
character played by populace sector unionism in Canada.
4
Indeed, from the 1960s on, social unionism has become
particularly associated with public sector unions, as their “ economistic ” collective dicker interests are inherently tied to public policy debates and consequently roentgen
equire political mobilization and coalition-building
around visions of what the state should do for the populace,
in ways that those of private sector unions do not.
5
The massive growth of canadian public sector unions
since the 1960s and 70s led to a “shift [in] the
libra of power from international to national unions
”, from private-sector to public-sector unions, and can
therefore explain why social unionism is now considered
to be a core value of the Canadian labour movement.
6
On the basis of this orientation course, CUPE has been a l
eader in the practice of community unionism, which
Steven Tufts defines as “ the formation of coalit
ions between unions and non-labor groups in order to
achieve common goals. ”
7
In particular, CUPE has conducted not
able campaigns against the privatization
of populace services, the proliferat
ion of free trade agreements which place public services in jeopardy, and in
support of protection and elongation of health wish, childcare, yield and employment equity, same-sex rights, international solidarity and anti-globalization struggles. These strategies adopted by CUPE are not only
9 8
Robinson, 36; Kim Moody,
Workers in a Lean World: Unions in the International Economy
(New York: Verso, 1997) ; Bruce
Nissen, “ Alternative Strategic Directions for deoxythymidine monophosphate
he U.S. Labor Movement: Recent Scholarship,”
Labor Studies Journal
28, no. 1
( spring 2003 ) : 133-155. 9
Craig Heron,
The Canadian Labour Movement: A Short History
(Toronto: James Lorimer and
Co., 1996), 94-98; Bryan Palmer,
wage-earning have : Rethinki
ng the History of Canadian Labour, 1800-1991
(Toronto: McLelland and Stewart, 1992), 320-
323 ; Desmond Morton,
Working People: An Illustrated History of the Canadian Labour Movement
, rev. ed. (Montreal: McGill-
queen ’ south University Press, 1998 ), 255-264. 10
Susan Crean,
Grace Hartman : A Woman for Her Time
(Vancouver: New Star Books, 1995); Patrick Lenihan,
Patrick Lenihan:
From irish Rebel to Founder of Canadian Public Sector Unionism,
ed. G.Levine (St John’s: Canadian Committee on Labour
History / Memorial University, 1998 ) ; John “ Lofty ” MacMillan,
The Boy from Port Hood: The Autobiography of John Francis “Lofty”
MacMillan
, with E. Hyslop and P. McGahan (Fredericton,
NB: New Ireland Press, 1996); Jim Pringle,
United We Stand: A History
of Winnipeg ’ s Civic Workers
(Winnipeg: Manitoba Labour Education Centre, 1991); Ed Thomas,
The Crest of the Mountain: The
resurrect of CUPE Local Five in Hamilton
(Hamilton: CUPE Local 5, n.d); Jerry White,
Hospital Strike: Women, Unions, and Public
Sector Conflict
(Toronto: Thompson Educational
Publishing, 1990); John Deverell, “The Ontario Hospital Dispute 1980-1981,”
Studies in political Economy
9 (1982): 179-190.
11
See my
Note on Methods and Sources
below.
widely held to be more effective than the traditional “ service model ” of unionism, but besides the only kind of unionism capable of countering the effects of neoli
beral globalization on workers and their communities.
8
Given the crucial contribution that CUPE has t
herefore made to the course of the Canadian labour
motion, not to mention its electric potential future, it is
surprising to find that nearly no academic work had been
conducted on the subject. Surveys of Canadian labour
history, though admitting the central role of public
sector unions, dedicate a very small part of their
pages to the subject of their origins, structures,
practices and distinct set about to unionism.
9
A few biographies of former leaders and staff, some local
union histories, and a few analyses of a peculiarly im
portant strike constitute the sum total of the
secondary literature on CUPE.
10
As such, a thorough excavation of CUPE’s origins and internal dynamics
would have to be undertaken from rub.
11
III. Why Public Sector Unionism ? New Understandings
of Democracy, Structure and Class Formation
Studying CUPE besides provides an opportunity to ex
plore some of the major theoretical questions
associated with the practice of unionism and its likely to provide a progressive and democratic footing for the expression of workers ’ interests. In particula
r, by exploring whether public sector unions like CUPE
have avoided the problems which plagued traditional industrial unions in the 20
th
century, namely the
10 12
Gary Chaison,
Union Mergers in Hard Times:
The View from Five Countries
(Ithaca / London: ILR Press / Cornell University
imperativeness, 1996 ). seeming contradiction between democracy and effectiv
eness, new light can be shed on the issue of union
democracy and its relation back to classify identity and solidarity.
This study explores this question by uncovering
and analysing the history of the take of CUPE. not to be ignored in CUPE ’ s story, and part of what it can add to our reason of union democracy, is the cardinal importanc
e of merger in its formation.
The merger process created a unique
conjuncture which reveals the key issues – usua
lly unstated assumptions – regarding the nature of
majority rule, bureaucracy, and leadership in the worki
ng class and its organizations. As well, examining
the consequence of CUPE ’ s amalgamation process allows us
to explore what kind of union a merger produces,
particularly in terms of the particular way that dem
ocracy and effectiveness are operationalized. Examining
this work is not merely of historical intere
st: it is central to understanding the possibilities and
implications of a key survival and growth scheme
now being used by unions around the world to respond to
membership worsen, maintain institutional viability and cope with the ever-increasing exponent of employers.
12
By examining how CUPE was marked by its own amalgamation
process, especially in terms of its impact on
internal office relations, identities, notions of comm
unity and mutual obligation, we may be able to evaluate
better the costs and benefits of fusion as
a contemporary union renewal strategy.
personal power considerations unquestionably info
rmed the merger negotiation process, and can
explain to some extent why certain individuals were
so attached to particular visions of the new union.
however, an exclusive focus on the personal ambitions of leaders serves to mask the more fundamental morphologic and cultural differences between NU
PSE and NUPE as a whole. Leaders wanted power for
reasons beyond personal aggrandizement or
mobility: they wanted to be in a position to bring to life the
kind of union they believed public sector workers needed.
Differences over union purpose and function, the
kind of union structure required to serve these pur
poses, ‘good’ leadership, and the appropriate place and
11 system of weights of the membership in decision-making were all
at play in the discussions. Viewed in this light, the
frequently agonizing and fiddling disputes over constitutional
provisions, the relative weight of representation,
per head levels and the types and numbers of appointed
staff are not mere technical details; rather, they
are political debates over the manner in which especial exponent relations should be institutionalized. In other words, the result of the fusion negotia
tions and fights over constitutional documents are
crystallizations of power, of a especial imagination of
the union’s identity, purpos
e, structure and internal
relationships, reflecting the relative weight of versatile
forces within the union at a given moment in time.
furthermore, these decisions were an crucial organizational moment in class geological formation, and indicate the framework within which public sector unionism has evolved. The union created by NUPE and NUPSE was marked by
the structures and practices of each
harbinger a well as the particular method used in its
formation. CUPE was a synthesis of two conflicting
visions of union purpose and structure. On the
one hand, leaders were able to construct a consensus
around the need for a potent central union with both
administrative and political power, and extensive
numbers of expert staff. On the other hand, the endur
ing strength of particularist local, regional and
sectoral identities within both unions meant that thyroxine
he political compromise needed to effect merger had to
entail the institutionalization of silicon
gnificant autonomy for local unions. This autonomy took the form of low
per head, the continued consumption of locally employed serv
icing staff, and voluntary membership in intermediate
union bodies, all of which placed constraints on the growth
of the national union’s servicing capacity, control
over locals, and ability to enforce its policies even when they had been demanded by the membership. The twin of a highly centralist imagination of the union and a structure which decentralized and fragmented political power produced a union load with negate
ory pressures and blocked full expression of either
logic. The first ten years of CUPE ’ sulfur being would t
hus be characterized by protracted internal battles for
laterality of one of these two models. however,
the outcome of these battles would always be
12 inconclusive, never overcoming the original fusion
compromise and resulting in a structure which could
provide neither the benefits of
centralization nor the democracy
promised by decentralization.
In that sense, CUPE demonstrates that the debat
e in the union as well as in the literature
mistakenly polarizes the relationship betw
een democracy and decentralization on the one hand, and
centralization and potency on the other. The degree centigrade
ounterposition of democracy versus effectiveness –
and the geomorphologic frameworks underst
ood to produce them – denies the way in which both interpenetrate
each early. ‘ Democracy ’ based on decentralize structures
may
allow for substantial membership
engagement and leadership accountability ; however, if
these structures are unable to carry out the
democratic will of the members, they are in important ways insufficiently democratic. On the other hand, the ‘ substitution ’ of leaders for the members ’ partici
pation can be insufficiently effective as well. The
engagement of members can be crucial in the process of meeting union objectives ( this has become particularly obvious since the collapse of the post-
war compromise); if the capacity to participate has
atrophied to such an extent that the union can not be defended or its objectives fought for, then centralization is limited in its potency. If, in the context of the fusion discussions, CUPE ’ s leaders and members had explored options which sought to comb
ine both more centralized forms of coordination
and broader collective identities with more substantive democratic processes, the union may have been able to create a structure which was both democratic and effective in meaningful ways. however, because understandings of democracy and effectiveness we
re so polarized around decentralization and
centralization, no such middle ground was always
explored and CUPE ended up being neither particularly
democratic nor effective .
13 IV. The social organization of the controversy Chapters 1 and 2 set out the major theoretical
perspectives on the issue of union democracy, and
explores its mean, supporting conditions and undermi
ning factors. In particular, I examine the
assumptions underlying Marxist, Michelsian and Institutionalist approaches. First, I argue that understandings of majority rule are rarely separate fr
om definitions of union functions and hence union
potency ; as such, it is significant to be sensit
ive to the interplay of means and ends both in theory and
in the notice of actual union processes. Se
cond, I point out that while unions may experience
knock-down tendencies towards oligarchy, these tendencie
s are not inevitable nor inherently vested in the
essential characteristics of either
leaders or members. Instead, ther
e are contradictory tendencies towards
both majority rule and oligarchy, which get worked out in
the process of concrete struggles and not always in
clear-cut ways. Third, I argue that union democra
cy and class formation should be understood as aspects
of the same historical work, and I attempt to
show how struggles over the question of democracy in
unions are actually a expression of the march of
defining the community with which one shares common
interests. ultimately, I show how the particular met
hod of class formation – in this case organizational
union through the procedure of fusion – has majo
r implications for the way that union democracy and
effectiveness are institutionalized. In Chapter 3, I contextualize the origins of C
anadian public sector unionism as it emerged at the
local charge in the early 20
th
century. In particular, the contours
of municipal employee class consciousness
and unionism were shaped by the complex interaction
of municipal employers’ structures, on the one hand,
and ideological and political debates within the labor
movement about the appropriate model of unionism
on the early. The disconnected nature and
paternalistic strategies of public employers in this period served
to construct municipal workers ’ identities, intere
sts and organizations in narrow ways, often reinforced by
the dominance of a craft exemplary of unionism in equality
ticular areas. However, processes of employer
14 rationalization and bureaucratization, along with the infl
uence of industrial or nationalist forms of unionism,
did produce amongst some elements a broader consci
ousness of workers’ interests and a desire to
construct organizational forms that would express tho
e interests. Public employees in general emerged
from this period with ambivalent class identities,
but coalescing around two major visions of union purpose,
structure, and internal democracy. chapter 4 explores in detail thymine
he nature of these two major alignments as they further developed
and were expressed in institutional form thr
ough the 1950s. Although all municipal workers faced
centralize and professionalize pressures emanati
ng from both the state and
the north american labor bowel movement, unlike groups ’ responses to such pressu
res were mediated by the traditions and visions set
up in the former time period. In cosmopolitan, populace
sector workers converged around a centralized and
decentralized vision of unionism, each characterised by
distinct methods of integration, types and
expectations of leaders, and understandings of the ro
le of members in deciding and acting on their
interests. The organizational expressions of these two
visions were the National Union of Public Service
Employees and the National Union of Public Employ
ees respectively. Although each experienced internal
debates over what constituted effective unionism
and what relationship between leaders and members
would best allow for that, a detail sight was hegemonic within each union. however, important contradictions within the processes of fusion used
by each served to place limits on the extent of class
formation and the rehearse of democracy at the center, and
would later result in major conflicts over identity,
functions, structures and inner democracy when thymine
he two organizations undertook to merge in the mid-
1950s. chapter 5 charts the beginnings of that amalgamation process, and explores the major barriers encountered in combining two different structures
and visions of democracy within one organization. In
particular, and through the tangle of details about procedur
es, jurisdictions, the definition and distribution of
15 leadership positions, I show how two competing understandi
ngs of democracy were in fact at issue. The
foremost conception was broad and based on whether the subs
tantive outcomes of a process met the interests
of a broadly-defined community of public sector
workers. This was opposed by a more narrow and
proceduralist understand in which
the representation of pre-exis
ting identities defined whether an result was democratic. Since these views
were present within both NUPSE and NUPE, each had
factions which worked to block the development of me
rger terms that would satisfy the claims of broader
democratic constituencies at the expense of more narrowly form ones. Each union was consequently required to renegotiate with its major home facti
ons the basis of unity, the relationship between local and
center, the balance between finical and general interests
in order to be suitable to the other as a merger
partner. In this chapter, the focus is on NUPSE ’ s
negotiations with the major proponent of local autonomy
within its midst, the Ontario Hydro Employees Un
ion. Although the basis of autonomy-seeking in NUPSE
was never eliminated, it was contained sufficiently to make for a relatively centralize and mix union. NUPE ’ s attempts to make itself acceptable to
NUPSE as well as deal with the pressures for
professionalization and serve in the context of a
very decentralized union form the main substance of
chapter 6. here, the contradictions between t
he membership’s desire for more services and its
unwillingness to provide greater fiscal and political res
ources to the centre worked to construct a self-
reinforcing hertz of autonomy. The traditions of autonom
y placed limits on the extent of centralization and
worked to build up other levels of the union as the
source of both servicing and claims for democratic
autonomy. NUPE ’ second failure to unify sufficiently at the cytosine
entral level forced it to make compromises over who
would lead the newfangled union in order to achieve broader
class unity in the public sector. However, the
continue resistance of autonomist forces within bot
h unions resulted in a centralist leader from NUPSE
being placed at the forefront of a profoundly decentra
lized organization in the tradition of NUPE.
16 consequently, a coupling premised upon aggressive expans
ion and central professionalized servicing
possessed a structure which reinforced localism. chapter 7 explores the immediate implications of
this contradictory outcome, and looks at how the
unsolved issues of the amalgamation continued to be st
ruggled over within the newly formed Canadian Union of
public Employees. here we see how a complex interaction of factionalism and decentralization both blocked significant accumulation of power at the centre, but besides produced undemocratic dynamics based on the hope to ‘ absolve ’ central leaders from the in
fluence of powerful locals who retained control over
membership dues. Although greater centralization in some
areas did proceed in the first four years of the
union, this did not importantly alter the narro
w understandings of democracy rooted in local unionism.
The consequence of factional disputes and metric ton
he manner in which the union was subsequently
consolidated is cover with in chapter 8. hera, I di
scuss the long-term formative impact that the bitterly
contested election of 1967 had on the practice of
democracy in CUPE. Rather than permitting the
circulation of elites, factionalism set off an all-out washington
r for control in which the norms of democratic practice
were ignored. This reinforce locals ’ suspicions of
the central leadership, entrenched their association of
local autonomy with majority rule, and made them reluct
ant to permit further centralization. Locals’
cover obstruction of centralization fostered a drawing card
ship view that they had to work to release
themselves from the constraints of membership over
sight so as to serve the interests of public sector
workers by rights. The outcomes of these renewed battles over centralization versus decentralization further entrenched the cycle of autonomy
and made it very difficult for CUPE to cope with the implications
of continue growth, changing membership demographi
cs and occupational identities, changing employer
structures and strategies, and the necessitate for combativeness. chapter 9 discusses in contingent how CUPE ’ s consoli
dation of the union on the basis of a narrow and
autonomist understand of democracy made it difficult to face the challenges of emergence, servicing ,
17 organizing, integration of modern members, deepeni
ng democratic accountability and participation, and
sustaining combativeness. In the period between 1971
and 1975, both the effectiveness and the democratic
basis of the local autonomy structure was brought into
question, in that the union was constrained in its
ability to meet the goals of its increasingly divers
membership. In particular, CUPE showed itself unable
to think through the implications of size for the public relations
actice of democracy; while it has centralized important
functions it did not construct decision-making processe
s that would allow workers to democratically define
and act on the interests of “ public sector workers ” as a solid. V. Note on Method and Sources CUPE ’ s organizational structure presents the resear
cher with more than an interesting theoretical
and empiric puzzle. Its decentralized, many-sided
nature presents methodological challenges as well.
The diverseness of experiences along sectoral and regional
lines, for instance, makes the construction of an
overarching narrative slightly diffi
cult. While there is a practical need to focus on particular sectors,
locals, or activists, this work aims at underst
anding the general dynamics which structure the union’s
inner political relationships, and as a resultant role deoxythymidine monophosphate
he possibilities and limits encountered by sub-units of the
unions. Although, as we shall see, there is variati
on in the extent to which locals benefit from local
autonomy, there is no doubt that
the particular way that local autonomy has been built into CUPE’s
structure has a brawny determining effect on local anesthetic union
action. As a result, the emphasis is on the major
debates over the meaning and practice of local autonomy
(and the way this has been articulated in terms of
democratic and effective unionism ) which are most visible at the national degree. This project is an in-depth case learn of one union at
a formative moment in its history. It provides
a detailed analysis of debates within a detail uni
on which touch on several key theoretical questions
about union democracy, bureaucracy, structure and one hundred fifty
ass identity. This approach has been adopted for
18 13
E.P. Thompson,
The Making of the English Working Class
(London: Penguin, 1963), 8.
three chief reasons. first, as has been mentioned, t
here has been little historical analysis of the origins
and central dynamics of CUPE, and as such historic
al documentation is intrinsically valuable.
Second, however, is the desire to demonstrate in
the case of CUPE the oper
ation of the historical
materialist penetration that people make history, but not
under conditions of their own choosing. Only by
examining the active attempts by public sector
workers and their union leaders to forge an organization
which would express a common set of interests and
identity, uncovering how debates over democracy and
structure were settled, and analysing how those decisions subsequently shaped much of CUPE ’ s future development can we understand the crucial
moments in the process of class formation. It is useful to refer,
as the deed of the dissertation does, to E.P. Thompson ’ s celebrated work,
The Making of the English Working
classify
. His emphasis, like mine, is on “making”, on the hi
storical process in which people actively intervene
to define themselves, their community of interest, and t
heir institutional and cultural expressions. Class, as
well as the organizational expressions of concrete solve
ing classes, “evades analysis if we attempt to stop it
dead at any given moment and anatomize
its structure. The finest-meshed sociological net cannot give us
a pure specimen of class, any more than it can give us one of deference or of love. ”
13
So it is with CUPE: in
order to understand its show, we must understand how
that present is the product of a set of earlier
struggles. Third, focus on the history of a finical case
allows us to ask questions of the conventional
wisdom which has grown up around the theoretical and
political questions concerning the nature of unions
as organizations. As such, this research is pres
ented against the backdrop of other historical analyses of
major canadian and other unions, upon which certain
theoretical generalizations about democracy and
social organization have been based. As Barrington Moore argues, it
is important to conduct history in a comparative
context, so that cases “ can serve as a uncut negat
ive check on accepted historical explanations” and
19 14
Barrington Moore,
The Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy
(New York: Penguin, 1966), x.
15
Ibid., xi.
16
David Harvey,
The Limits to Capital
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1989), 2.
possibly even “ lead to new diachronic generalizations. ”
14
In this process, the detailed case study is important
if sometimes confusing. In explaining the relati
onship between detailed histor
ical study and comparative
generalization, Moore describes we
ll the experience of researching and writing this dissertation:
Generalizations that are sound resemble a large-scale
map of an extended terrain, such as an airplane pilot
might use in crossing a continent. such maps are einsteinium
ential for certain purposes just as more detailed maps
are necessity for others. No one seek
ing a preliminary orientation to the terrain wants to know the location
of every family and pathway. hush, if one explores on
foot – and at present the
comparative historian does
precisely that a great deal of the time – the details
are what one learns first.
Their meaning and relationship
emerges merely gradually. There can be l
ong periods when the investigator f
eels lost in an underbrush of facts
inhabited by specialists engaged in savage disputes about
whether the underbrush is a pine forest or a
tropical jungle.
15
however, through this work, one gathers together t
he material out of which broader generalizations can
be made or disconfirmed. Although not presenting respective comparative character st
udies in the way that Moore did, this work
does contribute to the possibility of conducting future such work on the major unions in the canadian labor bowel movement. For the present moment, however, a det
ailed look at CUPE’s formation opens one window of
many possible windows on the subjugate of union structur
e and formation. David Harvey, in describing Marx’s
methodological scheme in
Capital
, provides us with another image that frames the methodological choices
made here. CUPE is one of many “ windows ” through wh
ich one can look to see the “inner structure” of
things ; “ [ thyroxine ] he view from any one window is bland and
lacks perspective. When we move to another window
we can see things that were once hidden from horizon
. Armed with that knowledge, we can reinterpret and
reconstitute our sympathy of what we saw thursday
rough the first window, giving it greater depth and
position. By moving from window to window and care
fully recording what we see,” we come closer to
understanding the whole.
16
Although the sojourn at CUPE ’ second windowpane is
long, it is nonetheless spent in the
hope that it contributes to better theory and triiodothyronine
he anticipation of views from other windows.
20 The core of the dissertation is based on elementary massachusetts
terials drawn from the Canadian Union of Public
Employees Fonds ( MG 28, I234 ) located at the Na
tional Archives of Canada (NAC). These documents
include executive board minutes, parallelism, repor
ts, convention proceedings, and other materials
from CUPE and its harbinger unions, NUPE and NUPSE.
Full information on the author, title and
specific placement ( volume and File ) are included in the
footnote when the document is first used. As well,
personal interviews were conducted with Kealey Cummings and Gilbert Levine, both key protagonists in CUPE ’ s formative years, and among the few remaining Na
tional leaders from that time who are still alive.
These interviews are supplemented by authoritative
biographies and autobiographies of CUPE leaders who
have either died or were not available for consultation .
21 1
Goran Therborn,
Science, Class, and Society: On the Format
ion of Sociology and Historical Materialism
(London: Verso, 1976),
71. chapter 1 : Rethinking Union Democracy I : The Role of Leaders and Members I.
The Union Democracy Literature: Lots of
Answers, but to the Right Questions?
The ‘ literature ’ on union democracy and bureaucracy
encompasses work from the past 150 years.
however, what one encounters is less a chiseled body of
work but rather a series
of distinct ‘literatures’,
each about working course organizations at a different st
age in their historical development, and each with its
own political-economic context and ideological assump
tions. As a result, not only do the questions deemed
relevant to explore exchange with each group of writers,
so too does the object of study, the union itself.
Sorting through these disparate ‘ sub-
literatures’ in search of what
Goran Therborn has called a “ social radiation pattern of determination ”
1
of union structure and functioning is a frustrating task. This is especially true
when one seeks to understand the inner logic of a particu
lar tradition. It is easy to get trapped within a
particular paradigm ’ randomness underlying assumptions and expl
anatory framework, to lose sight of one’s own
questions and to neglect to interrogate each tradition in term
s of what it may offer – or fail to offer – to an
understanding of a concrete working course organization.
This, however, is precisely what is needed if the
insights and limitations of the literature on craft union democracy ar
e to be appreciated and transcended.
rather than exploring what each ‘ custom ’ in
its turn has to say about trade unionism, and then
attempting to extrapolate what answers might be giv
en to the concrete dilemmas of CUPE with which I
have been struggling, I have opted to let my questions
structure the discussion, and explore if and how they
have been handled. This method of presentation serves
not only to eliminate tangential discussions which
do not bear on the CUPE feel, but besides to place the assorted positions in lead debate with each other. In such a presentation, the contributi
ons and absences of each tradition become clear, and the
areas of consensus and argument more obvious,
forming the groundwork on which my own critical
appraisal and analytic approach can be stated .
22 2
In the English language, at least, Richard Hyman,
Marxism and the Sociology of Trade Unionism
(London: Pluto Press, 1971),
John Kelly,
Trade Unions and Socialist Politics
(London: Verso, 1988), and Leo Panitch,
Working Class Politics in Crisis: Essays
on Labour and the State
(London: Verso, 1986) are the major exceptions.
While there is some overlap, there are three im
portant and distinct traditions which have dealt with
the issues of union democracy, structure and functions. Marxists were the first to have taken a unplayful interest in the organizations of the working class in
terms of their potential for transforming capitalist
company. For them, craft unions are an significant part
of understanding the process of
class formation, both in the abstract and the concrete. however, there
has historically been a definite gap between the Marxist
claim that craft unions form the basis on which revolutionary class consciousness and a democratic socialist company can be built, and the more reformer
and accommodative record of ‘actually existing’ trade
unionism. Marxists have consequently found it necessity to grapple with the reasons for this discrepancy. With their focus on whether, how and why deal unions might impede the working class from becoming revolutionist, the question of democracy per selenium in
workers’ organizations has often been secondary, or
assumed to be implicit in in revolutionary politics. There is a surprising dearth of theoretical work on the concrete structures and dynamics of trade unionism from a marxist position, particularly given the centrality of the working class in their political vision.
2
The marxist literature on the trade unions thus
seems to be beside the point for a discussion of
union democracy. It is not, however, for in their attemp
ts to explain why the working classes in the West
have not promulgated revolutions, Marxists have dev
eloped an analysis of the internal politics of unions
which reveals a distinct impression of democracy, it
s supposed connection to revolutionary politics, and the
conditions prevent its emergence. The long-standing Ma
rxist analysis of the material bases of bureaucratic
leadership is one of this tradition ’ s most authoritative and influential contributions to the discipline. Marxists, such as Gramsci, stressed the non-hegemonic nature
of the trade union as a product of capitalist
production relations ; having internalized the divisions in
capitalist social structure, trade unions are unable
23 to fulfil the working class ’ democratic and hegemonic pot
ential. There is also an important set of debates
about home majority rule in party life, beginning with the exchanges of Lenin, Luxemburg and Trotsky, which contain significant insights. These views cont
inue to have a contemporary relevance, as they find
expression in the political practice of many labour
movement activists, both those who are members of
socialistic organizations angstrom well as those involved in
the rank and file movements for internal union
majority rule. In the academic mainstream, Robert Michels ’ atte
mpt to understand the workings of power in trade
unions has been highly influential, becoming a mainstay
of mid-twentieth century orthodox industrial
relations literature. Combining insights from W
eber, elite theory and socialist-anarchist perspectives,
Michels ’ best sleep together work,
Political Parties
:
A Sociological Study of the Emergence of Leadership, the
psychology of Power, and the Oligarchic Tendencies of Organization
, is a compelling
prima facie
case for
the inevitable emergence of undemocratic rehearse
s and reformist politics even within socialist
organizations apparently committed to the democratiza
tion and revolutionary alteration of capitalist social
relations. The detailed descriptions Michels provi
des of the inner workings of the German Social
democratic Party ( SPD ) are disturbingly familiar to
those who have participated in workers’ and socialist
organizations, and have convinced many of their universal
validity. As such, his account, rather than the
marxist literature, has been established as the starti
ng point in nearly all academic discussions of union
democracy over the by century, and as such must be engaged. It is unmanageable to nail down precisely who should be grouped in the Michelsian custom, as its charm is thus wide. however, the unite thread is an emphas
is on the factors which sustain oligarchy. Seymour
Martin Lipset provides a methodological criterion :
he argues that this group consists of those who seek
merely to extend Michels by describing concrete oli
garchical practices in a variety of unions, but not by
24 3
Seymour Martin Lipset, “The Political Proce
ss in Trade Unions: A Theoretical Statement” in
Labor and Trade Unionism: an
interdisciplinary Reader
, eds. W. Galenson and S.M Lipset (N
ew York: John Wiley and Sons, 1960), 216.
4
Joel Seidman,
Union Rights and Union Duties
(New York: Harcourt Brace and Co., 1943), 20-51.
5
Mark Leier,
Red Flags and Red Tape: the Making of a Labour Bureaucracy
(Toronto: University of
Toronto Press, 1995), 16-19;
180. 6
Frances Fox Piven and Richard Cloward,
Poor People’s Movements: How They Succeed, Why They Fail
(New York: Vintage,
1979 ), xx-xxi. “ developing a sic of propositions which can be tested by research. ”
3
Joel Seidman’s work, which involves
an exhaustive and detailed list of U.S. union leadership
transgressions against their members, is illustrative
of this overture.
4
A deep-seated pessimism about the possibility of democracy in large organizations gives
oneness to the Michelsian perspective, and as such encompasses those on both the right and the leave. Mark Leier ’ sulfur work is a beneficial exemplar of a leftist Michelsian : while clearly influenced by socialist anarchism and bolshevik theories of the parturiency gentry, his anal
ysis of internal union dynamics follows Michels very
closely, with the exception of the latter ’ mho united states virgin islands
ews on the character and role of the membership.
5
Similarly,
Frances Fox Piven and Richard Cloward, in their important cultivate
Poor People’s Movements: Why They
Succeed, How They Fail
, argue that attempts to institutionalize economic and political resources for the
“ lower classes ” by creating “ master of arts
ss-based, permanent organization” are doomed to fail in these aims. For
Piven and Cloward, it is the moment of gra
ssroots insurgency which is genuinely oppositional; the
organizations which emerge in the context of in
surgency inevitably abandon their oppositional politics and
become “ more useful to those who control the re
sources on which they depend than to the lower-class
groups which the organizations claim to represent. ”
6
A third base approach is Institutionalism, which had an initial and early formulation in the work of Sidney and Beatrice Webb, but became established as a full-fledged paradigm in the 1950s and 60s under the influence of U.S. behaviouralist social skill. C
oncerned with what was perceived as the growing power
of trade unions in post-war american animation, institutionalists sought to understand the nature, sources and implications of that ability for company in general. Most
of the work in this third perspective is characterised
25 7
Judith Stepan-Norris, “The Making of Union Democracy,”
Social Forces
76, no. 2 (1997): 476.
8
Maurice Zeitlin and Judith Stepan-Norris, “The Insurgent Origins of Democracy,” in
Reexamining Democracy: Essays in Honor
of S.M. Lipset
, eds. G. Marks and L. Diamond (London: Sage, 1992), 253.
by detail empiric study, and aims to uncover metric ton
he factors in union structure and function which support
democracy ( rather than oligarchy ). The influence of bot
h Weber and Michels is clear in this work, but most
deviate from a rigid Michelsian view in one of a number
of ways. Some do not share Michels’ views about
the problem of reformism ; others do not necessar
ily equate bureaucracy with oligarchy; still others do not
believe that oligarchy itself is inevitable ; and fina
lly, some do not find the emergence of oligarchy at all
debatable. There is, therefore, much variation in this liter
ature, making it somewhat difficult to organize or
relegate. In her inspection of this literature, Stepan-Norr
is offers a scheme of classification which identifies two
camps : the “ legalists ” and the “ behaviouralists ”.
Legalists place emphasis on unions’ formal internal
structures, like constitutions, leadership powers, hundred and one
vil and political rights of members, and the rights of
minority groups.
7
Insofar as union democracy is possible,
it is via institutional arrangements which
memberships place an effective check on oligarchic
power. Legalists tend to set out their ‘ideal model’ of
democratic unionism, and then assess the extent to whic
h actually existing unions conform to or diverge
from that model. The influence of the Webbs, Edelstei
n and Warner, Cook, and Leiserson in particular focuses
on these concerns. Behaviouralists, on the early hand, examine the alternating current
tual practices of union leaders and members, on
the assumption that constitutions do not constantly
reflect what people in organizations actually do.
8
By
looking at demeanor, these works typically attemp
t to develop testable propositions and generalizations
about inner marriage dynamics. In many ways, this work
is an attempt to put Michels to the ‘social scientific’
screen, to see whether and under what conditions his propos
itions hold up. Seymour Martin Lipset is the most
celebrated member of this group ; beginning with
Union Democracy: The Internal Politics of the ITU
, he ( along
26 9
John Hemingway,
Conflict and Democracy: Studies in Trade Union Government
(London: Clarendon, 1978), 1.
10
David Held,
Models of Democracy
, 2
nd
ed. (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1996), 2.
with Coleman and Trow ) endeavoured to find the conditions under which democracy is made possible and can be sustained. He concludes that Michels was not
entirely correct in that not every union will produce
an oligarchy ; however, he argues that the few unions
that possess the conditions necessary to sustain
majority rule are the exceptions which prove the dominion. A third group of institutionalists should be added to
Stepan-Norris’ classification which we might call
“ managerialists ”. In this group, the question of union dem
ocracy is rather beside the point. Instead, their
goal is to determine the conditions and morphologic arr
angements which will best allow unions to perform their
functions efficaciously and responsibly. Most of these
commentators argue that it is worthwhile to give up
inner democracy if it means that unions will be bette
r able to defend the interests of their members, most
frequently understood in economic terms. democratic cont
rol by the rank and file is only an issue if it is
needed to restrain a root leadership.
9
The works of John Commons, Magrath, Hoxie, and Lester are
outstanding examples of this approach. With this feel of the general terrain of the literature on coupling majority rule, we turn now to examine in more detail the ways in which democracy and its oppos
ite, oligarchy, are variously defined within it.
II.
Union Democracy: Subject to Definition?
It is important to begin with some exploration of
what is meant by “union democracy”, if we are to
grasp the conditions under which it is created, sustained and undermined. It is broadly accepted that democracy, at its most basic, is a especial
process
of collective decision-making or rule-making in which
the integral community, ‘ the people ’, participates. however, as David Held points out, there is little consensus beyond this rather obscure formulation ; in fa
ct the “scope for disagreement” is quite vast on each
element of this definition.
10
As in the arguments over how to organize
the political life of entire societies, the
27 11
Edmund Ions, “Oligarchy,” in
The Blackwell Encyclopaedia of Political Science
, ed. V. Bogdanor (London: Blackwell, 1991),
391. argument over the mean of union democra
cy, and the structures and practices implied, is characterised by
hearty discrepancy. Definitions of union dem
ocracy usually address the question of who exactly
participates, how and when they do therefore, and in what kinds of decisions. They much besides specify the conditions – economic, legal-institutional, or cultural –
which make this participation possible and effective.
The diverse answers to such questions result in an a
rray of other controversies over whether democracy in
unions at present exists, is desirable, or is flush potential. furthermore, all process-based definitions of
union democracy are in fact linked to the
content
of
decisions made, to the result of the democratic proce
ss. Whether implicit or explicit, all definitions of
coupling majority rule have as a standard some notion of the carbon
haracter of workers’ true interests. Since it is
broadly agreed that unions should be designed to serve
workers, assumptions about the latter’s essential
interests define what the genuine functions or purposes
of unions are (or should be), and therefore which
processes will best serve them. Decisions and practices which prevent unions from fulfilling these functions are therefore much seen as ‘ undemocratic ’, as
not serving the real interests of the majority. In
other words, in most conceptions of union democra
cy – even those which claim to be purely process-based
– adjective and substantive aspects are inextricably linked. ultimately, most definitions of union majority rule involve
some notion of what is taken to be its opposite,
oligarchy. indeed, most of the spell on inte
rnal union politics has chronicled the multitude of
undemocratic practices and the conditions in which they
flourish. The classical Aristotelian definition of
oligarchy involves the rule of the few in the service
of their own interests, most typically understood as the
prolongation of their own ability and relative privilege.
This can take the shape of a formal governance
social organization, or, more typically in the advanced era, of
a “management style” which emerges in the context of
formally democratic institutions.
11
However, the point at which the line between democratic and oligarchic
28 12
Carole Pateman,
Participation and Democratic Theory
(London: Cambridge University Press, 1970), 14.
13
Hilary Wainwright,
Arguments for a New Left: Answering the Free Market Right
(Oxford: Blackwell, 1994), 128.
government is crossed varies well in the
literature, as does the status of bureaucracy as a
particular kind of the “ principle of the few ”. While bureauc
racy connotes the ability of officials to make decisions
on behalf of others, there is significant consider over tungsten
hether it inevitably displays the second characteristic
of oligarchy, that of rule in the opportunism of
the office-holders themselves. As such, the question of
whether bureaucracy is inherently oligarchic
and therefore whether dem
ocracy and bureaucracy are
mutually exclusive is besides central to the diverse perspectives under examination. It is possible to categorize conceptions of union dem
ocracy on a spectrum from ‘narrow’ to ‘broad’,
in terms of the number and type of participants, as we
ll as the kind and scope of participation. There are
besides authoritative variations in how ‘ participation ’ is
conceived, which can be placed in one of three categories.
In the first gear, participation of the huge majority is confi
ned to the election of leaders, who substitute for them in
most decision-making and execution.
12
In the second, participation of the members is widened to
include decision-making on important policy matters, wisconsin
th elected and appointed officials responsible for
implementation. The third gear view emphasizes the importance of broad public address system
rticipation in the implementation of
decisions, which Wainwright terms the “ democracy of doing ”.
13
Those who employ a narrow definition of union dem
ocracy take as their model the practice of
spokesperson politics which characterizes capi
talist democracies. For these commentators, who
come chiefly from the legalist and managerialis
t camps and who are influenced by contemporary
democratic theory of the Schumpeterian
variety, it is not necessary for all members to participate in all
decisions. alternatively, the practice of delegating is
understood as sufficiently democratic: while the
membership may not be in send and direct control condition of
all decisions, they retain ultimate authority via
their ability to elect and ‘ unelect ’ their representatives in
regular electoral contests for leadership. In such a
model, most daily decision-making is restricted to a relatively little group of people. In order to
29 14
Stepan-Norris, 477; Pateman, 4, 14.
15
Samuel Gompers, “The Philos
ophy of Trade Unionism,” in
Unions, Management and the Public
, eds. E. Wight Bakke and C.
Kerr ( New York : Harcourt Brace and Co., 1948 ), 30, 31. 16
Adolph Strasser, quoted in J.B.S. Hardman,
American Labor Dynamics
(New York: Harcourt Brace & Co., 1928), 31.
17
Philip Taft,
The Structure and Government of Labor Unions
(Cambridge, Mass: Harvard
University Press, 1962), 35.
see the democratic character of this division of
responsibility, it is argued that conditions in which
members may meaningfully hold their r
epresentatives accountable are paramount.
14
As such, the
conditions which sustain competitive elections and or
ganized opposition as taken as the key indicators of
democratic process. The restriction of members ’ participation to electi
ons is often (but not always) linked to a narrow,
consistent and instrumental understanding of workers ’ interests and unions ’ purposes. Most of those who stress accountability over engagement argue that
since workers’ interests lie with economic
improvements, not with majority rule or revolution, uni
ons should therefore be structured to be effective in
economic struggles. such views are much directly attributed to the influence of Samuel Gompers, over the character and philosophy of the U.S. labor movem
ent. For Gompers, president of the American
federation of Labor for closely forty years, and his centiliter
ose associate Adolph Strasser, the priority in trade
union legal action is to bring immediate corporeal improv
ements to the working class, not to imagine “a new
company constructed from rainbow materials. ”
15
As Strasser put it in his testimony before the Senate Committee on Education and Labor, the tug drift has
“no ultimate ends … We are fighting only for
immediate objects – objects that can be realized in a few years. ”
16
Such views about the appropriate
officiate of trade unions were subsequently adopted by
many institutionalist theorists. Taft argued that
unions are “ single-purpose organizations ” focussed on thymine
he “protection of the economic interests of its
members. ”
17
Similarly, Selig Perlman asserted that, as “
opportunists”, U.S. workers “do not start with any
general theory of industrial company, but approach the subject as bargainers, desiring to strike the best wage
30 18
Selig Perlman,
A Theory of the Labor Movement
(New York: Augustus M. Kelley Inc.,1950), 268, 266.
19
John Rowett, “Labour Movement,” in
The Blackwell Encyclopaedia of Political Science
, ed. V. Bogdanor (London: Blackwell,
1991 ), 315. 20
Bruce Kaufman, “The Early Institutionalists
on Industrial Democracy and Union Democracy,”
Journal of Labor Research
21,
no.2 ( Spring 2000 ) : 197-8. 21
Lipset, “The Political Process in Trade Unions,” 238.
22
R.A. Lester,
As Unions Mature: An Analysis of
the Evolution of American Unionism
(Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press,
1958 ), 17. 23
Sidney and Beatrice Webb, quoted in J.E.T. Eldri
dge, “Trade Unions and Bureaucratic Control,” in
Trade Unions under
capitalism
, eds. T. Clarke and L. Clements (London: Fontana Collins, 1977), 177.
bargain potential. ”
18
For him, workers’ “universal scarcity
consciousness … led them to try to create,
through negotiations with employers, corporate regul
ations governing the conditions and terms of work.”
19
Some institutionalists have a slightly broader
notion of union function than those following the
Gomperist line. For those like John Commons of metric ton
he Wisconsin School, unions also have an important role
in democratization of industry and company. Unions can reduce the “ insidious results ” of autocracy of industry and “ balance [ the relative ] bargaining power ” of labor and capital by creating institutions of collective bargain which allow workers to partici
pate in the regulation of their wages and working
conditions.
20
Unions, as an organized interest group, also protect “political democracy in the larger body
politic ” : they do so by “ facilitating political educ
ation and opposition … training new leaders, organizing and
representing their members to other groups and t
he state”, and “checking the encroachments of other
groups. ”
21
They also provide a means for “guiding worker
s’ discontent into orderly channels” and thus the
passive “ reconciliation of conflicting interests. ”
22
Whether focussed on economic improvements or one
ndustrial democracy, institutionalists tend to
agree that participatory forms of majority rule interfere
with trade unions’ essential functions. The Webbs
pointed out long ago that attachment to the “ archaic democratic ” principle that “ everything which concerns all should be decided by all ” inevitably leads to
“inefficiency and disintegration” or oligarchy.
23
Excessive
home debate or electoral opposition is seen to
undermine both union cohesiveness and the credibility of
31 24
Taft, 35.
25
Richard Hurd, “Professional Employees and Uni
on Democracy: from Control to Chaos,”
Journal of Labor Research
21, no. 1
( Winter 2000 ) : 8, 1. 26
Pateman, 5, 10, 14; M. Crozier, S.M. Huntington, and J. Watanuki,
The Crisis of Democracy: Report on the Governability of
Democracies to the Trilateral Commission
(New York: New York University Press, 1975).
27
Will Herberg, “Bureaucracy and Democracy in Labor Unions,”
Antioch Review
3 (Fall 1943): 411.
28
Kaufman, 190.
29
Lipset, “The Political Process in Trade Unions,” 238.
incumbent leadership, specially in the eyes of the employer.
24
The involvement of the grassroots in day-to-
day decision-making can be had at the high price of
“conflict, internal fragmentation, and disunity”, and
results in what Hurd refers to as the “ chaos of democracy. ”
25
These perspectives are consistent with those
of Schumpeter, Sartori or Hunti
ngton, who argue that “too much dem
ocracy” above a required minimum
level is perilously destabilize.
26
The estimate that democracy is antagonistic with union
function takes several forms. For some, there
is a actual “ majority rule dilemma ” about how to comb
ine effective unionism with popular control.
27
however, most grudgingly accept that the effective gas constant
epresentation of workers’ interests requires that unions
dramatize undemocratic inner structures. While this is troubling to them, they believe that what is to be gained by such organizational forms is at least equal to, if
not greater in importance,
than what is sacrificed.
Commons and his followers reconciled the necessity for undemocratic unions “ through a pragmatic calculation that the social gain from using barter
unions to end employer autocracy in the workplace
outweighs whatever deleterious effects aris
e from autocracy in the unions themselves.”
28
Lipset goes further and argues that the conditions which foster
union democracy are undermining of democracy in civil
society more generally, as union majority rule leads to
self-segregation, selfishness and irresponsibility,
preferably than the civic virtues of compromise, common
understanding, tolerance of dissent, and consideration
of the interests of others.
29
Others do not find the absence of participatory or
even formal democracy problematic at all – in
fact daily control by delegate authority is seen to create the conditions of successful collective
32 30
V.L. Allen,
Power in Trade Unions
(London: Longmans, Green, 1954), 15.
31
Taft, 36, 64.
32
V.L. Allen quoted in Eldridge, 178; Lipset, 238.
33
Hemingway, 9-10.
bargain and frankincense to represent and serve workers ’ ulti
mate interests. No-one has stated this position
more clearly than V.L. Allen, who claims that “ tr
ade union organization is not based on theoretical concepts
anterior to it, that is, on some concept of democracy,
but on the end it serves … the end of trade union activity
is to protect and improve the general support standards
of its members and not to provide workers with an
exercise in self-government. ”
30
This line of reasoning entirely repl
aces procedural elements of democracy
with substantial ones. In this way, efficient
bureaucratic organization is understood as democratic because
democracy is more powerfully linked with outcomes rather than processes. In the most extreme variants of this status,
democracy is not even characterised by electoral
contest between elites. Inst
ead, these authors emphasize the wa
ys that leaders are “responsive to
members ’ interests ” in the absence of formally dem
ocratic procedures. Taft, for instance, points to the
process of pre-election compromise : for him, the abs
ence of observable opposition “does not indicate the
absence of differences, but preferably the fact that they
are compromised before the election.” He argues that
even incumbent leaders “ must constantly be aware of
important individuals, such as strong local or
regional leaders, and strategic locals, or crafts or
trade divisions” within the union, and endeavour to be
responsive to these differences. In other words, metric ton
he desire to avoid differences breaking out into the open
to preserve union cohesion and potency actually makes leadership responsive and therefore at least quasi-democratic.
31
Others argue that even within bureauc
ratic unions oriented around the economic
serve, members remain in ultimate authority. Leader
s must ‘deliver the goods’ or they risk losing their
placement or even their membership.
32
Hemingway calls this “control through satisfaction”, that is, through
the satisfaction of members ’ economic interests via colle
ctive bargaining; in this thinking, it is assumed that
members are satisfy and hence “ represent
ed” as long as there is no revolt.
33
In this argument, the notion
33 34
Pateman, 104.
35
Held, 157.
36
C.B. MacPherson,
The Life and Times of Liberal Democracy
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1977), 86.
37
Robert Michels,
Political Parties: A Sociological Study of the Em
ergence of Leadership, the Psychology of Power, and the
oligarchic Tendencies of Organization
(New York: Free Press, 1962), 318-19, 364.
38
Therborn, 208.
of ‘ delivering the goods ’ reflects the stay operat
ion of a democratic principle as it entails the
representation of members ’ interests. It is with some judge that the institutionalist
position is accused of a rather fundamental watering
down of the mean of majority rule. Pateman argues
that this twentieth-century theory of democracy
“ bears a strange resemblance to the anti-democratic
arguments” of the nineteent
h, in which the average
person is deemed incapable of anything more than selecting leaders.
34
David Held terms this vision
‘ competitive elitism ’, “ at best … a means of choosing between decision-makers and curbing their excesses ” and a reach to characterize the arrangements it describes as democratic.
35
MacPherson also rejected
“ pluralist elitism ” on the basis that it taxonomic
ally produces and sustains inequality, which is “in
contradiction of the central democra
tic tenet of equality of individual
entitlement to the use and enjoyment
of one ’ s capacities. ”
36
Others are more blunt and call all of
the above practices oligarchy – indeed it is
precisely this situation to which Michels applied thyroxine
he term. For him, the need for representation, for
deputation of decision-making power, and for leadership
– fundamental to the functioning of all large
institutions – is oligarchic in nature.
37
The emergence of organization which necessitates representation
is therefore a process of e
trangement between leaders and members.
38
On the basis of these assorted critiques of radius
epresentation, a more expansive understanding of union
democracy is premised on the impression t
hat all members should participate directly in all of the decisions
which affect them. As such, lead or participator
y democracy is the model against which union practice is
to be measured. many writers in the socialistic or Marx
ist tradition fall within this perspective, as does Robert
Michels in the more anarchist-influenced aspects of hawaii
s thought. Even the institutionalist Coleman posits a
34 39
J.R. Coleman, “The Compulsive Pressures of Democracy,” in
Labor and Trade Unionism: an
Interdisciplinary Reader
, eds. W.
Galenson and S.M Lipset ( New Yo
rk: John Wiley and Sons, 1960), 208.
40
Michels, 66.
41
A.J. Muste, “Army and Town Meeting,” in
Unions, Management and the Public
, eds. E. Wight Bakke and C. Kerr (New York:
Harcourt Brace and Co., 1948 ), 333. 42
Norman Geras,
Literature of Revolution: Essays on Marxism
(London: Verso, 1986), 134.
43
Karl Marx, “Provisional Rules of the Inte
rnational Working Men’s Association” in
The First International and After: Political
Writings Vol. 3
, K. Marx, ed. D. Fernbach (London: Pelican / New Left Review, 1974), 82.
44
Lucio Magri, “Problems of the Marx
ist Theory of the Revolutionary Party,”
New Left Review
60 (1970): 2.
broad definition of democratic decision-making as char
acterized by “meaningful opportunities for members
participation in formulation, ratifica
tion and implementation of union policies.”
39
What justifications are given field-grade officer
r participatory models of democracy?
At the center of these views is the impression that workers ’ interests are more than merely economic. rather, respective thinkers have asserted that workers as human beings have an interest in freedom
from the control of others,
in self-realization, and
in economic and political emancipation via their self-activ
ity. The most basic is Michels’ socialist-anarchist
commitment to “ pure ” democracy, which permits
the masses’ direct and equal participation in “the
regulation of the coarse interests ”
and prevents their control by others.
40
Muste argues that trade union
democracy satisfies needs that workers possess but
which are not satisfied in capitalist production
relations ; through active participation, workers “ mho
eek release from the monotony and regimentation of
mechanize industry, and the opportunity for self-expression. ”
41
The importance of the active engagement of workers in the contend for their own dismissal is by and large highly developed by Marxists. For Marx, the mind of
proletarian self-emancipation is central to both
theoretical understand of history and
the revolutionary political process.
42
He accordingly placed the idea
that “ the emancipation of the working classes must
be conquered by the working classes themselves” at
the very beginning of the
Provisional Rules for the International Working Men’s Association
.
43
According to
Lucio Magri, Marx ’ s goal was “ to found in theory and to pr
omote in practice the action of man in history, as
a national of will and freedom following rationally arranged decisions and ends. ”
44
In other words, it is not
35 45
The link between participation and self-rea
lization was originally theorized by R
ousseau (see Pateman); however, as Geras
points out, there are some important cont
radictions in his conceptualization, namely that while engagement in participatory
structures creates the kind of person
capable of such engagement, those structures
themselves must be introduced by the enlightened who are not trapped by the undemocratic st
ructures in which we exist (Geras, 134-5).
46
Karl Marx, Thesis III,
Theses on Feuerbach
, 1845, at http://www.marxists.org/arc
hive/marx/works/1845/theses/index.htm.
47
John Kelly,
Trade Unions and Socialist Politics
(London: Verso, 1988), 35.
48
Rosa Luxemburg,
The Russian Revolution
, in
Rosa Luxemburg Speaks
, ed. M-A. Waters (New York: Pathfinder Press, 1970),
389. 49
Ibid., 386-7.
enough to have one ’ sulfur “ interests ” met by others ; rat
her, one must be actively engaged in the definition and
satisfaction of those interests. It is in the process of struggling to transform society, of creating revolution, that people are themselves transform, become capabl
e of reaching their full potential, and of living in
socialistic ways.
45
This “coincidence of the changing of circ
umstances and of human activity or self-change”
is Marx ’ s definition of revolutionary exercise.
46
The “ self-education of the working class ” is therefore a cardinal separate of the rotatory process. This subject is most potently expressed in the
work of Rosa Luxemburg. Her prioritization of
workers ’ self-activity is linked to her sympathy
of the process through which the struggling class
becomes aware of itself and its corporate interests.
In her attempt to understand what is required not only
to make revolution but besides to sustain a post-revol
utionary society which is both socialist and democratic,
she pays sustained attention to “ the immanent moment of class consciousness. ”
47
For Luxemburg, the
“ political discipline and education of
the entire mass of the people” is t
he “very air” which a revolutionary
government needs to survive.
48
The “unending pressure”, the “active, untrammelled, energetic political life
of the broadest bulk of the people ” acts as a correc
tive for “all the innate shortcomings of social
institutions. ”
49
Because revolution itself has no blueprint, because it “lies completely hidden in the mists of
the future ”, its very nature demands that the wides
t scope of experience and creativity be available and
used. Leaders can not possibly anticipate all problems or
develop all solutions, for “socialism by its very
nature can not be decreed … The negative,
the tearing down, can be decreed;
the building up, the positive,
36 50
Ibid., 390.
51
Ibid., 391.
52
Geras, 137.
53
Rosa Luxemburg,
The Mass Strike
, in
Rosa Luxemburg Speaks
, ed. M-A. Waters (New York: Pathfinder Press, 1970), 172;
Geras, 171. 54
Luxemburg,
The Russian Revolution
, 391.
55
Geras, 137.
can not. New territory. A thousand problems. only experience is capable of correcting and opening fresh ways. only unobstructed, effervescing life falls into
a thousand new forms and improvisations, brings to
light creative force, itself corrects all err attempts. ”
50
“Public control” is thus necessary because,
otherwise, “ the exchange of experiences remains only wisconsin
th the closed circle of the officials of the new
regimen. Corruption becomes inevitable. ”
51
In other words, the successful revolution demands working class political engagement. A key locate of this ‘ education of the labor ’ for revolution and socialism is in their own autonomous class organizations like deal unions, in
which they develop the consciousness of their
interests within the current organization of company,
the desire to supercede it, and the capacity to participate
in full in the management of a future socialist company.
52
Since capitalistic social structures do not permit the labor to gain the necessitate capacities, bunco
sciousness and organization for full and equal participation,
these must be acquired in the “ living petty officer
litical school” of revolutionary activity.
53
Otherwise, people will
just replicate the elitist social relations to whic
h they are accustomed. Through participation in these
organizations, workers develop “ social instincts in station of conceited ones ” which are the consequence of “ centuries of bourgeois govern. ”
54
They throw off “all habits of deference”, acquire “confidence in [their] own
ability to organize and rule ” and develop “ experience in organization and in the make of political decisions. ”
55
Put otherwise, workers need to develop, in t
heir own organizations, “the kind of capacities and
potentials which are absolutely fundamental to one day build
ing a different kind of society: the capacities for
37 56
Sam Gindin, “Socialism with Sober Senses: Developing Workers’ Capacities,” in
The Socialist Register 1998: The Communist
Manifesto nowadays
, eds. L. Panitch and C. Leys (New Yo
rk: Monthly Review Press, 1998), 79.
57
Karl Marx to Johann von Schweitzer,
13 February 1865, 147; Karl Marx to Johann von Schweitzer, 13 October 1868, 156; Karl
Marx and Frederick Engels, Circular Letter to Bebel,
Liebknecht, Bracke, et.al
., 17-18 September 1879, 375.
58
Geras, 157.
59
Geras, 170-172.
doing, creating, design, executing ” which are systematically underdeveloped by capitalism.
56
For this
rationality, Marx placed a identical high priority on the exploitation of trade unions as spaces for the work course to learn how to “ walk by themselves ”,
and condemned those leaders like Lassalle whose tactics
served to substitute themselves for the workers
and deny that the latter was able to liberate itself.
57
It was
for exchangeable reasons that both Trotsky and Luxemburg ar
gued that the Leninist form of organization risked
creating a party “ from above and on the pin down basis of a small but compress group of marxist intellectuals ” rather of “ from below and on the basis of an ever
growing participation of the working class.”
58
For the most part, then, participatory democracy is
classically seen in the Marxist tradition as both
an crucial goal in itself and as an effective means to a variety of important ends : it is both developmental and instrumental. furthermore, these two faces of equality
ticipation are organically connected, for “the content
of the future must already be sketched in the activity of
the present”; in other words, if the ultimate goal is to
create a company in which all people are able to participate fully and evenly in decision-making and management of homo affairs, then the
process by which this is achieved must itself be participatory;
“ [ oxygen ] therwise, the end itself is distorted. ”
59
But evening amongst those who emphasize participation, the particular content of union action is besides important and serves to qualify which arrangements are seen as democratic. For exemplify, Lenin saw majority rule as integrally linked to the result of
trade union activity. Workers’ leaders and organizations
advocating rotation were by definition democratic, as
they expressed the ‘true’ interests of the majority,
namely their interest in the upset of capita
lism and its replacement with an egalitarian social and
economic order. The leaders of revolutionary wage-earning organizations were besides, by definition, not
38 60
Leier,
Red Flags
, 24.
61
Stepan-Norris, 477; L. Pearlin and H. Richards,
“Equity: A Study of Union Democracy,” in
Labor and Trade Unionism: An
interdisciplinary Reader
, eds. W. GALENSON and S.M Lipset (N
ew York: John Wiley and Sons, 1960), 266.
62
Leier,
Red Flags
, 25.
63
See Hemingway, 1-2 for a similar argument.
“ bureaucrats ”. Trade unions or political parties
which had adopted a reformist ideology were, on the other
hand, undemocratic.
60
ultimately, it is hard to avoid defining democ
racy without referring to both accountability and
participation, work and content, means and ends.
In many respects, there is a strong connection
between the two, since leadership accountability is exist
t secured by an active, informed, and participatory
membership.
61
However, the difficult truth is that proce
ss and content can and do come into contradiction
with each other. indeed, the identification of democracy ( or oligarchy ) by ideological subject at the expense of process can be used to justify an inadequate baron relationship between leaders and members on the basis of an elect ’ south presumed limited cognition of workers ’ interests.
62
When goals and methods come
into conflict, how to decide which is to take priority ? This problem can not be resolved
a priori
and imposed by decree on organizations. The balance between representation and engagement is and must be worked out jointly, in the context of an ongoi
ng political struggle over the concrete meaning and
practice of democracy. The relationship between means
and ends is key to democracy: the self-activity of
the knead class must be central, not because they
are always automatically democratic, or because they
constantly make the ‘ right ’ decisions, but because without
this, there is no basis for building an egalitarian
society, let alone democratic socialism. But
saying so doesn’t help us understand whether democracy
comes to be adopted within a especial marriage and why it takes the specific form it does. consequently, it is significant to
keep these various definitions of union democracy in mind as we move
to a more detailed interrogation of the factors whic
h are thought to sustain or undermine it. Definitions
involve conceptions of the concrete arrangements or
practices deemed to be sufficient to foster democracy.
63
39 64
See, for instance, Michels, Seidman, and Dan La Botz,
Rank-and-File Rebellion: Teamsters for a Democratic Union
(New York:
Verso, 1990 ) for countless examples whic
h span different historical periods.
This is thus not lone for academics, but for union leaders and members angstrom well, as they have recourse to these definitions of democracy as a justification field-grade officer
r their own activities within unions. Keeping these
definitions in mind, then, we will now move on to a moment
re detailed examination of the factors which influence
the libra struck between representat
ion and participation in workers’
organizations. In particular, we
want to understand why one expression may dominate over the other, and with what consequences. The focus here will be on the shock of the character, intere
sts and capacities of leaders and members, and their
kinship to one another, on the possibilities of union majority rule. At this point, we must delve more deeply into the factors which have been put fore as major influences on the democratic quality of unions. Mo
st treatments spend considerable time on elaborating
the factors which encourage democracy ’ sulfur opposites, o
ligarchy and bureaucracy. They vary only on the
motion of whether and to what degree these oligarchic
al tendencies are inevitable. However, much less
time is spend looking at the pressures
for
majority rule. here we will examine both, and in fact highlight how in each of the areas to be considered, there are coincident, contradictory and multi-directional pressures at work. III.
Leaders: Representatives of the Workers?
common to the majority of the perspectives
examined here is the idea that leaders bear a
significant share of the duty for the creation and replica of undemocratic union structures. The focus is on the undemocratic effects on leaders
of possessing delegated power from union members.
baron either changes once democratic leaders,
making them both oligarchical in approach and
conservative in ideology, or reinforces their al
ready existing tendencies. Given the easily catalogued
misdeeds of many union leaders, it is no surprise that they are deemed the primary culprits.
64
Michels in
40 65
David Beetham, “Michels and his Critics,”
European Journal of Sociology
22 (1981): 87; J. Edelstein and M. Warner,
Comparative Union Democracy : organization
and Opposition in British and American Unions
, 2
nd
ed. (New Brunswick, New
Jersey : Transaction Books,1979 ), 32. Edel
stein and Warner argue that Michels di
d not equate existence of organizational
leadership with oligarchy, rather that the
former leads to the latter (and are therefor
e by implication distinct). However, sin
ce
Michels posits this movement as inevitable, quite than mere
ly a strong tendency, organization and oligarchy are for all intent
s
and purposes the same thing, and the distinction Edelst
ein and Warner point to is, in my view, academic.
66
Hyman,
Marxism
, 9.
67
David Fernbach, “Introduction,” in
The First International and After: Political Writings Vol. 3
, K. Marx, ed. D. Fernbach (London:
Pelican / New Left Review, 1974 ), 25 ; Karl Marx
, letter to Karl Liebknecht, February 11, 1878.
68
La Botz, 10.
particular stressed the mutually reinforce nature of
psychological, political-organizational, and sociological
processes which leads those who possessed organizational power to abuse that might.
65
While emphases
deviate, the huge majority of commentators use both
material and psychological factors to explain why so
many leaders work to preserve their position at the thymine
op of the union hierarchy. The central controversy here
is whether such undemocratic leadership is inevitable,
inherent in leaders’ personalit
ies or in the structural
placement of leadership itself, or whether
some leaders may escape these tendencies.
The most basic version of these arguments attributes undemocratic leadership behavior to personal greed, dishonesty or opportunism. In other
words, some leaders are morally weak, unable to
resist the temptations of agency, and as a resultant role fa
il to defend the true interests of workers. Marx and
Engels, for example, emphasized the role that the “ master of arts in teaching
erial or ideological” corruption of leaders could play
in turning the labor movement towards
conservative ends and undemocratic practices.
66
Corruption and opportunism explained for Marx and Engels why Brit
ish trade union leaders, in exchange for an expansion
of right to vote and for bribes, opted to mobilize working chlorine
ass electoral support for the Liberal Party in 1868.
67
La Botz ’ s analysis of oligarchy in the Teamsters ’ union besides identifies the personal corruption of leaders as the central trouble. His description of the 1986 Teamst
ers’ convention is archtypical: instead of being a
consequence for democratic decision-making, it was a december
adent Roman orgy of food,
drink, entertainment and
hero worship in which then-president Jackie Presser,
“was carried into the hall on a sedan chair on the
shoulders of four eskimo dog weightlifters dressed
in the sandals and tunics of Roman centurions.”
68
The
41 69
Seidman, 21, 49.
70
Michels, 205.
71
While Michels does admit that “nurture” has some role to play
, in that leaders become good at or
used to leading, such sociall
y
fostered habits merely reinforce rather than count
eract nature. Beetham, “M
ichels and his Critics,” 83.
Teamsters are an extreme case of the relatively common idea that union leaders use their positions to benefit personally from the fiscal resources of the
union. The implication here is that the difference
between democratic or authoritarian leadership hinges
on “the type of men in office”: “much depends upon
the intelligence and personality of the union head. If he is
lustful for power or possesses an ego that craves
flattery, he may build a machine that crushes democracy. ”
69
In other words, leaders who were “better
people ” would be more able to resist
inducements to “betray the workers”.
A more pessimistic translation of the argument emphasizes that
all
leaders seek and maintain their
positions in order to satisfy complex psychologica
l needs. Those who would become leaders share a set of
predispositions which not alone make them successful in
their bid for power, but also drive them to seek that
exponent and the condition it brings. This scene is equality
ticularly pronounced in Michels’ work, and he attributed a
great share of undemocratic practices to the personal
ambition of leaders. For him, all leaders or would-
be leaders are ultimately the like ; allowing for variations owing to class origins, at base leaders are psychologically driven by the same desires,
that is, their “natural greed for power.”
70
In this view, these
individuals besides have the “ natural aptit
udes of leaders” which allow them to
fight their way to the top of the
social structure and satisfy their ambitions.
71
The “metamorphosis” of leaders into oligarchs is, for Michels,
rooted in their nature. Having attained such mighty positions, union liter
eaders begin to derive personal satisfaction from a
sense of importance and superiority. Their relations with union staff and members, vitamin a well as employers and government officials all foster such a self-concept
ion. Their success in union elections and collective
bargain, their accumulated cognition and experienc
e wins them the admirat
ion and deference of the
members. Their proportional success vis à vis their field-grade officer
rmer workmates fosters in leaders a tendency, “even if
42 72
C. Wright Mills,
The New Men of Power: America’s Labor Leaders
(New York: Harcourt Brace, 1948), 105.
73
Seidman, 47.
74
Michels, 81; Muste, 340; Samuel Friedman,
Teamster Rank and File: Power, Bur
eaucracy and Rebellion at Work and in a
Union
(New York: Columbia University Press, 1982), 26-7.
75
Lipset, “The Political Process in Trade Unions,” 223. The im
plication, of course, is t
hat middle-class union leaders will not
turn
into oligarch, and this is indeed partially of Lipset ’ s explanation for the doggedness of
democracy in the ITU. These ideas are a
lso
found in Michels : while he did discuss the presence of members of the middle class ’ s intellectual and petit larceny class amongst the socialistic ranks, he did not see them as the chief campaign of em
bourgeoisment in working class parties. Rather, it was the effect
of
leadership on those of working class origins
that was the concern. See Michels, 238, 256.
76
Lipset, “The Political Process in Trade Unions,” 224; Muste, 341.
77
Seymour Martin Lipset, “Michels’ Theor
y of Political Parties”, Introduction to
Political Parties: A Sociological Study of the
egress of Leadership, the Psychology of Power,
and the Oligarchic Tendencies of Organization
, R. Michels (New York: Free
press, 1962. ), 18. unconsciously, to look down on those who have not succeeded ”, and therefore to believe in their need for healthy leadership.
72
Their work brings them into contact wi
th members of the managerial class, by whom
they are seen, if grudgingly, as powerful people to be tantalum
ken seriously. Their greater control over their own
working conditions gives them a common sense of domination,
although their long hours in the service of the union lead
them to believe they are self-denying and therefore owed gratitude. Because of these ‘ heroic efforts ’, leaders increasingly collapse the distinction between themse
lves and the union, until “opposition to him and his
policies seems like treachery to the administration. ”
73
Their activities have a profound impact on the lives of
many others, which fuels their sense of importanc
e. They can often appear to have “saved the day” by
making difficult compromises and last-minute deals, thymine
hus averting costly and disruptive strikes. Through
these experiences, leaders come to see themselves
as powerful, indispensable and in possession of a right
to their leadership put.
74
These psychological dynamics, it is argued,
are particularly pronounced amongst leaders from
“ low-status ”, wage-earning occupations. Lipset arkansas
gues that the greater the
status gap between a leader’s
former occupation and their position within the uni
on, the greater the pressure to hold onto power.
75
The
idea of returning to the shop deck, of leaving the
sphere in which they have both control and respect, is
chagrin incarnate.
76
They must at all costs preserve this positi
on, for to lose it “is to lose that which
makes them crucial individuals. ”
77
This sense of self-importance is deeply rooted in working-class
43 78
Mills, 100.
79
Michels, 281. He goes on to argue that the variety of me
thods used to reduce the leader
’s dependence on the organization for
fabric benefit and promotion are besides in bootless. An insistenc
e on free service to the cause
would lead to two other negative
outcomes – either a dependence on “ comfortable cobalt
mrades” for leadership, or an incentive to
low-paid officials for “corruption a
nd
demoralization ”. See Michels, 140, 146. 80
Lipset, “The Political Process in Trade Unions,” 224.
81
Karl Marx to Ludwig Kugelmann, 23 February 1865, 148.
82
Michels, 260.
leaders who have, by their own efforts, “ made it ” up a
very long ladder to an important place in the social
structure.
78
However, the material insecurity inherent
in democratic processes and the psychological
inferiority still internalized by those who attain some
sort of social mobility plagues the “parvenu” ex-
proletarian, leading them “ to mainta
in his authority with extreme jealou
sy, to regard all criticism as an undertake to humiliate him and to diminish his import
ance, as a deliberate and ill-natured allusion to his
past. ”
79
In other words, union leaders confront an ov
erwhelming conflict between their psychological needs
and their ( erstwhile ) democratic commitments ; however, Li
pset argues, it is the former which usually wins
out, and results in “ strenuous efforts of the region of
many trade union leaders to eliminate democracy.”
80
Marx seems to have viewed Lassalle in this inner light,
and explained the German SPD leader’s failure to fight
Germany ’ s anti-combination laws and win unionizati
on rights for workers, and his accommodation with
Bismarck ’ randomness government in exchange for universal right to vote,
in terms of his desire to be seen as “the heroic
savior of the work class. ”
81
The profound psychological attachment to the trappings
of office is further reinforced by the normal
( rather than dirty ) material benefits associated with
leadership. This theme is emphasized by Michels
and Trotsky, and their respective followers, and their conscientious objector
mments on this issue are strikingly similar. Leaders
end to be members of the working class in socio-
economic terms: union leadership brings with it higher
salaries and control over the fiscal resources
of the union. As socialist and labour movements
themselves constitute a source of social mobility,
they allow proletarians to abandon manual labour for the
more financially advantageous, prestigious and impregnable
“brainwork” of party and union officialdom.
82
On
44 83
Michels, 262, 282-3.
84
Michels, 207.
85
Michels, 254; Beetham, “M
ichels and his Critics,” 87.
86
Michels, 283-4.
87
Kelly, 44, 49.
88
Leon Trotsky, “Marxism
and Trade Unionism,” in
Trade Unions under Capitalism
, eds. T. Clarke and L. Clements (London:
Fontana Collins, 1977 ), 77. 89
Michels, 264; Hyman,
Marxism
, 18; Trotsky, 84; Kelly, 44.
their nowadays higher wage, leaders are now able to enjoy a “ respectable ” petty businessperson life style and internalize the norms of “ good company ” to which they immediately have access.
83
A relinquishing of leadership
would not alone be a psychological humiliation, but besides
a “financial disaster” for those who would now have
to return to manual parturiency.
84
In other words, union leaders
undergo a process of embourgeoisement
through which they are “ assimilated into
the elites of established society.”
85
Both Michels and Trotsky emphasize the way that
the new material position of leaders has an
consequence on their political orientation and goals, a well as on the inte
rnal democratic process. As a result of their new
kinship to “ the existing ordering ”, proletarian liter
eaders relinquish their commitment to the overthrow of
capitalism. Michels asks, “ [ w ] hat concern for them
has now the dogma of social revolution? Their own
sociable rotation has already been effected. ”
86
Trotsky agrees: for him, the
root of leadership antipathy
towards rotatory change was the material privil
eges gained by the full-time labour bureaucracy, which
led to an identification with the organizations themse
lves rather than with working class interests and
struggles.
87
Union leadership, having “satisfactorily solved its own social problem”, opted to become
“ lieutenants ” or “ the economic police ” of c
apital in the exploitation of the workers.
88
In other words, union
leaders were nowadays “ strangers to their class ”, in full inco
rporated into capitalism’s mechanisms for controlling
workers, and resistant to any attack to mobilize work
ers in ways that they themselves did not control or
which undermined the material basis of their organizations.
89
According to this view, then, “trade union
45 90
Kelly, 77.
91
Geras, 161.
92
Geras, 199, 169, 195.
93
Trotsky, 77.
94
Trotsky quoted in Kelly, 42.
leaderships will tend to restrain social station
-and-file militancy because of its th
reat to their own privileges and to
industrial relations order. ”
90
IV.
Members: The Font of Democracy?
Another key factor examined in the literature is the function of
the membership in sustaining or
undermining union democracy. The identification of union
members as the source of democracy is common
in much Marxist think, but is peculiarly pronounced in the work of Luxemburg ( as we have already seen ) and Trotsky. These views are discernible in their employment with Lenin over the allow kind of internal party constitution and its kinship to the working course, their criticisms of european and American party and coupling leaders, and their think on
working-class strategy. Both maintained what
Geras calls a “ confidence in the efficacy of mugwump ma
ss political action”, of working-class self-activity,
upon which their review of bureaucracy within socialist and union organizations was based.
91
Both were
opposed to ‘ substitutionism ’ in which a party ( or union )
leadership, believing in its superior knowledge of the
means and goals of contend, stands in for and direct
s the working class, and both believed that mass
engagement would be an effective “ antidote ”
to bureaucratic inertia and conservatism.
92
For Trotsky and his followers in especial, the only hope for a democratic and revolutionist deal unionism lie in “ the dismissal of the workers
from the reactionary influence of the trade union
bureaucracy. ”
93
Trotsky’s writings from the 1930s contain
an analysis of the crisis-ridden political economy
of the time that led him to believe both the material
conditions and the workers themselves were ready for
revolution.
94
Given this, responsibility for the absence of such revolutionary action and continued political
46 95
Kelly, 43.
96
Trotsky quoted in Hyman,
Marxism
, 18.
97
Friedman, 14.
98
Stan Weir, “The Conflict in American Unions and the Resist
ance to Alternative Ideas from the Rank and File,” in
Workers’
Struggles, Past, Present :
A ‘Radical America’ Reader
, ed. J. Green (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1983), 254-8.
99
Michels, 107.
100
Therborn, 208.
defeats of the working class ballad with thei
r leaders, and in particular the union bureaucracy.
95
“The present
officials … are impregnated with the sp
irit of the bourgeoisie … In order to make the trade unions fit for their
future function, they must be freed of cautious offi
cials, of superstitious blockheads, who from heaven know
where expect a ‘ peaceful ’ miracle. ”
96
A trade unionism which the members democratically controlled would
therefore besides be revolutionary. This position is easily observed in much left wr
iting about trade unions and labour history from the
1970s on, and is particularly pronounced in the literat
ure by and about rank-and-file democracy movements
in the U.S. parturiency campaign. Friedman, for instanc
e, believes that union members are the main bulwark
against bureaucratization, which they can “ prevent or roll second ”.
97
Weir also describes the ways in which
workers have always ad lib organized via militant lead action as against leaders ’ efforts to tame them.
98
While Trotsky and Michels plowshare similar indictment
s of the labour bureaucracy it is on the question
of the workers ’ kinship to democracy that t
hey part company. Michels and those institutionalists
influenced by him assign an ample partake of bl
ame to union membership for the emergence and
sustenance of oligarchy : rather t
han the font and guardians of democracy,
the workers are its willing grave-
diggers. Michels argued that oligarchic tendencie
s of leaders are reinforced by what he termed “the
incompetence of the mass ”.
99
In this view, Michels was profoundly influenced by the social Darwinism
permeant in the bring of his contemporary
elite theorists like Pareto, Mosca and Le Bon.
100
Michels’
bifurcated sympathize of human nature, psychology and coke
onsciousness led him to believe that essential
47 101
Michels, 85, 107, 112.
102
Michels, 170; Beetham, “M
ichels and his Critics,” 97-8.
103
Robert Hoxie,
Trade Unionism in the United States
(New York: Russell and Russell, 1966), 178.
104
Lipset, “The Political Process in Trade Unions”, 220.
105
Michels, 105.
106
Michels, 83, 85, 87; Hoxie, 178.
differences existed between elites and masses. Howe
ver, they shared a common willingness to sacrifice
majority rule to satisfy other desires. The rank and file are seen to have profound intellectual deficiencies which make them incapable of taking on oligarchic leaders or participating in a
fully participatory democracy. For Michels, leaders and
members are mirror images : as the elites rise up in
organizations due to their natural superiority, rationality
and matter to in political affairs, so excessively are the masses
naturally uninterested in politics, politically immature
and uneducated, and thus unable to participate efficaciously.
101
For him, their fundamental ineffectuality is
apparent even when they occasionally revolt against
their leaders, for these attempts are “always
suppressed ” and ultimately irrelevant.
102
Hoxie argues that “the workers, untrained … cannot keep track of
affairs. ”
103
Lipset also emphasizes workers’ lack of polit
ical skills like communication and organization. He
points out that “ the average worker has
little opportunity or need to learn political skills. He is rarely, if ever,
called upon to make a language before a large group, to
put his thoughts down in writing, or to organize a
group ’ s activities. ”
104
The underdevelopment of these capacities in
the vast majority of union members
prevents the crystallization of discontented into
organized opposition or alternative leaderships.
Union members participate in their own subordinat
ion in ostensibly democratic organizations due to
their own psychological predilections ( different from thyroxine
hose of leaders), whether to self-gratification, laziness,
or a need to be instructed. The young “ find other ways of
employing their leisure; they are heedless, their
thoughts run in erotic channels ” while their
older counterparts are “weary and disillusioned”.
105
At the end
of the day, “ the proletarian can think only of perch, and of getting to bed in commodity meter ” and therefore is contentedness to “ leave the think to the officers. ”
106
The workers, Michels writes, des
ire to be led: “[t]hough it grumbles
48 107
Michels, 88.
108
Michels, 92.
109
Michels, 96-7.
110
Michels, 87.
111
Beetham, “Michels and his Critics,” 83.
112
Michels, 64.
occasionally, the majority is actually please to find pers
ons who will take the trouble to look after its affairs.
In the batch … there is an huge need for steering and guidance. This need is accompanied by a genuine fad for the leaders, who are regarded as heroes. ”
107
Such a view of leadership, venerated for their
sacrifices and casual martyrdom in the service
of the cause, produces uncritical gratitude and hero
worship amongst the members, and augments the leader
s’ sense of their permanence and indispensability
though continual reelection.
108
The workers’ “need to prostrate
themselves” before great ideals and great
individuals produces a kind of megalomania in drawing card
s, who come to believe in their infallibility.
109
furthermore, drawing from new writings in chromium
owd psychology at the time, Michels argues that
workers are vulnerable to the “ poisoning ” of non-rational appeals. Workers are only attract to public affairs when the shape preferably than the capacity is interest
ing to them. The mass is not interested in tactical or
theoretical questions ; rather, Michels writes, “ t
he ordinary members have a weakness for everything
which appeals to their eyes and for such spectacles as will always attract a agape crowd. ”
110
Michels also
emphasizes the function of oratory in attracting the chromium
owd’s interest and attention, which when combined with
the allegedly non-rational character of groups, makes the masses prone to emotionality and demagoguery.
111
Therefore, “the crowd … is always subject to suggestion, being readily influenced by the
eloquence of bang-up popular orators ; furthermore, direct
government by the people, admitting of no serious
discussions or heedful deliberations, greatly facilitates coups de mains of all kinds by men who are exceptionally bluff, energetic and adroit. ”
112
Such susceptibility, combined with the capacity for blind and
49 113
Michels, 90; Beetham, “M
ichels and his Critics,” 84.
114
William Leiserson,
American Trade Union Democracy
(New York: Columbia University Press, 1959), 66-8.
115
Herberg, 411.
116
Perlman, 266-8.
disorganized destruction, means not alone that the massachusetts
sses’ energies must be harnessed by elites, but also
that it is supremely easy to do so in the context of impart organizations.
113
finally, there is a materialist basis amongst the me
mbership for their willingness to give power over
to oligarchies. such views of union membership run
throughout the institutionalist
literature. Leiserson, for
example, argues that british labour party leaders are not entirely res
ponsible for the drive to autocracy in unions. Rather,
“ the demeanor and attitudes of the rank and file of
organized labor may be responsible for as serious
threats to freedom and majority rule in union organizations
as the desires of labor leaders for autocratic
powers. ” Leiserson agrees with Michels that worker
s “admire and rather prefer ‘strong’ leaders” who
“ deliver the goods ” ; as “ pragmatic sanction materialists ”, deoxythymidine monophosphate
he rank and file are thus “willing followers” and cooperate
in the creation of a bureaucracy which acts in its target.
114
Similarly, Herberg ar
gues that “members are
quite satisfy ” with union oligarchies “ vitamin a long as
things go well and they receive … proper service and
protection. ”
115
These views are in line with Perlman’s view
of workers as “opportunists”, not revolutionaries
or democrats, “ desiring to strike the best engage bargain potential. ”
116
V.
Conclusion: The Contradictory Pressures on Leaders and Members
The Michelsian and Trotskyist perspectives on the
relationship to democracy of trade union leaders
and members are very influential, well beyond the bounds of
their respective self-declared followers. Their
shared disapprobation of union leadership commands widespread attachment on both the right and the leftover, and provides many with an easily-digested answer to
trade union problems. Indeed there is much which
rings dependable. The action through which leaders come to
have and protect interests distinct from those of
their memberships, the catalogue of leadership stra
tagems to maintain control, the collapse of any
50 117
Therborn, 208.
118
David Beetham, “Michels, Roberto,” in
The Blackwell Encyclopaedia of Political Science
, ed V. Bogdanor, ed. (London:
Blackwell, 1991 ), 365. 119
Therborn, 189.
differentiation between the administration and the leadership, thymine
he use of left organizations as sources of working
class social mobility, the borrowing of timid rat
her than revolutionary strategies: these dynamics and
practices can be readily documented in workers ’ organizations. however, both of these frameworks suffer from
some important and common problems. Both use
categories – ‘ elite ’ and ‘ mass ’, ‘ trade union bureaucracy ’ and ‘ absolute and file ’ – which are homogeneous and overgeneralized, with little to no telescope for variation. Both are deterministic in a reductionist fashion, peculiarly with esteem to human nature and consci
ousness, although they differ on the essential causal
mechanism at exploit. On the contrary, there is a lot
historical evidence to show that the categories of
‘ leaders ’ and ‘ members ’ control much more diversity
than is claimed, variations which have important
organizational effects. As well, both groups are subjec
t to contradictory pressures, and as a result their
motivations and behaviour are vastly more complex.
Finally, both groups are shaped by the specificities of
their structural or organizational context, by what thymine
heir unions do and how they do it, and by capitalist social
relations. In other words, the phenomenon we observe in barter unions are not merely the leave of the interview of will or desire of either leaders or mem
bers. Let us develop these ideas in more detail.
The inevitable and universal fictional character of Michels ’ explanations is based on a defective methodology which renders him “ ineffective to deal with
social and historical variation.”
117
Michels’ focus on commonalities
rather than differences give his conclusions the charac
ter of a natural and positivist “iron law rather than as
a inclination that could with conscious effort be counteracted. ”
118
His psychological determinism and social
darwinism compounded such universalize : by rooting hawaii
s theory in the “basically invariant characteristics
of men ”, Michels rendered unnecessary any
explanation of divergent practices.
119
Leaders and members
possess inherently given capacities ( or incapacities )
and motivations which determine both their position in
51 120
Michels, 175; Beetham, “M
ichels and his Critics,” 95.
121
Therborn, 191; MacPherson, 86.
122
Michels, 369.
an organization adenine well as their behavior. In the fa
ce of phenomenological variations, Michels can assert
with assurance that their underlie motivations are the same : leaders are greedy and self-aggrandizing, the masses bungling and apathetic, and the entirety of
their actions are explicable in those terms.
Michels ’ essentialist and universalize, if
divided, understanding of human nature has several
implications. His “ crude and reductionist ” see of
the ideology and consciousness of leaders as “merely as
a reflection of personal ambition and office seeking ” a
llows Michels to claim that conflicts between leaders
have no meaning – differences in ideology, policy or st
rategy are distractions from the root of the matter,
which is the search for power.
120
As such, Michels ignores both the authoritative differences hidden by his categories of ‘ elite ’ and ‘ mass ’, vitamin a well as the possibility of learning or of consciously shaping human behaviour so as to develop effective organizational barriers to oligarchy. Michels ’ pessimism about the capacity of homo beings to be transformed by social forces and their own activeness over meter is most pronounce with esteem to the masses. In this, Michels was like all the elite theorists of the belated 19
th
century, who, Therborn argues, shared
“a profound fear and contempt of the
masses ” and based their views on “ an unobjective premise that the political capacities of the average person in a modern marketplace society are a specify datum. ”
121
While Michels agreed that if the mass was to be empowered in any room, social education would be absolutel
y necessary to raise their “intellectual level”; he
maintained that such efforts would remain
“within the limits of what is possible.”
122
Workers’ capacities for
democracy at the time Michels wrote were one
ndeed limited: given the absence of mass education and
literacy, members ’ capacities to understand the comple
xity of their own organization, let alone capitalist
political and economic processes, were restricted in
important ways. However, Michels extrapolates and
generalizes besides much on this footing. As such, it is
useful to keep in mind that
“human potentialities are not
52 123
Geras, 170. Emphasis in original.
124
Kelly, 49.
125
Kelly, 166.
126
Kelly, 50.
exhausted by any
given
activities of men, not by their
present
attitudes and needs, level of education, and
so on. ”
123
Trotsky ’ s outline suffers from alike problems
of overgeneralization.
Leaders and members are
sympathize in terms of a polarize
and pre-determined set of categor
ies wherein the leaders act to preserve their privileges under capitalism and puerto rico
event the otherwise revolutionary workers from
overthrowing capitalism. But this understand of
leadership is deeply economistic, and assumes that the
consciousness of leaders can be read off their economic placement in a relatively direct fashion.
124
queerly, however, such determination of consci
ousness holds only for leaders, whose ideas “are
passively determined by material interests such as ra
latively high salaries”; workers’ consciousness, on the
other hand, is “ actively determined thursday
rough practice, understood as struggle.”
125
This is a bifurcated theory
of awareness, which is dialectic for so
me people but unmediated and economically determined for
others. While Trotsky ’ s political commitments led him
to an assessment of workers’ capacities which is
diametrically opposed to Michels ’, his position are si
milarly pervaded by an essentialism which defines
a priori
the nature of leadership ( ‘essentially conservative ‘ )
and the rank-and-file (‘essentially revolutionary’, but
always held back by the leadership ), and which obviates
the need to explore the actual positions, actions,
and awareness of these groups, however
nuanced or contradictory they may be.
126
Trotsky’s framework
therefore results in a taxonomic overassessment of
both the revolutionary potential of workers and the
undemocratic conservatism of leaders. Such an apprai
sal is contradicted by much historical evidence
which indicates the universe of both revolutionary and cons
ervative leaders, and of both radical and conservative
memberships .
53 127
Mills,
The New Men of Power
, particularly Chapters 4 and 5.
128
J. Barbash,
The Practice of Unionism
(New York: Harper, 1956), 371-2.
129
Lipset, “The Political Process in Trade Unions,” 236.
130
Stepan-Norris, 340.
131
Lipset, “The Political Process in Trade Unions,” 236. Of cour
se, the exception for Lipset ar
e former Communist leaders, who,
though motivated by a calling, are in his position more likely to us
e “the organizational machinery” in
“ruthless” and “dictatoria
l”
fashion in decree to remain in ability. Differences in the background, character, and i
deological orientations of leaders and members are
relevant to their motivations and behavior within the organization.
127
For instance, there are those who are
motivated by a “ will to leadership ”, but as Barbash argues, it is rare to find union leaders whose sole determination is the attainment of domination for its
own sake. Instead, “the purpose and the power are
inseparable. ”
128
The nature of this purpose varies, and has specific effects. Lipset, for instance,
distinguishes between the “ called ” and the “ careeris
t” leader. Those who enter the labour movement
merely for mobility, monetary rewards, and personal
status are much less likely to be concerned with
membership engagement, except on a strictly instrum
ental level. Leaders motivated by a sense of social
mission, on the other hand, are more likely to be “ a
ccessible to the membership … more concerned with
violations of a union ethic of military service to the
membership, and have greater
personal integrity.”
129
While they
may not constantly follow democratic practices, they are
more likely to feel constrained by their ideological
commitments and prevented from behaving as full-blown o
ligarchs. Similarly, Stepan-Norris’ research on
CIO unions with extremist leadership in the 1940s dem
onstrates that these unions had minimized the gap
between leaders ’ salaries and those
of the workers they represented.
130
Thus “the different calls that have
led people into the parturiency apparent motion make for
significantly different types of behaviour.”
131
unlike kinds of membership besides produce variat
ions in internal dynamics. The organization of
work and of different occupations has an significant effect on workers ’ capacities, their ideas and norms, and their feelings about themselves, not to mention thei
r relationships with fellow workers. The content of
exercise skills and the extent of control condition over work have
an impact not only on workers’ capacities, but also on
54 132
Pearlin and Richards; Lipset, “The Politic
al Process in Trade Unions”; Hurd.
133
Muste, 334.
134
Mills,
The New Men of Power
, 10.
their self-concept and sense of entitlement and ability to
participate in union affairs. Studies which have
identified such “ occupational sources of union majority rule ”
tend to locate the requisite characteristics in
higher-status, highly skilled or professional bring like printing, acting, teach, and journalism.
132
While
there is a diagonal here which inappropriately associ
ates workers in mass production industries with a
aptness for submission to authority, the stress of
the analysis on the way work shapes the views and
capacities of members is utilitarian. Both union leaders and members are besides subject to
opposing pressures, such that conflicts of
pastime within unions are not always manifested in term
s of this simple, binary opposition. As Muste points
out, leaders want democratic support but besides to step in
and direct the course of discussion. Similarly,
members want ‘ results ’ deoxyadenosine monophosphate well as the opportunity to express their views.
133
Mills also highlights the mixed
nature of leadership itself : “ [ metric ton ] he labor drawing card is
an army general and a parliam
entary debater, a political
foreman and an entrepreneur, a rebel and a martinet. ”
134
These multiple roles and interests imply different
kinds of behavior which is frequently mutually exclus
ive, and hence the direction leaders and members will take
international relations and security network ’ deoxythymidine monophosphate constantly clear
a priori
.
last, leaders and members are engaged in a mutually-conditioning relationship, and the effects of one on the other are not always visible in spectacula
r ways. For instance, a complete victory of the
membership over the leaders is not gas constant
equired for an impact to be felt; opposition
does
military unit leaders to act in response, in ways that may be suppressive or cooptive, but which ultimately does lead to some change in policy, social organization or process. In other words, the “ ma
sses” are not “inert political clay, without self-activity”;
preferably, their interventions do “ limit and influence ”
decision-makers, if not always in the way that is
55 135
Leo Panitch, “Elites, Classes, and Power in Canada,” in
Canadian Politics in the 1990s
, eds. M. Whittington and G. Williams
( Toronto : Nelson Canada,1990 ), 189. 136
Michels, 371.
137
Alvin Gouldner quoted in Hyman,
Marxism
, 33.
138
Richard Hyman, “The Politics of Workplace Trade Unioni
sm: Recent Tendencies and Some Problems for Theory,” in
The
political Economy of Industrial Relations : theory and Practice in a cold Climate
(London: MacMillan, 1989),157-8; Beetham,
“ Michels and his Critics, ” 98. 139
Beetham, “Michels, Roberto,” 365. Michels
of course admits this is possible, but
dismisses the idea that leadership change is
somehow indicative of democracy. For him,
the circulation of elites does not distur
b the domination of the mass by leadership.
See Michels, 343. intended.
135
Indeed, Michels himself admits that “the democratic currents of history resemble successive
waves ” which are repeatedly unwrap by oligarchy.
136
However, if oligarchical leadership is so powerful, and
the membership so impotent, from whence do thes
e “democratic currents” issue? As Alvin Gouldner
astutely points out, “ if oligarchic waves repeatedly
wash away the bridges of democracy, this eternal
recurrence can happen lone because men doggedly rebuild them after each flood. Michels chose to brood on only one view of this process, neglecting to consider this other side. ”
137
In light of this, a view of
the membership incapable of influencing the leadership
or the direction of the
organization is unwarranted.
therefore, the categories of “ barter union bureaucracy ”
and “rank and file”, like that of “mass” and
“ elite ”, hide a much as they reveal. Models prem
ised on this division ignore the multiple divisions and
tensions within each of these categories and the
mutually conditioning relationship between “leader” and
“ member ”.
138
What is most notable in both the Michelsian
and Trotskyist perspectives is the great deal of
conscious and effective power ascribed to union elites
. However, there are many problems with this
premise. Leaders aren ’ deoxythymidine monophosphate always competent, better organi
zed or able to assimilate challenges: they are
occasionally turned out of function.
139
But more than this, elites don’t and aren’t always free to act according to
their personal wills. As Panitch argues with res
pect to elite analysis in general, “too much credence [is
given ] to the autonomous ability of ‘ elites ’ to make
unconstrained decisions.” Instead, “[a]uthority positions,
positions of control, set structural limits to what
individuals can do in occupying decision-making roles within
56 140
Panitch, “Elites, Classes and Power in Canada,” 189.
institutions. ”
140
One might add that individuals are also
empowered and encouraged to act in other ways
shaped by their geomorphologic localization. As such,
the question then becomes one of understanding not only the
motivations of leaders, but besides the way that
institutions have been shaped (or might be shaped) to
encourage or terminus ad quem certain kinds of leadership and member
ship activity. It is to an examination of how union
functions perform this structuring character that we now turn .
57 1
Hemingway, 3-4.
2
Derek Bok and John Dunlop,
Labor and the American Community
(New York: Simon and Schuster, 1970), 70.
chapter 2 : Rethinking Union Democracy II :
Union Functions, Structures and Class Formation
As we have seen, it is not enough to study thymine
he attributes and behaviours of individuals within
unions. Though there are important insights to reta
in from the discussion of leaders and members, we
must be careful not to assume that social practices ar
e merely the result of individual will. Rather, people
dissemble within the context of institutions which struct
ure their behaviour, often independently of what they would
wish. In detail, the function of organizati
ons has a potent influence over the norms, goals and
strategies which are deemed lawful for individuals to
pursue, whatever their propensities. As such, we
turning to explanations which emphasize the function that
trade union functions play in shaping democratic and
oligarchic practices. I.
The Structuring Effects of Union Functions
The most cosmopolitan interpretation of the argument that union functions impose specific practices refers to the tactics which are necessary for a “ active arrangement ”. A very common explanation given for the bearing of autocracy in union structures is the indigence to
maintain discipline in the context of a collective
struggle : some kind of structure is needed to ens
ure (through both positive and negative incentives) that
everyone is working towards the accomplishment of common
goals. Insofar as unions seek to “protect [their]
members against external parties ”, whoever they ma
y be, they require solidar
ity, the subordination of
“ individual sake and autonomy to the collective good ”, and hence discipline.
1
In other words, unions’
very functions necessitate undemocratic forms of bury
nal organization. What varies are conceptions of the
union ’ s goals and the prescriptive value placed on them relative to democracy.
2
This theme of fight creating a
disciplinary imperative is particu
larly prominent in the work of
some socialists and radical labor organizers. For them, the
class struggle
imposes a set of imperative
58 3
Muste, 332.
4
Michels, 78-79.
5
Ibid.
6
Leiserson, 70.
tactical considerations on workers ’ organizations, fo
rcing them to adopt a military model. Working class
parties and unions exist in conditions of “ latent warf
are” which continually threatens their organizational
survival. consequently, as Muste argues, the union is “ a
fighting instrument” which “exhibits … a tendency to
take on the fictional character of armed forces and
warfare in its structure and activities.”
3
To fight effectively,
Michels contends, a hierarchical form of decisi
on-making and implementation is required to ensure
“ punctuality of decision, integrity of
command, and strictness of discipline.”
4
Centralization is thus posited as
the prerequisite for coordination of policy and action,
and for quick and effective mobilization of members.
such “ conditions of war ” are not propitious for dem
ocracy. As in military organizations, democratic
calculation of the members is impossible ; in this
vein, Michels quotes Lassalle, one of the original leaders
of the german SPD, who argued that “
[t]he rank and file … must follow their chief blindly, and the whole
constitution must be like a forge in the hands of its president. ”
5
The presumed tactical effectiveness of
such arrangement in the face of threat to organiza
tional survival is also said to produce a willingness
amongst the absolute and file to acquiesce to centraliz
ed leadership. As Leiserson points out, the insecurity
caused by the fear of external attack creates condi
tions in which oligarchic practices are endured, for
differently “ members would hardly be uncoerced to grant
arbitrary powers to their executives and support and
approve those who assume such powers were it not fo
r the persistent fears that their unions were in danger
of destruction or weakening to the point of ineffectiveness. ”
6
In other words, it is the dire situation in which
unions find themselves, quite than the power-seeking
of leaders or the apathy of
members, which creates
oligarchy. many institutionalists and some Marxists argue that it is the specific nature of
collective bargaining
as a action of conflict mediation which forces
unions to develop bureaucratic forms of discipline and
59 7
S.M. Lipset, M.A. Trow, and J.S. Coleman
, Union Democracy: The Internal Politi
cs of the International Typographical Union
( New York : The Free Press, 1956 ), 9. 8
Kaufman, 203.
9
Richard Hyman and Richard Fryer, “Trade Uni
ons: Sociology and Political Economy,” in
Trade Unions under Capitalism
, eds. T.
Clarke and L. Clements ( London : Fontana Collins, 1977 ), 160. 10
Lester, 23.
11
Lipset, “The Political Process in
Trade Unions,” 218; John Commons,
Industrial Government
(New York: Macmillan, 1921).
administration. The very work of corporate bargai
ning is bureaucratizing as it implies the need to make
and enforce complex agreements with employers. This
requires unity and discipline vis à vis subordinate
units, bolstered by demands for “ responsible union leadership ” from management.
7
Bargaining also
involves complex legal and economic issues which requires specialized expertness not widely held by rank- and-file workers. That is, effective collective bar
gaining generates a series of technical-administrative
pressures, and requires a particular kind of discipline
and knowledge, all of which have deleterious effects
on internal union democracy. As many of the institutionalists points out,
successful collective bargaining requires unity and
solidarity amongst the members, which is much transla
ted in practice into “a high degree of centralized
control by the leaders. ”
8
The need to present a united front to the
employer leads many to view internal
dissent an important obstacle to overcome, a problem
to contain. The maintenance of unity at the expense
of democracy may be particularly crucial in unions with diverse memberships, and consequently whose “ dicker strategy may require a judicious reconciliation of divergent sectional interests. ”
9
The pressure to expand the coupling ’ s penis
ship and bargaining coverage also generates
tendencies towards centralized oligarchic control.
Unions pursue growth because, as Lester points out,
there is a widespread, if naive, notion that
“size and power are directly correlated.”
10
Growth strategies may
have a rational basis, however. In industries with
regional, industry-wide or national product and labour
markets or with much competitive press, thymine
here is a compelling need to expand bargaining coverage to
more and more workplaces, then as to remove the non-union advantage.
11
This may take the form of pattern
60 12
Lester, 24.
13
Bok and Dunlop, 156.
14
Michels, 67-71.
15
Bok and Dunlop, 156.
16
Michels, 70.
17
Lester, 24.
dicker, a rehearse which besides contributes to
centralization because of the need to develop and apply a
common program to different workplaces or employers.
12
Expansion beyond the union’s traditional
legal power may besides be required for plain organizational
survival, especially if a union’s original industries
are in decline.
13
This strategy of growth, usually via organi
zing drives and amalgamations with other already
existing unions, is intended to preserve and increase
collective bargaining effectiveness for all but also
creates organizations excessively big and excessively complex for me
mbers to control effectively through participatory
democratic means. The natural and spontaneous response to growing size and complexity is, in the Michelsian position, bureaucratization. boastfully organizations require specializ
ed elites working in a centrally governed division of
parturiency in ordering to achieve their goals efficiently.
14
As growth often brings with it the additional problems of
an increasingly divers membership, working in a
variety of industries, this increased complexity
compounds the necessitate for home functional specialization, delegating, and bureaucratization.
15
The intricacy
of inner structures makes it impossible for mem
bers either to understand the whole or to exert control
over it, and this “ renders necessity what is called expert leadership. ”
16
The demand for speciate expertness is further reinforced by the increasingly complicated and legalistic nature of the collective bargaining proce
ss. As Lester argues, the character of collective
bargaining “ has tended to be increasingly actual, statis
tical and full of economic reasoning, so that the
amateurish negotiator feels … at a disadvantage. ”
17
As a result, there is a need for experts who understand
the conditions and specific problems faced by each diligence they deal with, adenine well as specialists in “ job
61 18
Ibid., 24.
19
Michels, 70, 72.
20
Wainwright, 214.
21
Coleman, 209.
22
Lipset, “The Political Process in Trade Unions,” 219.
evaluation, time-and-motion study, pensions, medi
cal and hospital care, and supplementary employment
benefits ”, subjects which are “ broadly beyond the trai
ning and know-how of persons at the local level.”
18
The closely cosmopolitan consensus in the literature
is thus that there exists a negative correlation
between union size and complexity on the one handwriting, and
internal democracy on the other. The pressure
for large-scale organizations to develop rational so far hier
archical bureaucratic structures leads not merely to
a division of labor but the control of specify centrum
l elites over the entire organization. This expertise
is, for Michels, no mere supplement to members ’ cognition ; it rather usurp members ’ power to determine policy, and “ emancipates ” leaders from democratic operate.
As a result of their technical and political ability,
then, leaders “ acquire a freedom of actinium
tion which [they] ought not to possess.”
19
According to Hilary
Wainwright, Michels and others are describing what
they believe to be “an unavoidable ‘Taylorism’ in
political administration ”, with its intendant concent
ration of organizational power in the hands of a
professional elite.
20
It is, for some, the very nature of bureaucratic decision-making which is undemocratic:
as Coleman argues, “ bureaucracy involves a ‘ non-re
sponsive leadership’ that assumes a considerable
degree of omniscience as to what is best and attainabl
e for the members, that restricts access of its
opponents to the members, and that perpetuates a particular system of
superordination and subordination
through the growth of a relatively shut condition arrangement. ”
21
Thus, while bureaucratic organization may
permit unions to be more administratively effective and
effective in collective bargaining, “the greater the
bureaucratization of an arrangement, the less the pot
ential for membership influence over policy.”
22
But the undemocratic shock of collective legal profession
gaining on the relationship between leaders and
members flows not merely from its technical natur
e. It is argued that the acceptance of “contractual
62 23
V.I. Lenin, “What Is to Be Done?” in
The Lenin Anthology
, ed. R. Tucker (New York: W.W Norton & Co, 1975), 37; Anne
Showstack Sassoon,
Gramsci’s Politics
, 2
nd
ed. (Minneapolis: University
of Minnesota Press, 1987), 40-41.
24
Hoxie, 182. Almost exactly the same language is used by Mills (
The New Men of Power
, 105). Of course, Hoxie believes such
moderation is a positive development. unionism ” and “ industrial legality ” itself has ideological effects on leaders which shape their practices and consequently their kinship to the rank and file.
Participation in the collective bargaining system not
lone integrates unions into the system of capitalist radius
eproduction, it implies the ideological acceptance of the
legitimacy of employers ’ rights of ownership and inte
rests in profitability and wo
rkers’ subordinate place in
the labor process and the economy in general. In
the view of both Lenin and Gramsci, trade unions’
employment in the economic fight and
collective bargaining signifies acceptance of ideological terrain
defined by capitalist product relations – the division of labor, businessperson legality and the definition of the actor as seller of tug power under capitalism – as
evidenced in their struggle over the price of labour
world power and not the commodification of labor per southeast.
23
Inherent in the system is the idea that mutually
beneficial agreements which ‘ balance ’ the interests of
employers and workers can be made. As such,
primacy is placed on the initiation and maintenance of
a peaceful, orderly, long-term relationship between
union and management. thus, battle in the collectiv
e bargaining system is conservatizing. Given
that union leaders are the direct participants in this kinship with the employer, they are most directly subject to these ideological pressures ; as Hoxie points out, their employment in collective bargaining “ tend [ randomness ] to make the leaders bourgeois. Re
sponsibility sobers them. As soon as they engage in
negotiations they realize the power of
the employers, and the limitations
in the ability of the employer to
meet demands. ”
24
Leaders ’ behaviour towards their memberships
is fundamentally shaped by the realities of
contractual unionism. They become “ managers of phonograph record
ontent” whose primary responsibilities are to police
the enforcement of the collective
agreement, and in particular to discipline and control members who refuse
63 25
Mills,
The New Men of Power
, 9; Friedman, 21.
26
Lipset, “The Political Process in Trade Unions”, 217.
27
Mills,
The New Men of Power
, 119.
28
Hyman, “The Politics of Wo
rkplace Trade Unionism”, 150.
29
See Don Wells, “The Origins of Canada’s
Wagner Model of Industrial Relations: T
he United Auto Workers in Canada and the
suppression of Rank and
File Unionism, 1936-1953,”
Canadian Journal of Sociology
20, no. 2 (1995): 192-224, and Daniel
Drache and Harry Glasbeek,
The Changing Workplace: Reshaping C
anada’s Industrial Relations System
(Toronto: James
Lorimer & Company Publishers, 1992 ) for applicat
ion of these arguments to the Canadian context.
30
Beetham, “Michels and his Critics”, 84.
31
Michels, 177-79, 183; Beetham, “Michels, Roberto,” 365; Lipset, “Michels’
Theory of Political Parties,” 18.
to adhere to contracts or who seek to act in washington
ys outside the bounds of the legally prescribed process.
25
The continuance of a bargaining relationship with megabyte
anagement is premised on the provision of “responsible
union leadership ”, defined by employers as the leaders ’ willingness to moderate demands, enforce agreements and restrain spont
aneous outbursts of militancy.
26
Mills describes the trade-off entailed in this
agreement : “ [ thymine ] o fasten peaceful plants and profitabl
e enterprises in a stable economy, the leaders of
british labour party will deliver a responsible, which is to say, a
well-disciplined union of contented workers in return for
junior partnership in the productive work, secu
rity for the union, and higher wages for the workers of
industry. ”
27
As a result, leaders are forced to assess member
ship activism in terms of its impact on the
union ’ south ( and their own ) ongoing kinship with management.
28
These considerations come to displace
the members ’ needs and interests. Rather than repr
esenting the members to the employer, union leaders
are said to impose the employer ’ mho needs on the members.
29
How are these insights about the shape effects
of union functions related to the previous
discussion of the fictional character of union leaders and members ?
The Michelsian framework uses these ideas to
reinforce their argument regarding t
he inevitability of oligarchy in unions. For Michels and Lipset, leaders’
control of bureaucratic administration, for whatever roentgen
eason, provides them with the political-organizational
tools to fulfil their congenital desires and maintain a bag on office.
30
Unparalleled access to information, expertness, coordination, and communication allows drawing card
s to assimilate or fend off challenges if and when
they arise, and with techniques that range from hyper-procedural to repressive.
31
In other words, there is a
64 32
Michels, 221; Beetham, “Michels and his Critics”, 87.
33
Kaufman, 205.
34
Hoxie, 179.
35
Kelly, 57.
convergence of psychological and organizational needs. No
t only do “the internal structural needs of the
administration and its care come to impose their
own logic”, displacing the membership’s goals, but
leaders besides increasingly identify personally with
these requirements, with
the organization itself.
32
In other
words, the addition of the structuring function of marriage
functions, and collective bargaining in particular, merely
deepens the Michelsians ’ pessimism. Managerialists would agree that the charac
ter of leaders and members converges with
organizational needs to create oligarchies. however,
this is embraced, or at least appreciated for the
‘ positivist ’ results it proffers, namely “ greater
organizational stability and moderation in the conduct of
bargaining. ”
33
This position is based on the Michelsian view
of members as “ignorant and impulsive”, unable
to appreciate the subtleties of dicker or the cons
traints faced by the employer, but managerialists are
not plagued by the Michelsian commiseration.
34
The Trotskyist scene of leaders and members can besides accommodate these arguments about the effect of “ industrial legality ” and collective bargaini
ng. The pressures on leaders to preserve an ongoing
bargaining relationship with an employer, to secure
the union’s organizational integrity and survival, and to
specify crucial craft union action as master rat
her than activist are real
. However, the important
nuance here is that such orientations do not flow
merely (or even primarily) from the consciousness of
button-down leaders. rather, these pressures emanate
from the more general context of capitalism. As
such, the Trotskyist ‘solution ‘ to bureaucratic conserva
tism, namely the alteration of the material conditions
of the leadership, could never wholly solve the public relations
oblem “so long as collective bargaining and collective
agreements dominated the wo
rld of trade unionism.”
35
As Hyman argues, such a model “help[s] explain
why union officials, though much politically and socially
more advanced or progressive than many of their
65 36
Hyman, “The Politics of Wo
rkplace Trade Unionism,” 150.
37
Hyman,
Marxism
, 84.
38
Hyman,
Marxism
, 33.
39
Muste, 332-35.
40
Muste, 333.
41
Johnathan Zeitlin, “‘Rank and Filism’ in
British Labour History: A Critique,”
International Review of Social History
34 (1989): 60-
61. members, frequently perform a conservative role in
periods of membership activism and struggle.”
36
however, while there is no question that trade marriage
leaderships face constant pressure to become
incorporated into capitalistic baron structures, Trot
sky assumed that leaders embraced their role as agents
of capitalist discipline. This can only be assum
ed if one adopts the Michelsian
position that leaders are
wholly independent of the rank and file.
37
Instead, as Hyman points out, the extent to which leaders
act to discipline members is variable star and needs to be analysed.
38
There are, in fact, severe problems with the washington
y that collective bargaining is portrayed as having
merely conservatizing and oligarchic effects.
Such an emphasis assumes that union functions are
homogeneous and non-contradictory. On the contra
ry, though unions are collective bargaining agencies,
they besides have other functions which result in cont
radictory pressures. Muste, for instance, emphasized
that unions are not nonreversible : they
are “armies” but also have the
structure of the “democratic town
meeting ” in which the “ generals ” argon
e elected and “the declaration of war and … the terms of the peace” are
voted on. Unions must both “ crusade and hash out ”. H
ence, due to their multiple functions, unions have a
“ divided soul ” which can not be escaped, and which pr
events the wholesale adoption of either extreme.
39
Unions ’ self-conception as power for industrial democra
cy means that they are “barred from developing in its
members the unquestioning obedience, the iron discipline,
the fixed routine, that characterizes and army.”
40
Herberg calls this situation the “ majority rule dilemma ”.
Zeitlin also argues that there is an ongoing tension
between confrontation and negotiation.
41
66 42
Hyman,
Marxism
, 73.
43
Perry Anderson, “The Limits and Possibilities of Trade Union Action,” in
Trade Unions under Capitalism
, eds. T. Clarke and L.
Clements ( London : Fontana Collins, 1977 ), 334. 44
Mills,
The New Men of Power
, 9.
45
Mills,
The New Men of Power
, 8-9.
46
Coleman, 213.
Unions are ambivalent organizations because, as a mean to exert power for workers over or against das kapital, they are underwrite by a democratic
rationale which legitimizes in certain circumstances
membership control over the leadership. Members do
respond to what are seen as egregious violations of
democratic process, placing limits on how far leaders can go in the pursuit of interests which are at odds with those of the membership. In early words, ther
e is a two-way system of power in unions, which defines
the legalize moments when leaders and mem
bers can exert control over each other.
42
The boundaries of
these relations of control are besides subject
to controversy and ongoing attempts at renegotiation.
Unions ’ relationship to capitalism more generally is
also contradictory. As Anderson argues, “trade
unions are dialectically both an resistance to capitalis
m and a component of it. For they both resist the
given unequal distribution of income within the societ
y by their wage demands, and ratify the principle of an
inadequate distribution by their universe, which impli
ed as its complementary opposite that of management.”
43
In early words, unions are both functional for capitalist parturiency markets as a contractor of labor and are rebellious against the prerogatives of private property and unilateral management dominance.
44
As a result, it is
ill-timed to interpret Mills ’ word picture of british labour party
leaders’ role as ‘managers of discontent’ as merely
involving the inhibition of rate and file activeness, as both the Michelsian and Trotskyist versions would have it. rather, leaders are sometimes required to “ w
hip up the opinion and activity of the rank and file”
against the employer, at other times to “ sit on it,
exploiting it to maintain a continuous organization.”
45
Even
in the context of institutionalized
collective bargaining, this tension c
an be observed, as leaders often wish
for a free hired hand in negotiations, and however understand the power that an angry and mobilize membership can provide.
46
As Hyman puts it, the union leader’s constant attempts “to sustain a delicate balance between
67 47
Hyman,
Marxism
, 37.
grievance and satisfaction, between activism and quiescence ”
means that it is not useful to beat all life out
of the membership.
47
This ambivalence thus provides counter
vailing pressures against the conservatizing
and undemocratic tendencies of unions ’
collective bargaining function.
Trade unions are shaped both by tendencies to be radi
cal and democratic, as well as conservative
and bureaucratic. Rather than taking as our starting
point the assumption that union functions inevitably
produce irremovable oligarchies, we rather need
to develop an understanding of how unions’ multiple
functions interact with each other, and encourage triiodothyronine
he development and ascendency of one or other side of
the equation. This leads us to ask whether marriage degree fahrenheit
unctions impose the same organizational architecture on
all unions. indeed, it is quite easy to observe that
there are important variations in union constitutions,
internal political dynamics, and structure. Do thes
e structural variations have any moderating impact on
oligarchic tendencies ? We will now explore in moment
re detail the writings of those who argue that union
democracy can be kept alive through the consci
ous design of political institutions.
II.
Union Structures: Built for Democracy?
There is no doubt that some union structures are speed of light
onsidered more ‘democratic’ than others, if only
at an impressionist flat. however, U.S. social
scientists have attempted to provide some empirical basis
for these impressions. In their work, much att
ention has been paid by some to the content of union
constitutions in order to ascertain which may be said to sustain democratic dynamics. Examining the ball aspects of unions has been the focus of the lambert
egalist institutionalists in particular, but Michelsians
have besides examined such matters. Socialists, on the other hand, have tended to neglect examination of the formal bases of union democracy, both in theory and in
practice. As Edelstein and Warner point out, this
absence has been justified either by
a critique of representative forms of governance as “parliamentarist”,
68 48
Edelstein and Warner, 56.
49
Ibid., 55.
50
Seidman, 22; Leiserson, 110-114; Edelstein and
Warner, 29, 5; Stepan-Norris, 476; Alice Cook,
Union Democracy: Practice
and Ideal
(Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1963).
51
Zeitlin and Stepan-Norris, 252.
or by an anti-utopianism rooted in Marx ’ s horizon that
organizational forms will emerge from practice and not
from design.
48
While these are important cautions, the resu
lt has been a real paucity of Marxist thinking on
democratic organization. As such, we must turn to
the institutionalists and the Michelsians for insights on
the implications of unlike organizational forms for democracy. consistent with their commitment to representativ
e democracy, most legalists set out a very liberal
set of measures which are meant to guarantee polit
ical equality of opportunity and access; Edelstein and
Warner appropriately characterize this as
a “civil libertarian” approach to union democracy.
49
Typically,
such approaches consider some or all of the followi
ng constitutional measures as crucial indicators of
majority rule : freedom of actor’s line, particularly the right
to criticize union leaders, administration and policies;
exemption of fabrication, namely the mighty to organize oppos
ition groups or factions; equality of franchise and
of access to elected position ; exemption from discriminati
on, especially if one is a member of a minority group;
and the right to due process, a fair and unprejudiced tria
l, and the right of appeal. In addition, members should
be able to exercise these rights without concern of
reprisal, whether through violence or intimidation.
50
In other
words, legalists assess a union ’ second democracy according the bearing or absence of a constitutional “ bill of rights ” for union members. Legalists besides focus on
the type and extent of leadership powers, including
powers of date, trust territory, suspension and ejection. There are, however, important lim
itations to legalist constitutional analyses, which are recognized
even by some of its more contemporary practitioners.
Stepan-Norris and Zeitlin, for instance, point out that
certain constitutional guarantees or “ basic freedoms ” argon
e “indispensable” if “active participation” is to be
sustained, but not sufficient for democracy.
51
While these rights “provide the possibility for democracy, they
69 52
Stepan-Norris, 476.
53
Edelstein and Warner, 63.
54
Lipset, Trow and Coleman, 4.
55
Ibid., 3. Lipset, Trow and Coleman argue that the failure of
perfectly constructed consti
tutions designed in 1919 and designed
to guarantee majority rule in Germany, for example, demonstr
ates amply the naivete of the legalist position.
56
Ibid., 8.
never ensure it. ”
52
Similarly, Edelstein and Warner usefully
consult to nominally democratic structures as carrying “ democratic potential ” : while not claimi
ng a direct correspondence between rules and practices,
they point out that some arrangements have
a greater capacity for democracy than others.
53
Lipset, however, is more emphatic in his review
of legalism. Lipset, Trow and Coleman argue that
coupling members “ have learned … that the clauses in t
he constitutions which set forth the machinery for
translating membership interests and sentiments
into organizational purpose and action bear little
relationship to the actual political processe
s which determine what their organizations do.”
54
They suggest
that to believe differently puts one in a nautical mile
nority position, and even makes one a bit naive.
55
They claim that
“ with very few meaning exceptions all the efforts
to reduce oligarchical control [in unions] through formal
mechanisms have failed. ”
56
A concenter on the letter of the police does not expl
ain the gap which often exists between nominal
democracy and actual oligarchy. Nor is it enough to me
rely enumerate constitutional provisions which are
not even nominally democratic ; such an access may demonstrate the presence of oligarchic tendencies, but does not account for how or why consti
tutions came to be this way. Therefore, it is
necessary to look at factors other than constituti
onal measures to explain the presence of democracy or
oligarchy. As a result, for some institutionalists t
he actual extent of leadership accountability in unions is
more crucial. Rather than taking the constitution ’ sulfur
word for it, these researchers examine the factors,
whether formal, sociological, historic or ideological, which actually result in the membership ‘ holding leaders accountable ’. In such perspectives, the focu
s is on identifying how to ‘measure’ accountability, and
on establishing the conditions which sustain the indicato
rs of accountability. Competitive elections, defined
70 57
Hemingway; Edelstein and Warner, 63 passim.
58
Edelstein and Warner, 66.
59
Ibid., 63.
60
Taft, 41 passim.
61
Edelstein and Warner, 65-6.
62
Lipset, Trow and Coleman, 8.
by the level of quarrelsomeness and measured by how centiliter
ose an election is, are seen as a primary indication
of leadership accountability.
57
Close elections, it is claimed, indicate that competitors are operating in
conditions of relative equality, and that there are no taxonomic or structurally-produced biases.
58
Edelstein
and Warner in particular take a conventional organizational
approach to the question of elections, and investigate
which structures are able to “ chromium
eate equal competitors for leadership.”
59
A refer measure of leadership accountability is
the frequency with which incumbent leaders are
actually replaced. Taft, for exemplify, examined the francium
equency with which the national executive officers in
U.S. unions were defeated between 1900 and 1948, with
a particular emphasis on the president. His
results show that, over this period, union presidents faced fewer and fewer challenges, and rarely left office except by their own option.
60
These findings may give an excessively pessimistic impression, however, specially if the focus is entirely on the exceed officer. Edelstein and Wa
rner argue that a concentration on pr
esidential elections which involve
incumbents is besides pin down, and can mask extensive electo
ral competition for lower posts and for the top spot
when it becomes vacant. electoral struggles over di
fferent positions can be part of longer-term strategies
for building the persuasiveness to compete for the presidency,
and as such indicate a level of contentiousness not
observed if presidential contests are tallied up in isolat
ion. In that sense, unions which fill positions below
the top officeholder with close elections might be cons
idered democratic, or at least “non-oligarchic”.
61
In their attempts to explain the low level of
leadership accountability in unions via elections, to
discover “ why … confrontation groups find it so unmanageable to survive ”
62
, some have sought to elaborate the
cozy factors which might sustain organize factions. There is no question that factionalism in general is
71 63
Muste, 332.
64
Mitchell quoted in Taft, 59.
65
Lipset, Trow and Coleman, 15.
66
Ibid., 401.
a deeply contradictory phenomenon. It is believed by some to be “ a gestural of life ”,
63
and one of the conditions
which makes accountability and hence majority rule possibl
e. Others, however, emphasize the destructive
nature of factionalism in undermining a union ’ second integrity and
cohesion. Distinctions between different kinds of
factionalism and their varying capacity to contribute
to union democracy are thus made in the literature.
On the footing of his analysis of the Internati
onal Typographical Union, Lipset emphasizes the
special function that an “ institutionalized resistance ” pl
ays in making electoral contests relevant, without
undermining the coherence and stability of the organization as
a whole. For some reason, as Taft points out,
the ITU is characterized by factions which engage in “ vigorous ” electoral contests, but seem to “ keep in mind the necessity of preserving inviolat
e the strength and int
egrity of the union.”
64
As an preach of pluralist theory, Lipset makes
institutionalized
opposition central to his conception of union democracy. He
argues that, just as in ‘ mass societies ’ more generally
, citizens can only participate effectively in large-scale
organizations when members of sub-groups. Otherwise
, they will remain “atomized” individuals unable to
resist the authority of the “ controllers of the penny
ral power apparatus”. “Structured sub-groups” are the
footing for “ relatively independent and autonomous kernel
s of power” and sustain ongoing political conflict.
65
These groups in bend foster ongoing engagement : onc
e established, a two-party system is “one of the
principal opportunities and stimulation for engagement in
politics”, since parties
“attempt to activate the
apathetic ” so as to win world power.
66
However, in order to foster democratic practices and values, such as
tolerance for other opinions and deference for minority rhode island
ghts, and to “maintain a basic loyalty to the larger
organization ”, these sub-groups must exist in a relative balance, with none “ strong enough to gain complete power ”. Some have argued that factionalism at
least modifies the ‘iron law of oligarchy’: “even
though the success of one faction over another [ may
not] guarantee democracy … the continuing factional
72 67
Gordon Smith, “Iron Law of Oligarchy,” in
The Blackwell Encyclopaedia of Political Science
, ed. V. Bogdanor (London:
Blackwell, 1991 ), 299. 68
Lipset, Trow and Coleman, 13, 15.
69
Lipset, “The Political Process in Trade Unions,” 219, 221.
clamber ensures that no one gr
oup will wield permanent power.”
67
For Lipset, however, the two-party
system is by definition democracy, and his project is
thus to uncover the factors which lead to the
emergence and nutriment of such institutionalized gr
oups or “political parties” within trade union
structures.
68
decidedly, the universe of opposition is lin
ked to constitutional guarantees to members:
dissenters must feel that their rights to organize and
participate in union politics are protected. However, to
possess a correct is not the lapp as being able to ac
t on that right in an effective manner. Lipset thus
identifies several factors outside of constitutions
which affect whether and members can operationalize
their ball rights. There are at least two
important extraorganizational sources of support for
commit factions, namely “ communication roentgen
eaching the membership from sources outside the
organization ”, and means through which members can
develop their political skills outside the union.
external means of communication can be useful in di
sseminating views which are critical of union policy or
leadership, views which may not otherwise reach thyroxine
he membership via the channels controlled by the
leadership. As for political skills, we have already
seen that Lipset argues most workers do not have
access to such discipline through their jobs, and union
education programmes which provide such training
merely indoctrinate people into the “ party occupation ”. Ther
efore, he considers radical
political parties, churches
and the content of especial occupations as
sources of political skills development.
69
Lipset thus argues unlike organizational forms may sustain at least congressman, if not participatory, democracy. His inquiry in the ITU
shows that according to his definition of democracy,
some unions defy Michels ’ ‘ iron law ’. however, the
factors which he identifies as central to sustaining
democracy – decentralized industrial structure, deoxythymidine monophosphate
he presence of an occupational community, and the
73 70
There are many who have subs
equently adopted Lipset’s framework in an attempt
to refute his conclusions by demonstrating
that union democracy is introduce in many more unions than
originally thought. See Pearlin and Richards and Judith Stepan-
Norris, J. and M. Zeitlin. “ Union Democracy,
Radical Leadership, and the Hegemony of Capital,”
Sociological Review
60 (1995):
829–850 for examples. 71
Michels, 172.
72
Beetham, “Michels and his Critics,” 97-98.
73
Edelstein and Warner, 51.
74
Ibid., 51.
care of an institutionalized
opposition – are, according to him, rarely found and becoming more
scarce with the progress of modern industrial organization.
70
Hence, union democracy, is possible, but
strange, evening in terms far more narrow than those employed by Michels. But as we have already discussed, the equation
of democracy with competition between potential
leadership groups is at least controversial. Michels
argues that factionalism is not a source of democracy,
but rather represents the being of
a competing set of elites also wishing to establish themselves in
oligarchic positions. Oppositional attempts are explained aside as the wax of ambitious counter-elites seeking to become dominant themselves, and whose par
ticular programme or critique is irrelevant.
71
As
such, Michels focuses merely on the “ form rather triiodothyronine
han the content of party [
and union] struggles”, thus
eclipsing any analysis of the concrete changes in orientation and politics which may have resulted from the action of unlike groups or types of leaders.
72
By assuming that the content of internal political differences
between sets of leaders never matters, we never have to investigate whether it does or not. In this view, “ tied close rival is a fraud : it takes rate between groups which are or aspire to be oligarchic, and hence ‘ majority rule ’ equals oligopoly if not oligarchy. ”
73
Lipset himself admits that factions do not reflect a
leaders / members confrontation, but rather the action of
competing elites. However, the justification is given
by Edelstein and Warner : “ some option is better than none. ”
74
furthermore, Lipset is inconsistent in his treatm
ent of constitutional provisions as unimportant in
sustaining electoral competition. Zeitlin and Stepan-
Norris argue that Lipset’s anti-legalism is one-sided in
that he claims that clauses guaranteeing democracy do
not matter but those which reinforce oligarchical
74 75
Zeitlin and Stepan-Norris, 254-55.
76
Lipset, Trow and Coleman, 399.
dominance do. They argue that it makes no smell to say that some aspects of constitutions matter while others do not : if anti-democratic clauses have effects,
then so too do democratic ones, if not in the way
that liberals claim. If constitutions
didn’t matter, then top officers w
ouldn’t bother to attempt to have them
changed in their favor. Constitutions are import
ant, even if they don’t have a one-to-one correspondence
with reality. First, there are differences in the in
ternal political dynamics of nominally democratic unions
and those that are not. Second, and possibly more
importantly, constitutions are “living political
documents ” which reflect an internal political fight electron volt
olving over time, the factions participating in these
struggles, and the ‘ balance of power ’ struck in consecutive periods.
75
Constitutions are crystallizations of
internal power relations, the concretization of carbon monoxide
llective means and ends, which come to structure and
form future battles and their outcomes. even Lipset
admits this: he does point to the importance of formal
measures in the International Typographical Union
in sustaining democracy, even when the sociological
conditions which spawned them switch. For exemplify,
he credits the design of the electoral system and
built-in measures to weaken the ability of incum
bents with helping to restrain oligarchical tendencies.
If not causal, then, constitutions do matter at
least as reproductive or limiting mechanisms.
76
organizational purpose is another set of internal factors examined for their democratic implications. The simplest set of ideas has to do with the degree
of centralization. There is a broad consensus that
decentralized structures are positively related to
democracy, while centralized ones are most prone to
oligarchic control. This is based on considerations
of scale and proximity: local organs are assumed to
be more democratic since they are smaller and loca
te power within the reach of the membership.
Michels dissented from this position and argon
gued that even decentralized organizations can be
oligarchic, and resistor to cardinal control may not
be democratically motivated. Decentralization was
no answer either, for quite than being “ the consequence of the democratic tendencies of the masses ”, such
75 77
Michels, 198-9.
78
Ibid., 320, 326. Even syndicalism and anarchism, in his view, st
ill led to the domination of leaders over the masses, albeit
in
forms distinct from those in socialist or
ganizations. In the case of syndicalism, t
he emphasis on “direct action” by the worker
s, in
the shape of strikes in particular, itself leads to the emergenc
e of new leaders who seek to tr
ansform themselves in a permanent
elect. In the case of anarchism, avoiding organization and form
al leadership does not prevent
powerful orators from coming to
dominate over the minds of the masses. 79
Edelstein and Warner, 34-51.
80
Ibid., 52.
arrangements were indicative of minority leaders w
ho were unwilling to subordinate themselves to the
central constitution and hoped to maintain their “ local
spheres of action”; these leaders, while deploying
the “ terminology ” of majority rule and resistance against tyr
anny, were actually driven by the desire to “be
first in Munich rather than second in Berlin. ”
77
Such a position reflected Michels’ deeply-rooted pessimism
about the electric potential of different
institutional arrangements to
protect against oligarchy.
78
however, even though Michels was right to
caution us about the automatic equation of
decentralization and majority rule, Edelstein and Warner hav
e argued that there is much more variation in
the types of oligarchy than Michels understand. Michels implied that there might be different versions of oligarchy, but did not explore what remainder thes
e permutations might make. Edelstein and Warner do
investigate the means that oligarchies vary according to the membership and localization of leadership groups, and the different kinds of groupings which support them ; on this basis they develop of typology of oligarchic structures.
79
While they admit it is difficult to say which of these models is relatively more
democratic, Edelstein and Warner argue that “ [ einsteinium ] qually
oligarchic organizations are not necessarily equally
oppressive in the exercise of political might. ”
80
In other words, while we may agree with Michels that
decentralization does not imply the absence of oligarch
y, it might also be true to say that decentralized
structures may be less oppressive and therefore have more democratic openings. however, while many take the time to enumer
ate the undemocratic implications of centralized
structures, it is rare for person to bot
her to demonstrate the link between democracy and
decentralization. This wear connection is disturbed when structures are placed in a comparative
76 81
Donald Swartz, “United We Fall: Solidar
ity v. Democracy in Canadian Unions,”
Our Times
11, no. 4/5 (September 1992): 37-41
and Donald Swartz, “ Democracy in
Canadian Unions,” paper present
ed 2 September 1990 at the
Democracy in the Workplace
league, Centre for Research on Work and Society, York University, Toronto. context, and the specific fundamental motivations are
analysed. Swartz’s comparison of processes of
structural consolidation in the UAW and Steelworkers in
the 1940s demonstrates this point. In the UAW the
theme of more centralize District Councils was “ pushed by
the left as a means of controlling district leaders
– and in the context of a belligerent politics – as a means
to bring activists together.” On the other hand, an
anti-left politics in the Steelworkers
produced a different logic: to margi
nalize the left and to minimize their
entree to members, national councils were to be avoided and formal local autonomy enhanced. In this sense, decentralization, preferably than a mean to ensur
e local democratic control, was a method to support
maximal local dependence on pay staff controlled by the zone and international agency.
81
For these
reasons, the relative meaning and effects of structur
e must be understood in its specific historical and
political context. furthermore, these categories do not reveal the nat
ure of bureaucratic or membership power over
specific issues and processes. The ‘ division of labor ’ within unions is not constantly a elementary as leaders and experts leading, and members following ; rather, the precise contented of leadership and membership manipulate is variable. Take, for example, the example of operate
over strike pay. This is typically cited as a key source
of centralized bureaucratic power, and clearly a potent
ial means to ‘manage the di
scontent ’ of a militant, strike-prone membership. however, centralized strike
funds do not automatically confer such control. In
many unions, the use of hit pay as a form of inte
rvention in local collective bargaining is extremely rare.
intelligibly it is not enough to equate all centralize exponent res
ources with oligarchical control. Therefore, while
we must accept the universe of oligarchic tendenc
ies, we need not think that all such structures are
mechanically centralizing, evenly oppressive, or that they foreclose on all the same attempts at exercising democratic master. The pilfer and ahistorical categor
ies of ‘centralized’ and ‘decentralized’ tell us little
77 82
Richard Hyman,
Industrial Relations: A Marxist Introduction
(London: MacMillan, 1975), 41.
83
Ibid., 62-3.
about their connection to the particular forces whic
h created union structures, what their interests and
politics were, and how these interests were specifically institutionalized. This more nuanced sympathize of variation in uni
on structure requires an historical focus.
Hyman tries to historicize our understand of union structure, argui
ng that it “is not a fixed phenomenon
but a
process
, the historical outcome of interdependent but
not purposefully integrated strategies of a
variety of disconnected employee groups ”. As such,
this process has been characterized by the dynamic
interaction of “ two contradictory forces ” : that to
wards “breadth, unity, and solidarity” and that towards
“ parochialism, sectionalism and clannishness ”.
82
Hyman then presents a hi
story of the development of
trade coupling structures, demonstrating that craft uni
on movements have always engaged in struggles over
definitions of collective interests and determination, and the chromium
iteria for inclusion in or exclusion from working
class administration. The solution has been “ diverse form
s of workers’ solidarity”, indicating “contradictory
elements in their consciousness. ” And while there is
a great deal of organizational inertia, he points out
that “ traditional organizational forms are not immu
table”, nor is there any simple or mechanistic
determination of trade union structure by capital.
83
Therefore, while trade union structure may be
characterised by oligarchy and incorporation, it is besides a moral force process in which there is room for intervention. IV.
Democracy for Whom? Defining and Creating the Democratic Community
It is useful for Hyman to remind us that union stru
cture is the product of struggles over what unions
should do, how they should do it, and who should be involved, for it raises a question deeply submerged or absent in the union democracy literature : who belongs to
the core democratic constituency of the working
class to which unions must refer ? How is the definiti
on of that constituency related to how we evaluate the
78 84
Tom Langford, “Strikes and Class Consciousness,”
Labour / Le Travail
34 (Fall 1994): 111. Of course, these generalized
class interests can be thought to be satisfied in either social
democratic or socialist ways; nonetheless, both of these political
projects do in some way reach for generalized forms of class
consciousness which emphasize “the
class quality of the unharmed society ” and “ the want for the working class to unite and struggle. ” 85
David Harvey, “The Geography of the Manifesto,” in
The Socialist Register 1998:
The Communist Manifesto Now
, eds. L.
Panitch and C. Leys ( New York :
Monthly Review Press, 1998), 63.
democratic character and effectiveness of union stru
ctures? How does a focus on the goal of class
constitution – preferably than the more narrow one of meet
ing workers’ economic interests change our analysis of
the relationship between leaders and members, between union democracy, function and structure ? last, in what way does the method of class formation hav
e an impact on both the contours of the community and
the quality of the relationships which lin
k members of that community together?
Where the undertaking of class formation is made a cent
ral goal of union activity, then the question of unity
is often about more than mere potency at sati
sfying economistic interests within the confines of
capitalism. alternatively, oneness is part of the contend
to create a “generalized class consciousness” upon which
workers ’ interests can be realized.
84
As such, ‘effective’ unions are not simply those which act efficiently to
suffer members ’ immediate material interests. Rat
her, they are those which engage members in a process
of coming to see their interests as more than economic and as integrally linked to people beyond their contiguous workmates. In other words, unions are impor
tant in the process of “b
ring[ing] together all the
assorted highly differentiated and much local movem
ents into some kind of commonality of purpose.”
85
consequently, the clamber to create
an organizational expression of a wider class unity can be part of the
democratic representation of workers ’ interests. Where class formation is an significant moti
vation for union leaders, our understanding of the
mean and dynamics of centralization must necessarily be modified. centralization in this lawsuit is not merely about amassing personal baron at the top
of an unaccountable bureaucracy, nor even solely about
creating an ‘ effective ’ administration, although these may al
so be in play. Rather, such leaders are aiming at
foster and sustaining reciprocal bonds of obligation to those with whom the individual union member may
79 86
Ibid., 54.
87
Ibid., 64.
have little to no contact. These ‘ colleague workers ’ may besides have specific interests in conflict with both the general interest of the community and the particular
interests of one’s own immediate group. Though the
motivation to create a share common sense of interest out of
many particularities as well as to balance genuine
particular interests with general ones may involve forms
of discipline, this discipline is not always merely
top-down but rather can be reciprocal. As such, it is more
difficult to label all centralizers as mere oligarchs;
alternatively, the capacity of their goals deoxyadenosine monophosphate well as their lik
ely commitment to different (and contradictory) union
functions make them a lot more ambivalent fi
gures than Michels and Trotsky would have us believe.
In that sense, particularism based on Lipset
’s occupational communities, and the decentralized
forms of direct democracy which can be ( but ar
en’t necessarily) part of local unionism, are not
unproblematically more democratic than more centrum
lized structures. Instead, they rely upon a more
narrow understand of the boundaries
of the demos, based on the assumption that the immediate
community of workers is somehow more ‘ organic ’ than
general ones. This is unsurprising in that, as David
Harvey reminds us, capital organizes the working class spatially and concentrates them in places where they ( can ) become aware of a particular set of common interests.
86
These powerfully-felt particularities are
not bare appearance either : they are deoxythymidine monophosphate
he result of real differentiations in the working class, “actively
produced ” by the variations in “ capital accumulation and
market structures”, not to mention the articulation
of divisions of british labour party with “ ancient cultural dist
inctions, gender relations, ethnic predilections and religious
beliefs. ”
87
However, to presume that such communities
contain an essential common interest which
unproblematically demands commitment and defines the boundar
ies of legitimate democratic decision-making is
to naturalize a social structure and to passively accept the consequences of capital ’ s decisions in organizing the accumulation procedure. “ Place-bound loyalt
ies” are not more ‘real’ than those which stretch
across distance, and though mobilizations around them can be
very powerful, they create barriers to working-
80 88
Ibid., 70.
89
Charlotte Yates, “Unity and Diversity: Chall
enges to an Expanding Canadian Autoworkers’ Union,”
Canadian Review of
Sociology and Anthropology
35, no.1 (February 1998): 105.
course integrity. The structure of organizational forms
which unite that working class through democratic
processes seeks to “ intercede and translate
” between particular and universal interests.
88
furthermore, like centralizers, leaders rooted in thei
r commitment to particularist identities can be
both
democrats and personal power-seekers. indeed, t
hese leaders can use democracy, understood as local
autonomy, in opportunist ways, referring to a membersh
ip’s ‘given’ set of attitudes as a reason to be
exempted from broader obligations and retain ability rela
tive to central leaders. Even where these leaders
are accurately representing the ‘ will ’ of their membership, majority rule can be a much about insulating the group from the competing and ( possibly ) equally legi
timate demands of a larger community, and even
protecting privileges relative to others, as it is about retaining the right to make decisions over matters with direct effects on the group. As Yates points out, decentralized structures may be “ more permeable and consequently open to rank-and-file infl
uence” but they are also likely to
produce “autarkic local union bodies
that are only sporadically capable of coordinating strategies and actions beyond the local anesthetic sphere. ”
89
Insofar
as democracy involves not equitable representation and “ exemption from ” but besides egalitarianism, redistribution of ability and privilege, and authorization to act effectiv
ely in the advance of common interests, one cannot
plainly assume that localism is more democra
tic and centralism less so. Instead, decentralized and
centralized structures – and their respective proponents – must be understand as repl
ete with contradictory
pressures and potentials. In that sense, an emphas
is on how centralization can be linked to class
formation introduces new content to the “ oppose
ory pressures, motivations and behaviours” of leaders
and members, and in a way that destabilizes
previous understandings of those pressures.
To push the issue promote, classify formation probl
ematizes the posited inverse relationship between
majority rule and potency in batch organizations. While not denying the challenges associated with
81 90
George Ross and Jane Jenson,“Post-War Class Str
uggle and the Crisis of Left Politics,” in
Socialist Register 1985/86: Social
democracy and After,
eds. R. Miliband et.al. (London, Merlin, 1986); Kim Moody,
An Injury to All.
decision-making in large, building complex structures, when
the defence of broader class interests rather than
narrow economic ones is the goal, the criteria by wh
ich such actions are judged ‘effective’ change – and so
do the mean most likely to produce effective outcomes. There is cogency to the mind that merely economistic unionism, using the mechanism of roll up
ive bargaining, may require centralized, top-down
bureaucracies to achieve their goals efficaciously, al
though evidence from the 1970s onwards has shown that
such practices have diminished success given the massive
withdrawal of capital from the terms of the post-
war compromise with labor and the state.
90
however, where the formation and defense mechanism of broader class interests is at post, then different processe
s are needed for effectiveness, namely the need to foster
personal recognition with and committedness to broader
identities though a directly participatory process.
Members ’ contacts across workplaces and union locals, their capacity to ‘ have a state ’ in the decisions that affect that wider collectivity, and their date in
processes that attempt to balance the particular and
the general interest – all these are participatory
democratic aspects necessary to fostering a genuine
investment in the defense of class interests. As
such, there may be centralized organizational forms which
command
greater
rather than less membership participati
on and democratic control to be effective.
This is not to say that the goal of classify formation is constantly linked to democratic processes and outcomes or to argue that combining deeper forms of
democratic practice with centralized organizations is
straightforward or simple. As we have seen, there is
ample historical evidence of the use of undemocratic
forms of discipline in the search for working one hundred fifty
ass unity, which was partly what concerned Michels so
greatly. indeed, attention to the means used to effect
greater class unity in organizational terms reveals
precisely how messy and at odds such processes can be with respect to both democratic methods and outcomes, not to mention organizational capacities .
82 91
Gary Chaison,
Union Mergers in Hard Times:
The View from Five Countries
(Ithaca / London: ILR Press / Cornell University
weight-lift, 1996 ), 7-8. 92
Ibid., 14.
93
Ibid., 9-11.
94
Yates, 93.
95
Ibid., 104.
It might be expected that union mergers would be south
een as a key moment in the process of class
constitution, involving as they do working classify
organizational consolidation and the creation of broader
working class identities. While recent inquiry has
usefully emphasized their political rather than technical
nature, mergers have frequently
been understood as a defensive reaction, whether to declining union
membership, fiscal crisis, or destructive inter-union competition.
91
Moreover, merger outcomes are
generally evaluated in terms of “ bargain baron, or
ganizing ability, protection against raids, officer
recompense, membership engagement in coupling government, and economies of scale in union operation ”, all valid measures.
92
Finally, the literature does show how the
degree of post-merger integration is shaped
by the relative force of motivations and barriers
such as personal power considerations of leaders,
membership concern of loss of autonomy and fiscal
resources, and the challenges of melding union
structures based on varying approaches to
union function, democracy and administration.
93
rarely, however, are mergers understand as a part
of the process of creating a broader class
identity. not all mergers are motivated by this
goal; however, they all raise the key question of how to
“ represent the diverse and competing claims of thei
r expanding membership while at the same time being
adequate to of building inner oneness. ”
94
Charlotte Yates is one of the few to point to the complex connections
between interest representation, colle
ctive identity and organizational structures, all of which are objects of
controversy and the texture and dynamics of which
is generally missed in the merger literature.
95
She
examines how dramatic changes in union membership
, frequently produced by mergers, challenge existing
corporate identities and the organizational
structures which sustain them.
83 96
Mike Davis,
Prisoners of the American Dream
(New York: Verso, 1986), 7.
What is needed, however, is a deep sympathize
of how the outcomes of mergers actually
frame in mighty ways the subsequent
re
negotiation of collective ident
ities and the development of
decision-making structures. Mergers are unique mo
ments in an organization’s life, where underlying
assumptions about the function and relationship of drawing card
s and members, as well as notions of democracy and
union determination are crystallized, laid bare and subject to
discussion and debate in ways they simply aren’t in
‘ convention times ’. As the outcomes of struggles over how union identities, functions, structures and democratic practices should be conceived, mergers
form the terrain on which adaptations take place,
shaping the development of identitie
s and the organizational capacities to act on them in ways not fully
intended by their protagonists. In detail, the me
thod of unification has a major influence on whether old
identities are transcended or frozen into the newly stru
cture, new collective ident
ities formed or precluded,
new democratic practices to tie in concert the broader
community developed or blocked. While not wanting
to ascribe permanence or inevitability to the struct
ural outcomes of mergers, one should not underestimate
their importance. Mike Davis has argued with respect to the general serve of class constitution, “ the character of sediment historical experiences of the working
class [have] influenced and circumscribed its capacities
for exploitation in succeeding periods. ”
96
V.
Conclusions
My purpose has not been to deny the universe of
oligarchical tendencies within unions, or even to
dispute the mind that democracy is a very unmanageable thing
to achieve, even in its most minimalist forms. There
are powerful forces which push union leaders to substitu
te themselves for their membership, for members
to relinquish the democratic rights, for collective barroom
gaining to incorporate unions into the reproduction of
84 capitalism, for bureaucratic structures to diminish
the scope for both accountability and participation. The
literatures examined here have, if nothi
ng else, amply illustrated these problems.
What I do wish to contest is the character of molybdenum
st explanations for these dynamics. First, it is
authoritative to reject explanations based on all-important char
acteristics, whether of l
eaders, members, collective
dicker processes, or centralized and decentralized struct
ures. Second, it is wrong to assert that anti-
democratic tendencies are inevitably winner
ious, that there is an oligarchical telos fatalistically working itself
come out of the closet. Third, discussions which fail to examine the effects of variations and contradictions in demeanor, serve and social organization are neither utilitarian nor social scientific. ultimately, it is impossible to understand the dynamics of union majority rule and oligarchy in a static and ahistorical fashion. Leaders and members should be conceived as possessing a variety show of tendencies and capacities, the development of which is profoundly dependent upon characteristics of the social context in which they alive. They may possess certain psychological propensitie
s given this social context, but the expression of
these tendencies is highly mediated by the structures
in which they operate. The link between workplace
experiences and visions of democracy is particular indicative, and can form the basis for important conflicts over union purpose. furthermore, these tendencie
s are contradictory, and action taken can be highly
contingent. More than this, however, the identical definition of
“capacity” and “incapacity”, of “expert” and “inexpert”
and the distribution of these qualities, is subjective and thyroxine
he object of struggle. It is taken as a given that a
particular kind of cognition is required for an effect
ive working class organization. However, what is
constituted as relevant cognition is socially construc
ted, its distribution is determined by capitalist social
relations, and is basically linked to organizational
purpose. Internal struggles are as much about
defining what constitutes the correctly kinds of skills
and knowledge to be a leader, as they about deciding who
possesses those qualities. These battles do not take
place in a vacuum, of course, and are structured in
85 97
See Harry Braverman
Labor and Monopoly Capital: t
he Degradation of Work in the Twentieth Century
(New York: Monthly
Review Press, 1974 ) ; Craig
Heron and Robert Storey, eds.,
On the Job: Confronting the Labour Process in Canada
(Montreal /
Kingston : McGill-Queen ’ second University
Press, 1986); Cynthia Cockburn,
Brothers: Male Dominance and Technological Change
, 2
nd
erectile dysfunction. ( London : Pluto Press, 1984 ) ; Jane Gaskell, “ What C
ounts as Skill? Reflections on Pay Equity.” In
Just Wages: a Feminist
position on Pay Equity
, eds. J. Fudge and P. McDermott, 141-159 (Toront
o: University of Toronto Press, 1991).
98
Wainwright, 216.
99
Ibid., 214.
100
Heron,
The Canadian Labour Movement
, 32; Leier,
Red Flags
, 73-4.
crucial ways by the actions of both
capital and the state, but the outcome
is not as a result given. The
struggle over what constitutes skill is much be
tter studied and documented in the domain of the labour
process than within the sphere of working class or
ganizations, but the insights are nonetheless relevant.
97
The process of defining expertness within left organizations
is similarly an active social process of deskilling
the membership, of reorganizing what is and
who holds and transmits relevant knowledge.
98
The qualities
which define ‘ good union leadership ’ argon
e therefore not the same for all places and times, and evolve not
according to some natural blossom, but in the
context of battles over union function and the kind of
leadership thus required. An examination of Taylorism and its historical egress is particularly germane here as an doctrine of analogy. For what is authorize upon interrogation of the dev
elopment of scientific managem
ent is that it is not
production
per se which necessitates a highly differentiat
ed and rigidly hierarchical division of labour, but
preferably
production oriented towards the maximization of profit
.
99
In other words, Taylorism emerged as a
scheme in the clamber over
which
goals the organization of production would serve. Similarly, the
bureaucratization of working class organizations and the definition of leadership as technocratic should be seen as the merchandise of struggles over their purposes
and the organizational form which would best serve
those purposes. The embrace of institutionalized colorado
llective bargaining as a key mechanism of union power
did foster centralization of ability
into the hands of an ‘expert’ elite.
100
What is key, however, is that the
toleration of these finical “ definite aims ” was not
‘natural’ or ‘inevitable’,
but the outcome of lengthy
periods of inner struggle. It is therefore crucial to exami
ne those formative moments when the
86 movement could have developed in diverse directions,
and to ascertain why it took one path rather than
another, and not merely look at the result and
ex post facto
fashion it into a transcendental logic working
itself out. As a consequence, it is important to view union structur
es as the outcome of struggles over union function
and the kind of organization which will best serve deoxythymidine monophosphate
hose functions. These struggles are related to
democracy in complex ways that defy a bare equat
ion of centralization and leaders with oligarchy,
decentralization and members with democracy. alternatively,
the interaction of desires for effective business
unionism and for the formation of broader ( class ) ident
ities makes motivations – as well as the standard
moral or political judgements about these motivations – lupus erythematosus
ss clear cut. As we shall now see with the history
of CUPE, this is particularly the casing when examination
ining the merger process as a moment of both
organizational systematization and class formation .
87 chapter 3 : Contextualizing the Origins
of Canadian Public Sector Unionism
much that is central to understanding CUPE ’ s struct
ure and internal political culture stretches far
back beyond the year of its origin. The format
ive moments in its history predate even the kind of
unionism practised in the 1940s and 50s by its two
founding organizations, the National Union of Public
Service Employees ( NUPSE ) and the National Union of
Public Employees (NUPE). Both of these
organizations were chiefly the products of male, bl
ue-collar, skilled and unskilled workers in the hydro-
electric and municipal sectors, whose workplaces came
into existence at the turn of the last century, and
whose union locals were forged during the unionization
and strike wave associated with the First World
War. These locals were joined by groups of newfangled public employees brought into universe by a growing local state, whose bureaucratization through the
Depression and the Second World War ushered in a
moment wave of municipal unionization. such wo
rkers counted many more white collar clericals,
professionals, and women amongst their count, whos
e workplace identities and attitudes towards
unionism were often more ambiguous. These disparate
groups of workers faced significant challenges in
negotiating the class that their identit
ies, solidarities, and organizations would take, the results of which
were to have a fundamental impact on CUPE ’ south structure and declination
ision-making practices. As such, the contours
and contradictions of these fo
rerunners require exploration.
This chapter consequently delves into the emer
gence of municipal work and the changing economic,
political and ideological conditions under which it
was performed. The nature of urban expansion in
Canada brought municipal workers into close up, often
paternalist and politicized relationships with their
employers, relationships that served to impede the
development of class consciousness, maintain narrow
forms of identification, and prevent unionization. In
some workplaces, workers were pulled towards their
employers by a brawny sermon of service to t
he public good, shared professional values, or a pragmatic
recognition of the substantial benefits such cooperati
on would bring. Moreover, the fragmented nature of
88 municipal employers provided a geomorphologic basis for thyroxine
he formation of narrow identities and sectionalist forms
of administration. however, these relationships were besides full of
contradictions which, under the pressures of war,
tug deficit and unemployment, and economic and political
instability, led to their partial breakdown.
Public sector workers were pushed away from their
employers due to the changing nature of the work and
of labour-management relations. State expans
ion and the concomitant bureaucratization and
rationalization of municipal work, which began during the First World War and continued well into the 1950s and 60s, caused many to unionize and to seek broader, quasi-industrial organizational forms. furthermore, commitments to the populace commodity could be the basis of radicalization and the development of class consciousness, as the changing conditions of municipal
work made it more difficult for public sector
employees to carry out their service function, particu
larly to the urban working class. How these pressures
were understand and responded to varied over the periods in question and across different employee groups. These factors interacted in complicated ways with
the organizational, cultural and ideological milieu
of the already-established North Amer
ican labour movement. In the context of a split over the forms and
purposes of unionism, municipal workers aligned t
hemselves with organizations across the craft
versus
industrial divide that had been evolving since the 1880s.
Those groups most closely tied to their employers
opted for a very localize version of craft unionism
in which job control and local autonomy was paramount.
Those groups whose local conditions provided them with
experiences of broader worker solidarity, or who
had had minus experiences with a centralizing inte
rnational craft union, opted for industrial unionism
which emphasized broader commitment to working cla
ss interests and an organizational form to match.
such unions tended to develop notions of majority rule wh
ich asked workers to define their interests beyond
89 1
John C. Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City: Essays on Urban Politics and Policy, 1890-1920
(Ottawa: Institute of Public
government of Canada, 1977 ), 5. their contiguous workplace and be bound by higher levels
of authority which attempted to meet those
interests. however, these divisions were never simple or clear-cut. Discussing early municipal unionism is a undertaking easie
r said than done. It is exceedingly difficult to
find traces of the first municipal worker unions, tungsten
hether in the major surveys of Canadian labour history,
discussions of the processes industrialization and urbaniza
tion, or examinations of early city politics in
Canada. The col can be possibly explained by a general miss
of attention to workers’ role in political and
economic processes, but for tug historians, an orange group
erly narrow (if implicit) understanding of the working
class and the manner of its formation must besides be at
work here. Workers in the municipal public sector
were authoritative actors in both the urban and parturiency histor
y of Canada. Moreover, their specific place in the
political-economic order not only had deep effects on
their character and approach to union structure and
democracy, but besides on the nature
of the Canadian labour movement.
I.
Canada’s ‘Urban Boom’ and the Emer
gence of Municipal Employment
municipal workers as a group were brought into ex-wife
istence by the pressures of urbanization which
ensued from expansion of industrial output. This puerto rico
ocess is usually identified with flows of agrarian
workers to the cities in search of secret sector
industrial employment. The concentration of workers
around areas of industrial production, however, raises
serious questions about how to organize daily life in
densely populate areas. In the canadian context ( as elsewhere ), duty for managing these problems fell to local governments and
their agents, municipal employees.
The footstep and time of urbanization varies inter
nationally and within countries, but many urban
sociologists place Canada ’ s ‘ urban boom ’ between 1900 and 1914.
1
This boom was driven not only by the
“ most rapid [ economic ] emergence in the history of post-
Confederation Canada” up to that point, but also by the
90 2
Palmer, 161.
3
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 7-8.
4
Donald Avery, ‘
Dangerous Foreigners’: European Immigrant Wo
rkers and Labour Radicalism in Canada, 1896-1932
(Toronto:
McClelland and Stewart, 1979 ), 16. Avery points out that,
until 1914, the Dominion government was content “to give
businessmen a free hand in the recruitment
of the immigrants they required for
national economic development” due to the
determine of agricultural and railway interests. even though it wa
s expected that most would settle in the West and participat
e in
department of agriculture, a big share of immi
grants made their way to or got trapped
in urban labour markets (Avery, 16-38).
emergence of “ highly concentrated forms of corporat
e production” associated with the advent of monopoly
capitalism.
2
As a result, between 1900 and 1914 Canadian cities experienced a massive influx of people,
with over 2 million primarily european immigrants
seeking both temporary
and permanent employment.
3
City officials in this period faced the pressing ques
tion of urban organization and had to manage the results of
an open-door federal immigration policy over which they had little direct control.
4
Inadequate supply and
timbre of water and electricity, infrequent and over
burdened transportation, spiralling costs and restricted
handiness of propertyless housing, and concer
ns about public health and the spread of infectious
diseases : these were the outcomes of rapid urban growth with which city councils had to cope. however, it is important not to assume that
cities were passive, innocent bystanders upon whom
growth was being imposed from without. canadian urban
historians have demonstrated that most cities in
this period were dominated by pro-growth coaliti
ons of civic and business leaders. Although there are
authoritative regional and local variations in terms of thei
r precise class content, tilting them either towards
elitism or populism, such coalitions were about always bound together by an ideology of ‘ boosterism ’. As Alan Artibise explains, the central idea underlying metric ton
he “booster spirit” was an uncritical identification of
growth, of quantifiable material expansion as the centrum
l factor in a city’s success. Growth, progress and
notions of good citizenship were inextricably bound
up in the booster discourse: skeptics and opponents, or
“ knockers ”, were seen as lacking “ faith in the curie
ty”, “community spirit” and “business sense”. Another
powerful chemical element in this ethos was the notion that
all classes would benefit from a bigger and better city,
91 5
Alan Artibise, “Boosterism and the Deve
lopment of Prairie Cities, 1871-1913,” in
Town and City: Aspects of Western Canadian
Urban Development
, ed. A. Artibise (Regina: University of R
egina / Canadian Plains Res
earch Centre, 1981), 211-15.
6
Christopher Armstrong and H.V. Nelles,
Monopoly’s Moment: The Organization and R
egulation of Canadian Utilities, 1830-1930
( Philadelphia : Temple University Press, 1986 ), 11. 7
William R. Plewman,
Adam Beck and the Ontario Hydro
(Toronto: Ryerson University Press, 1947), 146.
8
Grace Palladino,
Dreams of Dignity, Workers of Vision: a History of
the International Brotherhood
of Electrical Workers
( Washington, D.C : International Brotherhood of Electrical Workers, 1991 ), 47. 9
J.S. Hagopian, “Debunking the Public Heal
th Myth: Municipal Politics and Class Conflict During the Galt, Ontario Waterworks
Campaigns, 1888-1890, ”
Labour/Le Travail
39 (Spring 1997): 40.
therefore securing sociable and political conformity. As
zealous partisans of their own communities, boosters
attend themselves as players in a high-stakes zero-s
um game in which another city’s gain was their loss.
5
The booster project ’ randomness equation of increase with
progress can be seen in the way they talked about
specific proposals for urban development. Infras
tructural developments like water and light were
“ metaphors for life and clarification ” and
the benefits they promised (the ability to walk safely at night, to
beverage and wash in ample and disease-free water,
and to protect against fire) were “the hallmarks of
bourgeois refinement. ”
6
Prevalent was the idea that electrificat
ion, whether through lighting or streetcars,
would solve urban ills like overcrowding and disease. According to Adam Beck, Tory mayor of London, ontario and the main advocate and first president of
a publicly-owned Ontario Hydro-Electric Commission,
“ [ planck’s constant ] igh rents, dear foods, slum conditions would be
greatly reduced by giving to city people cheap and rapid
transportation. It would besides make it possible field-grade officer
r the farmer to market his produce more quickly and
stingily. Under these conditions the interlocutor woul
d be eliminated, more people would be attracted to
the state, there would be cleaner, healthier and better condition of things. ”
7
Thomas Edison conceived of
electricity as “ a cardinal to homo liberation. ”
8
This converse of progress was a potent throng
ilizer of the community. However, many members
of pro-growth coalitions had much less exalted concerns
in mind. The presence of utilities could reduce the
price of doing clientele, as “ [ p ] roperty insurers
granted significant discounts to owners of property in
municipalities which had waterworks. ”
9
Beautification through the pl
anning of parks and boulevards was
92 10
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 33.
11
Artibise, “Boosterism”, 213.
12
In other words, booster coalitions were led by commerc
ial capital rather than indus
trialists. See Alan Artibise,
Winnipeg: A
Social History of Urban Growth 1874-1914
(Montreal: McGill University Press, 1975), 23-42.
13
Michel Gauvin, “The Reformer and the Ma
chine: Montreal Civic Politics from
Raymond Préfontaine to Médéric Martin,”
Journal
of canadian Studies
13, no. 2 (Summer 1978): 18-9.
14
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 40.
15
Artibise, “Boosterism,” 215.
not thus much for the enjoyment of local citizens, but a
“business proposition”, a “pub
licity sport ” to raise a city ’ second profile.
10
As individuals, boosters had a great deal at stake in the inter-city competition for industrial
employers and the leave increase
in population, pressures which were particularly acute in the small
and growing cities of the Prairies who
desired the status of regional centre.
11
Pro-growth coalition members
were typically merchants from the local Board of Tr
ade or Chamber of Commerce, real estate developers
and speculators, street railroad track and puerto rico
ivate utility investors, all of whom
would reap direct material benefits from larger cities and the infrastructure they could provide.
12
In many places, local politicians were
entrepreneurs in the very field central to urban gr
owth. For example, Raymond Préfontaine, Montreal
alderman and mayor in the recently 1800s, was a stockholder in the Montreal Water and Power Company, the St. Lawrence Electric Company, and the Montr
eal Land and Improvement Company, “which developed
areas rendered accessible by electric tramways. ” Préfont
aine’s personal self-interest partly explains his role
in securing a thirty-year contract for
the Montreal Street Railway Company.
13
This personal venture in the pace and focus of urban development led local businessmen to view the purpose of municipal government and
the public sector in instrumental
terms. For them, the primary
mandate of city government was to direct its res
ources to aid the businessmen who saw themselves as
uniquely responsible for the creation of the city ’ s wealth.
14
In other words, local government was not about
democracy or the representation of divers interests, but merely “ a tool serving personal and community prosperity. ”
15
The business community therefore sought to control city councils so as to ensure that
93 16
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 15, 39.
17
Artibise,“Boosterism,” 215.
18
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 39.
19
Artibise, “Boosterism,” 223; Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 28-9.
20
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 18, 39.
21
Artibise, “Boosterism,” 223.
22
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 17.
municipal services would be developed in ways that
supported their own profit-seeking activities.
16
similarly, though many boosters employed a democrat
rhetoric which emphasized “community spirit”,
cooperation, “ common ties ” and “ creating a shop of wale
th to benefit all citizens”, the best citizenry was one
which “ did not disrupt existing relationships ” and
provided mute consent for elite-driven projects.
17
This was particularly true of the function classes, and of municipal workers in particular, who were seen as obstacles to progress or “ just another factor of production
like raw material and energy, [which] should be cheap and
receive no party favor. ”
18
These ideological and fabric interests theref
ore led many booster-controlled city councils to
single-mindedly pursue undue expansion despite its colorado
st and the resultant “social catastrophe” owing to
the inadequate provision of services to already-e
xisting populations of the urban working class.
19
This “cult
of moreness ” was the hegemonic ideological public relations
ism through which the nature and goals of urban
growth were viewed, and the framework in whic
h city problems were addressed. As John Weaver
concludes, “ the urban boom was conducive to a occupation and real estate ethos … not to social reform values. ”
20
The concourse of the national-wide soar in urbani
zation and the specific strivings of city boosters
led to “ a elephantine problem for local anesthetic authorities ” and
a proliferation of “ever-increasing” demands for
municipal services.
21
As Weaver points out, “[t]he building boom in the private sector had a counterpart in
the public … [ in ] every major city. ”
22
These services were first and foremost infrastructural: water and
sewage, electricity and light,
streets, sidewalks, public transportation, parks, and fire and police
94 23
Labour Gazette
, January 1918: 33.
24
J.R. Conley, “Frontier Labourers, Cra
fts in Crisis, and the Western Labour Re
volt: the Case of Vancouver 1900-1919,”
Labour /
Le Travail
23 (Spring 1989): 17-8.
25
Kenneth G. Crawford,
Canadian Municipal Government
(Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1954), 182.
26
Armstrong and Nelles, 150.
27
Crawford, 183; Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 56-58.
departments were the kernel of municipal action in thursday
is period. The construction and maintenance of these
services produced an incredible demand for incompetent
and often temporary construction labour and cleaners
in especial, demand which was profoundly cyclic.
23
However, demand also increased for skilled workers
such as electricians, outside linemen, mechanics and
construction tradesmen, work that was often more
settled and plug.
24
In other words, early on there were
important divisions and hierarchies amongst
municipal employees, which posed the question of who
shared a community of interest and who should be
in the same organizations. Given this broader social and classify context
of municipal politics and urban development, the
amount and distribution of municipal employment was
often highly politicized and connected both to the
implementation of the booster sight and to ward politics. Council committees in the city ’ s areas of province were staffed by elect councillors, who would make decisions about which services would be provided, to whom and how. These committees
were also charged with appointing municipal
department heads who would be creditworthy for rent of employees.
25
These positions on the water, light,
streets, works, and exile committees were highl
y coveted, given the capacity of these decisions to
affect councillors ’ economic and political fortunes. City
committees were used in numerous self-interested
ways. Where cities used individual utility companies to
supply water, electricity and transportation, councillors
could secure kickbacks from companies to whom
they would grant exclusive and decades-long contracts.
26
besides, herculean committee members could ensure their polonium
litical allies or relatives were appointed as city
officials and department heads, whose lease decisions could then be used to buttress political hold in working class wards.
27
95 28
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 56.
29
Gauvin, 17, 22.
30
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 59.
31
Gauvin, 20.
32
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 58.
33
Lenihan, 159.
With a lot work for municipal governments not reliant
on skill, political criteria could more easily be
used to determine who was hired. In this period, thousand
unicipal employment was often a reward for political
loyalty and separate of local political machines ’ strategies for “ getting the vote out. ”
28
Commissions of
investigation in both Montreal and Toronto revolutions per minute
ealed extensive patronage networks in most municipal
departments. In Montreal, it was well known triiodothyronine
hat both Mayors Préfontaine and Martin courted the
francophone working class with promises of public works jobs and projects in their communities.
29
It was
besides revealed that “ applicants for civil use paid aldermen for a fluent process of their requests. ”
30
Similarly, the Royal Commission investigating municipal misdeeds in 1909 found that
“ kickbacks were rampant in the fire department – and
specifically that an inordinate number of firemen
came from the town of St. Eloi, Quebec. ”
31
Between 1900 and 1915, Toronto had no less than six separate
investigations into municipal department practice
s, which revealed the kind of control department heads
had over employees as a consequence of the latter ’ south addiction on their discrimination for jobs. Toronto city employees were exploited for the individual profit of councillors and department heads, who used ‘ free ’ labor to build their own homes or to raise vegetables in city parks for their secret sale.
32
Smaller centres like
Calgary were not immune from such dealings. There thymine
he currency of favouritism was alcohol: with regular
payments of whiskey to the foreman, advantageous
employment assignments or overtime could be
secured.
33
In other words, city workers were much involv
ed in paternalist social relationships with their
department heads and direct supervisors, connected to
them via links of gratitude and dependency. Added
to this in many communities was an ethnic dimension : employer and employee were often ‘ countrymen ’ ,
96 34
H. Clare Pentland,
Labour and Capital in Canada, 1650-1860
(Toronto: James Lorimer &
Co., 1981), 25; see also Robert
Storey, “ Unionization Versus Corpor
ate Welfare: The Dofasco Way,”
Labour/Le Travailleur
12 (Fall 1983): 8.
35
Palmer, 41-2.
36
Palladino, 5, 10.
37
Greg Kealey, “The Honest Workingman and
Workers’ Control: The Experience of
Toronto Skilled Workers, 1860-1892,” in
canadian Working Class History
, eds. L.S MacDowell and I. Radforth (T
oronto: Canadian Scholars Press, 1992), 159.
38
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 39.
connected via a shared inheritance which cut across authorit
y relations. These practices resembled the 19
th
hundred paternalism discussed by H. Clare Pentland in
that the promise of economic favours from those in
office elicited loyalty, deference and
consent to hierarchical relationships, while the threat of losing
discriminatory treatment was triiodothyronine
he coercive element which kept the system in place.
34
These practices made
organization amongst civil employees ve
ry difficult, for they worked to “undermine … the collectivity of the
oppressed by linking them to their social superiors. ”
35
skilled work, particularly at municipal utilities,
was performed under somewhat different conditions
and therefore produced stronger notions of collective identity. Electr
ical utility workers, especially outside
linemen responsible for stringing up electric wires, began as unskilled and ill-trained. however, they adopted a craft model of administration early on on. Organi
zing under the International Brotherhood of Electrical
Workers ( IBEW ), utility workers sought to increase standards
in their industry by raising the level of skill
and restricting entry into local labor markets.
36
Such strategies which aimed at monopolizing particular
skills were long the core of craft union ability and, as
Greg Kealey has shown, gave skilled workers a high
“ degree of … control condition of product. ”
37
The ownership structure of the i
ndustry was also important: utilities in
this period tended to be private companies. T
hose utilities that had begun or were being brought under
public management tended to be run by specialized authorities – appointed Boards or Public Utility Commissions – which existed at sleeve ’ mho duration from cities ’
political institutions. While not immune to political
influence, favoritism and other such practices,
hiring in both the private and commission-run utilities
tended to be less directly influenced by
patronage and political considerations.
38
This, combined with the
97 39
Palladino, 2, 23-5.
40
Ibid., 47. This identification of one’s work with the betterment
of humanity is a common and power
ful element in many crafts.
See the discussion in Kealey, “ The Honest
Workingman”, 173 of printers’ sense of
themselves as “the main carriers of
rationalism and the enlightenment ” for a alike sense of identity. 41
This preference for less disruptive forms of dispute resoluti
on like arbitration was prevalent
in North American electrical
unionism up to this point, and was a public relations
inciple enshrined in the IBEW’s cons
titution. Palladino, 10; Harold Logan,
Trade Unions in
Canada : Their Development and Functioning
(Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1948), 99.
42
Armstrong and Nelles, 1986: 245.
longstanding custom of craft unionism, resulted in wo
rkers being hired due to their skills, and served as a
basis for both craft pride and relative independence from management. The specific nature of utility work besides worked to
consolidate a collective i
dentity in important ways.
As Grace Palladino documents, outside linemen worked long hours in all kinds of weather putting up poles and stringing up “ hot ” high tension office lines,
and thus found themselves engaged in very dangerous
function. The senior high school pace of wound and death in the industr
y meant that “linemen relied on each other to see that
the job was done safely and competently ”, vitamin a well as field-grade officer
r disability and death benefits. Out of these material
conditions of shared danger and reciprocal dependence, thyroxine
hese workers thus produced a very cohesive,
solidaristic culture based on a “ fierce pride ” in their work.
39
This consciousness was not without its
contradictions, however. electrical workers were proud to be the agents of electrification, as they were thus separate of the march of build up and human liberation.
40
Insofar as the identification of electricity with progress
was an authoritative component in the elit
e vision of cities, electrical workers could be ideologically incorporated
into booster coalitions. Their sense of spell
ance to society and hence entitlement to safety and
recognition could be the basis for militant solidarity, but
it could also reinforce a service mentality which led
utility workers to prefer the conciliation process as southeast
t out in the 1907 Industrial Disputes Investigation Act
for the resoluteness of disputes.
41
The contradictions between a solidaristic and workerist culture and a public
service brain would become specially acuate as electrical utilities passed into public hands and the employer was nowadays the municipal taxpayer.
42
98 43
Gauvin, 23.
44
Ibid., 16.
45
Stephen High, “Planting the Municipal Ow
nership Idea in Port Arthur, 1875-1914,”
Urban History Review
26, no.1 (October
1997 ) : 12. 46
Armstrong and Nelles, 13-14; K.C. Dewar, “Private Electr
ical Utilities and Municipal Ow
nership in Ontario, 1891-1900,”
Urban
History Review
12, no.1 (June 1983): 31.
Whether skilled or unskilled, those involved in
the building and maintenance of urban infrastructure
had substantial interests in an ever-expanding city, and as such could be said to be subordinate members of the dominant allele ‘ booster ’ coalitions. Close material and
ideological ties to their employers fostered in many
places a very locally defined identity based more on “ community ” than on “ classify ”. The pro-growth agenda and the material interests
invested in it also produced counter-tendencies
which could affect the office of municipal workers and
their unions. Divisions within local elites emerged
during this period, not thus much over whether gr
owth should be pursued, but over who exactly should
benefit from it.
43
In other words, battles emerged over what
should be the exact nature of the relationship
between municipal government and private interests.
A movement for municipal reform emerged to
challenge the practices of the “ machine po
liticians” and the interests they served.
44
As such, municipal
workers were frequently caught in the middle of intra-e
lite disputes, and their status and working conditions
dramatically affected. Though much members of the capitalistic class them
selves, municipal reformers were critical of
particular capitalists turning themselves into monopo
lists at the expense of the rest of the business and
broader community. These monopolists were dis
paragingly known as ‘boodlers”, people “who personally
profited from public subsidies that had not benefited the community as a whole. ”
45
The private utility owners
were a especial target for anger, as their monopolistic
position in many communities allowed them to charge
“ exorbitant rates ”, provide less than ideal servic
e and engage in “cavalier treatment of customers.”
46
In
some communities like Port Arthur, private utilit
y entrepreneurs failed even to produce what they had been
contracted to build : “ numerous franchise agreements
… sometimes at considerable expense to ratepayers,
99 47
High, 12.
48
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 37; Armstrong and Nelles, 156.
49
Armstrong and Nelles, 141.
50
H.V. Nelles,
The Politics of Development: Forests, Mines
and Hydro-electric Power in Ontario, 1849-1941
(Toronto: Macmillian
crush, 1974 ), 248-9. 51
Armstrong and Nelles, 190; Toronto ratepayers voted 15,048 to
4,551 in favour of setting up a municipally-owned utility,
signaling their “ conversion … to radical
civic populism” and the view that “only
public ownership could guarantee cheap, effi
cient
electric avail ” ( Armstrong and Nelles, 156 ). 52
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 61.
ended with about nothing to show for them. ”
47
Since manufacturers wanted cheap and plentiful electrical
power, they were consequently some of the most
ardent supporters of muni
cipalisation of utilities.
48
These
reformers posited a vision of the municipal state as alternating current
ting in the ‘general interest’, which they understood in
terms of the city ’ s duty to provide positive conditions of capital accumulation for all, not for specific group of capitalists. The Ontario Hydro Electric Power Commission ( HEPC ) was precisely the product of the civil populism and anti-monopolistic opinion
characteristic of the reform movement of the early 20
th
century.
49
The HEPC, created in 1906, was the result of a hawaii
ghly successful campaign for public ownership that
appealed both to occupation and the general populace led by London, Ontario manufacturer, Mayor and conservative MPP Adam Beck. Enveloped in a di
scourse which emphasized both industrial progress on
the footing of brassy power and social progress attributed to the capacity of electricity to improve urban live standards, the HEPC was in this period closely identif
ied with the “public interest”, particularly when
counterposed with the unscrupulous
private power companies.
50
The creation of the
Toronto Hydro-Electric
system in 1911 besides emerged out of a similar desire
to push the privately-owned and increasingly reviled
Toronto Electric Light Company.
51
Reformers besides struck at the boodlers ’ allies, the
machine politicians. For some members of the
business class, the putrescence at city hall was bec
oming both unseemly and too costly, as many of them
wanted command over the municipal agenda without havi
ng to the pay high cost of bribery or kickbacks.
52
100 53
Ibid., 63-4.
54
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 65-68; Artibise,
Winnipeg
, 43.
55
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 68-9.
56
Armstrong and Nelles, 241.
Reformers besides took aim at democrat ward politicians
, whose paternalist connections to the working class
were deemed creditworthy for the miss of good government.
53
Reformers sought the depoliticization of
service provision and entree to employment, and purs
ued structural reforms which would allow municipal
politics to operate more efficiently, like a occupation.
Common reform proposals were boards of control,
commissions of question into city administration,
particularly to disclose petty patronage and corruption,
reductions in the number of councillors or evening outri
ght elimination of ward
systems of representation.
54
possibly most important was the establishment
of independent and specialized boards or commissions,
whose members were appointed and activities carried out
at arm’s length from repr
esentative institutions.
55
These commissions were the foremost concrete move to
wards rule by experts, the bureaucratization of city
presidency and the subsequent Taylor
ization of municipal work. These “depoliticizing” changes were in
fact deeply political, frequently ( but not always ) radius
educing the influence of the working class (and the
citizenry in general ) on municipal government. however,
labelling city services as technical rather than
political issues could only wallpaper over and not remove underlying conflicts around their distribution and the working conditions of those who provided them. Workers in these sectors were sometimes part
of these reform coalitions, sometimes neutral,
sometimes the targets and therefore opponents. Some, like
the employees of private utilities, were “among
the most ardent advocates ” of the thousand
unicipalisation of services; for them, “[o]nly complete replacement of
secret restraint … would ensure fair discussion of thyroxine
he public users as well as proper justice to the public
servants. ”
56
Other workers saw in the reform project the chance to democratize city hall and expand
working class charm over council. P.H. Wichern argues that parturiency aldermen in Winnipeg supported “ effective government reform ”, which concretely m
eant proportional represent
ation and improved fiscal
101 57
P.H. Wichern, “Historical Influences on Cont
emporary Local Politics: The Case of Winnipeg,”
Urban History Review
12, no. 1
( June 1983 ) : 40. 58
H.V. Nelles and C. Armstrong, “The Great Fight for Clean Government”, in
Urban History Review
2 (October 1976), 53, 55.
59
Armstrong and Nelles, 151.
60
Nelles and Armstrong, 51.
61
Gauvin, 20-1.
62
Gauvin, 21.
63
Armstrong and Nelles, 160-1.
management at city hall.
57
Saint John workers also supported
the commission system of government,
characterized by a smaller issue of elected official
s elected at large, which allowed the concentration of
the wage-earning vote behind labor candidates.
58
In other words, where reform took the shape of civic
populism, it produced “ a alliance that could cross
class lines and link up those who sought to democratize
local government with those who wanted centrum
lized administration performed with businesslike
efficiency. ”
59
However, this attempt “to accommodate potent
ially contradictory objectives” made reform
coalitions unpredictable and full of likely for conflict.
60
however, in places where reformers focussed on the reduction of the baron of what they viewed as a selfish and short-sighted working class operati
ng politically through the machine system, workers’
leaders vehemently opposed them.
61
The leader of the Montreal
Trades and Labour Council, for instance,
opposed the establishment of a Board of Control as “ a pl
ot of capitalists and corporations” seeking to shift
trade back into the hands of the Anglo elite.
62
As Armstrong and Nelles point out, the Francophone
democrat – and boodling – politicians were “ perceived as more responsive ” to their wage-earning constituents, while the “ english-speaking reformers
offended French-Canadian ward politicians with their
assumptions of automatic rifle superiority. ” As a consequence of
the interplay of class and ethnicity, Montreal municipal
workers specifically and the exercise classes more generally, were never separate of reform politics.
63
In other words, the contradictions of uni
mpeded urban growth were experienced by municipal
workers themselves, and made their political alignments
unstable. As municipal workers, they “produced
city life sentence ” and thus had an interest in sustaining gr
owth and expansion. However, as members of the
102 64
Johnston, 23.
65
Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 39; Johnston, 15.
working class, they besides had to live in the elit
e-defined and decidedly inegalitarian urban space they helped
to create.
64
In other words, there was a growing conflic
t between “boosterism” and social welfare, or as
Paul Johnston puts it, between economic growth
and collective consumption, a conflict embodied by
municipal workers themselves.
65
These tensions had the potential to
disrupt the paternalist relationships
between employer and employee. Another set of tensions was implicit in in the use of favoritism as a method acting of social control. As in any arrangement of discriminatory treatment,
for there to be winners there must also be losers. That is, not every
municipal employee could benefit equally from the
systems of favouritism: someone had to be on the
bottom in these workplace hierarchies. These hierarchies found themselves under increasing press as the necessitate for employees grew and the capacity to control bombastic groups of workers via personal ties diminished. such systems besides created a constituen
cy for reform of city administration amongst civic
workers themselves. ultimately, municipal workers were part of cross-cl
ass coalitions (whether for growth or reform), but
as dependent members whose interests would onl
y ever be partially addressed. As economic and
political conditions changed, the capacity to accommodate
municipal workers within these coalitions would
not constantly be sustainable, and their interests would most
likely be the first jettisoned. In other words, the
basis for battle ballad within the nature of the relati
onship between municipal workers and their elite “allies”.
These tensions can be most distinctly observed in the vitamin c
onflicts which emerged within reform coalitions due to
the rotation in city administration. The substitute
equent bureaucratization of civic structures meant the
breakdown of paternalist sociable relations and system
s of advantage. While this reduced preferential
treatment and condescension, now
all
workers were to be administered efficiently as inputs of the production
procedure. In other words, reform meant the creati
on of common conditions and experiences of employment,
103 66
Logan, 60.
peculiarly when fiscal restraint was imposed, which ac
ted as a unifying force. These new conditions also
required collective rather than person strategies to
protect workers’ positions and spawned the first wave
unionization of municipal workers. II.
Municipal Workers in a Divided Labour Movement
The effects of corporate concentration and conti
nentalization in the pr
ivate sector between 1890
and the 1920s besides exacerbated conflicts within the broader north american labor
movement itself over
the allow forms of unionism, conflicts which were to have their affect on the form to be taken by municipal proletarian unionism. There was in this peri
od a general growth in tensions between Canadian craft
coupling locals and their US-based drumhead offices. Municipal
and electrical utility workers had to find their place
within these struggles over organizational model,
national independence, and the location of the legitimate
democratic community of workers. Since the Trades and Labor Congress ’ 1902 Berlin
convention, the mainstream of the Canadian
labor movement had institutionaliz
ed the preeminence of the American Federation of Labor and its brand
of unionism. TLC-affiliated unions had to be organized
according to craft and affiliated to the appropriate
external union in their jurisdiction ; canadian uni
ons operating in the jurisdictions of US-based unions
were not to be chartered by the TLC and were deemed to be engaged in the cardinal sin of ‘ double unionism ’.
66
‘Dual unionism’ refers to the setting up of alte
rnative union structures in a jurisdiction where
already-established unions are organizing workers. This
“doctrine of solidarity”
was part of AFL president
Samuel Gompers ’ approach to unionism, which equat
ed labour solidarity with support for already-
established unions, regardless of their practices or polonium
litics. In general, “dual unionism” was used as a term
of defamation to designate newcomers as unsolidaristic
“splitters” and used as a justification to expel or
104 67
Ibid., 366-369. The Knights of Labor, the Industrial Workers of the World, the One Big Union, the Communist Party of Canada’s
Workers ’ Unity League, and the Congress of Industrial Organi
zations all emerged as ‘dual unions’ in this sense.
68
Ibid., 367.
69
Palmer, 168; Robert Babcock,
Gompers in Canada: A Study in American C
ontinentalism Before the First World War
(Toronto:
University of Toronto Press, 1974 ), 73. 70
Babcock, 96-7.
exclude them from labor federations.
67
Harold Logan characterised this scheme as “ conservative in the inhibitory sense, since it operates through prohibition of progressive challengers rather than through superiority of appeal for membership. ”
68
In the Canadian context, the Quebec-based remnants of the Knights of Labor who endured after the administration ’ s continent-wide collapse, as we
ll as those who had formed Canadian-based equivalents
to the US-based craft unions, posed a trouble to
AFL leaders aiming to establish a monopoly over
continental labor markets so as to ma
tch the reach of continental employers.
69
The Berlin Congress
permitted the expulsion of these competit
ors, comprising a fifth of the TLC’s affiliates, and specifically those
who continued to support both an industrial ( and
more encompassing) model of organization and
independent canadian unionism. These sections subsequently refused to be assimilated into a US- dominated labor apparent motion, nourish canadian nationalis
m amongst a section of the working class, and
provided an organizational home for the growing numbers of canadian members dissatisfied with the AFL ’ mho mark of labor internationality.
70
For those workers who remained within the bury
nationals, tensions soon emerged over the next 20
years over both the kind of unionism most appropriate
for the Canadian context and the share of decision-
making autonomy and control owed canadian workers, gi
ven their status as citizens of an independent
country. In that sense, growing nationalist south
entiment amongst Canadian workers was in some way
connected to notions of coupling democracy and the contours
of the legitimate democratic community. In this
period, many canadian locals of external unions
grew to resent their subordinate status and the
american leadership ’ s ignorance of and disinterest
in the specificities of the Canadian economic and
105 71
Ibid., 78.
72
Heron,
The Canadian Labour Movement
, 32.
73
Palmer, 160.
74
Babcock, 111.
75
John Crispo,
International Unionism: a Study
in Canadian-American Relations
(Toronto: McGraw Hill, 1967), 154.
76
Palmer, 160-61.
political setting. As Babcock puts it, many “ chafed under
the new restrictions that devolved from their
affiliation with international union headquarters, … res
ented the high level of dues, and feared that their
hard-earned money would be squandered or
misspent by union officials.”
71
These ‘new restrictions’ and
higher dues were separate of the development of the missouri
re centralized and bureaucratic model of “business
unionism ” in which “ featured … more full-time official
s and organizers, greater centralization of power over
fall funds and benefit plans, and stern
lines of demarcation around the crafts.”
72
Gompers’ aim here
was to create organizations that could compete in terms of scale and resources with corporate giants that were coming to dominate the canadian and american economies.
73
canadian unionists were besides incensed by Gompers ’ and the AFL ’ s attention to “ [
o]nly those elements in Canadian industrial life which
parallel conditions in the United States ”, and the
presumption that a common strategy without regional
variations was allow for the
entire continental labour market.
74
While such tensions between local or
regional units and home headquarter no doubt emerged in
the US as well, the confluence of conflicts
over master with canadian nationalism served to fuel secession movements in many internationals.
75
There were besides many outside established craft uni
on structures who were increasingly critical of
their exclusionary approach to unionism and their resu
ltant inability to organize the new categories of
workers being generated by monopoly capitalism. The concentration of corporate power which fuelled the urban boom was besides part of a broader shift in the field-grade officer
rm of capital accumulation. The reorganization and
deskilling of work in order to increase labor productivity was breaking down crafts and creating exchangeable workers with identical little bargaining office.
76
These workers would certainly not be able to
use the chief strategy of craft unionism – control over
the labour market in particular skills – to any effect.
106 77
Craig Heron, “The Crisis of the Craftsm
an: Hamilton’s Metal Workers in the Early 20
th
Century,”
Labour / Le Travail
6 (Autumn
1980 ) : 7-48 ; Gillian Creese, “ Exclusion or
Solidarity? Vancouver Workers Conf
ront the ‘Oriental Problem’,” in
Canadian Working
Class History
, eds. L.S MacDowell and I. RADFORTH (Tor
onto: Canadian Scholars Press, 1992), 314-17.
78
Heron,
The Canadian Labour Movement
, 36.
79
Mark Leier,
Where the Fraser River Flows:
The Industrial Workers of the World in British Columbia
(Vancouver: New Star
Books, 1990 ), 13. 80
Babcock, 154; Palmer, 252; David Berc
uson, “The Winnipeg General Strike,” in
On Strike: Six Key Labour Struggles in
Canada, 1919-1949
, ed. I. Abella (Toronto: James Lorimer and Co., 1975), 6.
81
Leier,
Where the Fraser River Flows
, 1.
82
James Naylor, “Southern Ontario: Striking at the Ballot Box,” in
The Workers’ Revolt in Canada, 1917-1925
, ed. C. Heron
( Toronto : University of Toronto, 1998 ), 149. however, quite than rethink the basis of uni
on power and develop broader, more flexible types of
organization, the mainstream labor
movement retrenched in a defensive attempt to maintain their craft
exponent against the deluge of unskilled and often immi
grant workers being brought into the production
summons.
77
In many canadian communities, however, both those within and outside the craft unions began to develop industrial unions with the potential to deal
with these new working conditions. Many labour
historians now argue that a combination of particula
r types of industry and distinctive regional political
economies combined to create constituencies for
industrial unionism in Eastern and Western Canada.
78
These communities faced “ aggressive corporate
employers” who brought
together large numbers of
workers, but in a context which was both ant
i-union and rapidly undermining and reorganizing the skill
content of work.
79
Added to these conditions was the growing sense that, in many communities, a strict
craft union scheme did not make as much sense due
to the relatively smaller industrial base, and the
fragmentation in bargaining ability and solidarity that would follow from dividing workers up by jurisdiction.
80
therefore, as the Second Industrial Revolution progressed, many canadian workers began to desire and employment towards “ a labor administration that w
ould respond to modern industrial conditions.”
81
In light of these dangerous conflicts, the condition of
municipal workers was not at all clear to anyone.
82
Where did municipal workers fit into the labor movem
ent? What kinds of organizations were most suited
107 83
Craig Heron and Myer Siemiat
ycki, “The Great War, the State, and Working-Class Canada,” in
The Workers’ Revolt in Canada,
1917-1925
, ed. C. HERON (Toronto: University of Toronto, 1998), 19.
84
Naylor, “Southern Ontario,” 147.
85
Greg Kealey, “State Repression of Labour and the Left in
Canada, 1914-1920: The Impact of the First World War,”
Canadian
Historical Review
73 no. 3 (1992), 306; Heron,
The Canadian Labour Movement
, 48.
to them ? Those who were skilled workers could be mo
re readily accommodated by already-existing craft
structures, but those many others
who were labourers were not seen as
‘respectable’ union men by craft
unions. All were employees of local governments whic
h diminished the rationale for international unionism.
Others were workers in culture medium to little communities
for whom craft divisions made little sense and only
served to fragment bargaining power. In all, there we
re no clear answers. However, these considerations
would not take concrete form until municipal actor
s actually organized into durable unions, a situation not
realized until the attack of the First World War. III.
World War One and the Emergence of Municipal and Hydro Unionism
urbanization, bodied concentration, civic boosterism, expansion of city services and employment, movements for municipal reform and praseodymium
ofessionalization of city administration, and debates
about union forms : these distinct but related processes ca
me together in the crucible of the First World War
and the subsequent “ labor rebellion ”. War production
and the numbers of men fighting overseas ended the
depression of 1913-14 and led a heightened demand for tug
which was increasingly in short supply.
These labour grocery store conditions gave canadian employment
ers “a new confidence” and an improved standard of
living for a brief meter, and allowed many former
ly unorganisable groups – like municipal workers – to
unionize and educe
de facto
union recognition from previously impervious employers.
83
In this period,
municipal workers were among those organizing unions “ at a stagger rate. ”
84
Indeed, the spread of
unionization to sectors like municipal study in which it was previously “ unthinkable ” was an indication of the extent and earnestness of the labor revolt.
85
For municipal administrations unused to negotiations and
108 86
J. Rouillard,
Histoire du syndicalism au Quebec: des origines à nos jours
(Montreal: Boréal, 1989), 149.
87
Bercuson, “The Winnipeg General Strike,” 4. This figure is based on data published monthly by the
Labour Gazette
.
88
Heron and Siemiatycki, 20.
89
Palmer, 166; Weaver,
Shaping the Canadian City
, 26-7.
90
Bercuson, “The Winnipeg General St
rike,” 4; Heron and Siematycki, 21.
91
Greg Kealey, “1919: The Canadian Labour Revolt,”
Labour/Le Travail
13 (Spring 1984): 41-2.
92
Heron and Siemiatycki, 33-4.
93
Rouillard, 148.
accustomed to undisputed and unilateral authority over
their employees, unionization was both a shock
and an diss.
86
As a solution, most of these early municipal locals faced enormous opposition and had to strike for courtly realization and a first contract.
In other words, they were pushed into militancy.
For most municipal workers, it was the economic
effects of the war, namely inflation, which
provided the spark for unionization. between 1914
and 1919, the cost of living rose between 50-75%.
87
By
December 1918, the propertyless “ family budget had leaped by 46 per cent over the 1916 level and, at the bill of the inflationary coiling in July 1920, by 82 per cent. ”
88
This spike continued a longer-term trend which
had commenced at the begin of Canada ’ second urban boom.
89
With the exception of those skilled trades in
high requirement in war-related industries, the huge majori
ty of workers were unable to keep pace with rising
prices.
90
As Kealey argues, the “inter-related issues of inflation, the cost of liv
ing, and war profiteering”
served to unite workers in a common oppositional proj
ect in ways that “the more limited workplace battles
sometimes failed to. ”
91
Public sector workers were amongst those “ par
ticularly victimized” by wartime inflation:
governments at all levels were specially bang-up to exercise engage chasteness as a room to deal with wartime expenditures and as an example to the secret sector.
92
This fiscal conservatism was not recent, either:
some groups of municipal workers, like those in
Montreal, had not received an increase for over ten
years.
93
However, the labour shortage provided these wo
rkers with more bargaining power than they had
previously possessed, and a total of the municipal
locals were forged in strikes over wages and
protection against ostentation. How municipal workers
used this bargaining power was important in terms of
109 94
Labour Gazette
, June 1913: 1419. Both parties accepted an arbitr
ated settlement on July 9, 1913, which included wage
increases, paid holidays, a nine-hour day,
and no discrimination agai
nst union members (
Labour Gazette
, August 1913: 186-7).
95
E.M. Ashworth,
Toronto Hydro Recollections
(Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1955), 48.
96
Armstrong and Nelles, 246.
97
Labour Gazette
, July 1919: 773; Armstrong and Nelles, 246.
98
Armstrong and Nelles, 246.
what it said about the setting for their classify identity and
their relationship to the broader community over the
longer condition. Workers at the Toronto Hydro-Electric System
, organized at this time by Local 353 of the
International Brotherhood of Electrical Workers,
demonstrated a marked wage militancy and made liberal
and reproducible consumption of the conciliation provisions of the
Industrial Disputes Investigation Act. This militancy
began in May 1914 with their beginning 2-day come to over w
hether workers would receive a 5-cent or 8-cent per
hour increase.
94
Throughout the war, these utility workers pressed for further increases to keep pace with
ostentation. In fall of 1915, the workers struck again to enforce a 5 % addition awarded them by an IDIA placation board but refused by the Commissioners.
The ability of the Commission to keep the power
going ended the three-week strike without gains, but in May 1916 the Commission raised wages by 5 % – which had been the placation board ’ s master award in any character.
95
In 1917, Toronto Hydro agreed to a
farther 5 % increase and a 5 % “ special wartime bonus ” to
“help employees cope with inflation” and “dampen
growing discontented. ”
96
By 1919, however, the Commission began to resist workers’ demands for a
reduction in the work week and for the conversion of
wartime bonuses into a permanent part of the wage.
rather of contact, however, the Toronto Hydro proletarian
s again used the Industrial Disputes Investigation Act
to secure a 15 % increase.
97
Armstrong and Nelles report that, as a resu
lt, linemen ’ randomness wages “ about treble [ vitamin d ] ” in the beginning ten of the municipal utility, “ from 27
7/9
cents to 78 cents per hour”.
98
This “wartime
aggressiveness ” was reflected in the utility sector more
generally: with a higher strike rate than the rest of
110 99
Ibid., 220.
100
This conflict will be discussed in more detail below.
101
James Naylor, “Toronto 1919,” in Canadian Historical Association
Historical Papers
(1986): 36-7;
Labour Gazette
, August
1913 : 612. 102
Naylor, “Toronto 1919″, 36-7;
Labour Gazette
, May 1918: 323.
103
Thomas, 23.
104
Geoffrey Ewen, “Quebec: Class and Ethnicity,” in
The Workers’ Revolt in Canada, 1917-1925
, ed. C. HERON (Toronto:
University of Toronto, 1998 ), 102. canadian industry between 1916-20, utility workers were
able to “stay slightly ahead of inflation” and
maintain these gains through the early 1920s.
99
Locals of civic workers besides pursued engage increases to
cope with war-time inflat
ion. Strikes of civic
workers in 1918-19 all concerned wage increases, in
flation and the question of whether wartime bonuses
would be integrated into post-war engage schedules
or would be rolled back. Winnipeg civic workers’
demands in April-May 1918 initially concern
the sufficiency of wages and wartime bonuses.
100
The
Toronto Civic Employees ’ Union No. 43, representi
ng nearly 1500 of the city’s 3000 labourers by July of
1918, went on a six-day strike over
the “entirely inadequate” anti-inflation war bonus they were receiving
and the city ’ s failure to make the increase retroactive.
101
The threat of a sympathy strike conducted by the
Toronto District Labour Council led city council to
accept an arbitrated settlement, a process they had
previously refused, in which about all the strikers ’ demands were met.
102
Hamilton civic workers, who had
organized in 1918, took a slightly different steer
ion and went on a successful strike in May 1919 for an
8-hour sidereal day for 9-hours pay.
103
other municipal workers were able to take adv
antage of wartime conditions to confront the
reorganization of municipal use
initiated by civic reformers.
Opposition to the implementation of
more “ effective ” and business-like local government formed
the context of the 1918 strike of Montreal civic
workers, police and firemen, and of water company use
ees in 1919, which were ostensibly about increased
wages and shorter working hours.
104
A reform coalition aiming to rationalize city administration and end
corruption and trade had won political restraint of
the city council in 1910. However, “business-like
111 105
Gauvin, 21-2.
106
Gauvin, 23; Wichern, 40.
107
Gauvin, 23; Ewen, 102.
108
Rouillard, 148.
109
Ewen, 101-2.
government ” did not lead to reduced expenditures or
an end to kickbacks. Rather, annexations and urban
growth continued, every city department had increased
expenditures, and public works projects like paving
were merely “ shifted … away from the eastern [ F
rancophone and working-class] wards to the more affluent
western wards. ”
105
These actions served to polarize the city further along class and ethnic lines. By the
depression of 1913-14, the affect of heavy municipal debt lode was catching up here, as it was elsewhere.
106
In 1918, after six years of the council back in the hands of the populists, the provincial
government appointed an administrative Commission to r
un the city in light of the financial problems
caused by former administrations of both reformers and populists. This Commission, less tied to the wards and city politics and advised by “ efficiency experts ”,
dealt with Montreal’s deficit by unilaterally “firing
excess employees ”, introducing a municipal civic service committee, redefining job descriptions, assignments and lines of assurance, and freezing salaries at a time of continuing eminent inflation.
107
They also
refused to negotiate with the unions ’ representatives.
108
In a context in where “French-Canadian workers …
expected to use their political pull to exert greater in
fluence over the allocation of jobs and services at the
municipal level ”, such moves were seen as undemocratic, tied to the class interests of the English- canadian bankers who held the city ’ south debt, and provoked
an outpouring of hostility. Overt class and ethnic
divisions informed this hit, and led municipal actor
s to broader organizational forms of solidarity in the
guise of “ a common front of patrol, firemen,
waterworks, engineers, and incinerator workers.”
109
other municipal workers ’ struggles were similarly politicized, but in ways that were more directly connected to the mean of the First World War and metric ton
he content of the “democratic values” for which
workers were exhorted to sacrifice. The level of rhenium
sistance to municipal worker unionism in many places
112 110
Pringle, 15.
111
David Bercuson,
Confrontation at Winnipeg: Labour, Industr
ial Relations, and the General Strike
. Rev. ed. (Montreal /
Kingston : McGill-Queen ’ south University Press,
1990), 58; Pringle, 17-18. The
participation of office workers is singular for this
time period. 112
Bercuson, “The Winnipeg General Strike,” 6.
113
Bercuson, “The Winnipeg General Strike,” 6; Bercuson,
Confrontation at Winnipeg
, 60.
raised the question of whether workers ’ right to union
recognition and to strike would be accepted as a part
of democratic citizenship. such questions were parti
cularly acute in the case of public employees, who
seemed to threaten the sovereignty of the democ
ratically elected governments who happened to be their
employers. The politicization of these conflicts by
city councils resulted in broader responses from local
labor movements. The Winnipeg municipal workers ’ strike of 1918 is
illustrative of this dynamic. In 1917, nearly 600
workers joined the Federation of Civic Employees, red brigades
inging together a wide array of employee groups, male
and female, from all departments, into one arrangement.
110
In 1918, the city’s teamsters, electrical workers,
water company employees, and agency workers ( alongside other
unions of electricians and firefighters) jointly
demanded engage increases, but rejected the city ’ s response – a bonus of two dollars a week “ designed to tide their employees over until peacetime ” and to av
oid “freez[ing] inflated wartime pay scales at an
artificially senior high school level. ”
111
However, the city’s business and political elite and local press were quick to turn a
“ straight dollars-and-cents write out ” into a political dispute over civil employees ’ right to strike.
112
A settlement worked out between the unions and a council sub-committee was scuttled by the full council through their inclusion of the “ Fowler Amendment ”, named after it
s sponsoring alderman. This amendment would have
“ all civil employees undertake to pledge that they would
not strike at all in future but would have their
grievances settled by arbitration ”, and was s
upported by the Board of
Trade and the Winnipeg Free
Press.
113
As Mitchell and Naylor point out, “[i]n the cont
ext of a war being fought ostensibly for democracy,
the refusal of the state to allow a group of workers
the right to participate in determining their own future
113 114
Tom Mitchell and James Naylor, “The Prai
ries: In the Eye of the Storm,” in
The Workers’ Revolt in Canada, 1917-1925
, ed. C.
Heron ( Toronto : University
of Toronto Press, 1998), 180.
115
Bercuson,
Confrontation at Winnipeg
, 60-1.
116
Bercuson,
Confrontation at Winnipeg
, 67; Bercuson, “The Winnipeg General
Strike,” 7; Mitchell and Naylor, 180.
117
David Bright,
The Limits of Labour: Class Formation
and the Labour Movement in Calgary
(Vancouver: UBC Press, 1998),
111-2. 118
Lenihan, 161; Mitchell and Naylor, 191.
119
Mitchell and Naylor, 200.
reeked of autocratic rule. ”
114
This “ undertake to put out a burn with a shower of gasoline ” mobilized the entire Winnipeg labour movement into a cosmopolitan sympathy
strike around a question of trade union principle.
115
The strikers ’ victory after ten-spot days demonstrated the
practical importance of br
oader forms of solidarity:
while the city had been able to keep the urine, prisoner of war
er and light departments running with ‘volunteers’,
participation in the strike of between fourteen
and seventeen thousand workers in public transportation,
telephone military service, displace stations, and railroad track sustenance,
among others, turned the tables in favour of the
municipal workers in Winnipeg.
116
This leave civil workers to be heavy involved in the Winnipeg General strike one year former. other canadian municipal workers were besides hundred
onfronting the fiscal restraint and autocratic
management style of city councils. The Calgary Feder
ation of Civic Employees, assisted by the local
trades and tug council, emerged between 1913-15 in res
ponse to a series of wage cuts, but also the
“ hob-nailed heel of dictatorship ” which characteri
zed the city’s approach to labour relations.
117
The local of
labourers was formally established by 1917, and was on strike in 1918 for union recognition.
118
On the other hand, many municipal workers ’ gr
oups were at best ambivalent and halfhearted in
their subscribe for the Winnipeg General Strike and other localized sympathy strikes of the menstruation. The position taken by populace employees in these strikes was
important, as they were often more visible to the
community ; the secession of their participation was
conspicuous and gave the impression that the dispute
was over.
119
Civic workers in Edmonton and Regina jo
ined sympathy strikes supporting the Winnipeggers,
114 120
Kealey, “1919,” 30; Mitchell and Naylor, 200.
121
Thomas, 23-4.
122
Naylor, “Toronto 1919,” 47; Kealey, “1919,” 28.
123
Mitchell and Naylor, 199.
124
Bright, 149.
125
Conley, 22, 20.
but returned early on as the strike “ was abandoned … as a doomed campaign. ”
120
Hamilton civic workers began their
mint on the lapp day as the Winnipeg General Stri
ke, but there was no indication that their efforts
contained any sympathy for the Winnipeg workers, particu
larly as they returned to work after two days and
upon settlement of their own quarrel.
121
Though Toronto civic workers officially backed a general strike
supporting the local metallic trades council in May 1919, t
hey chose to remain on the job until their contract
expired on June 16
th
, by which time the strike had already been called off.
122
Calgary civic workers were
similarly ambivalent in their support for workers who were not companion members. While they participated in October 1918 sympathy hit supporting Calgary cargo
handlers, eight months later they “opted not to
wager their newly achieved corporate
agreement” on the Winnipeg General Strike.
123
Bright even throws
doubt on the exuberance of the civil workers for parti
cipation in the 1918 sympathy strike: while they may
have voted in privilege of the legal action, they were not amongs
t the first to walk out. In fact, Bright implies the
public works and outside workers had to be
ordered off the job by their leaders.
124
Finally, Vancouver civil employees joined the sympathetic strike there and evening
voted to join the One Big Union in the spring of
1919, but were besides conflicted. The 250 permanent
construction workers “became preoccupied with
conservation of their longevity rights ” and reversed t
heir decision to join the OBU once the Winnipeg strike
had failed.
125
municipal workers in this period were therefor
e reaching towards broader forms of identification,
but remained limited in their drill of solidarity and
the risks they would take for other workers. These
workers were, as Kealey argues, part of a national
labour revolt and a heightening of working-class
awareness that was a answer to both the Firs
t World War and the “underlying structural changes in
115 126
Kealey, “1919,” 15-6.
127
Ibid., 39.
128
Naylor, “Toronto 1919,” 52.
capitalistic organization. ”
126
As well, the addition of municipal workers ( and public employees more generally ) to the ranks of the organized work class contribut
ed to the intensification
of labour-management conflict
during and after the war.
127
However, the concrete decisions of civic workers in the period indicate just how
uneven this burgeoning class consciousness and feel with trade unionism was in practice. nowadays added to the paternalist pull of municipal employers and
the mentality of public service was the desire to
protect hard-won contractual gains for the contiguous residential district of workers. This should not be taken as evidence of a lack of combativeness ; alternatively, as Naylor ar
gues, “[t]he struggle to establish a degree of protection
in the workplace through the mechanism of systeme international d’unites
gned agreements had proved so labourious that, once
established, the holiness of the contract had
become the guiding principle of their unionism.”
128
In other
words, the exercise of corporate bargain was
serving to shape the consciousness and identities of
municipal workers from their first foray into trade unionism. municipal workers came out of the First World Wa
r arrayed in two main organizational forms which
uncover something about the oscilloscope of identity and bunco
sciousness at this point. An important connection
existed between the types of constitution created and deoxythymidine monophosphate
he types of strikes fought during and after the war.
Those workers engaged in more overtly politicized st
rikes or who had been affiliated to US-based craft
unions tended to create broader-based unions based on
the industrial model and reaching towards a
national structure, although in reality these remai
ned regionally bounded. Those whose strikes were more
economistic tended to remain independent locals, calculate
ly chartered to the Trades and Labor Congress and
within the scope of international trade unionism. T
hese two main organizational forms imprinted each group
of municipal unions with discrete characteristics .
116 129
Logan, 96-7.
130
A.M. Barnetson, “A Brief History of the CETU,” 1965: 1.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 13]
131
Barnetson, 2.
In the immediate post-war menstruation, some electric
workers in the public sector became increasingly
anxious to break free of the constraints of chromium
aft unionism as defined by US-based unions like the
International Brotherhood of electrical Workers ( I
BEW). Rejecting the fragmentation which came with
narrowly define crafts, populace sector electric work
ers in the Toronto area were turning to industrial
organizing. These workers were besides opposed to the centralization of control in the US headquarters of the internationals, and were theref
ore part of a current of independent
Canadian unionism. They translated
these commitments into the formation of the Canadi
an Electrical Trade Union (CETU) in 1921 as well as
affiliation to the hyper-nationalist canadian Federation of Labour. The core of CETU was formed in September 1921 by 1200 Toronto-area electrical workers breaking away from the IBEW ’ s local 353. The IBEW
itself was riven with internal tensions: while
apparently a craft constitution, the Brotherhood in fact encompassed many different occupational groups linked to the production and transmission of electricity,
introducing a basis for factionalism within the union.
however, it appears that “ antagonistic social philosophies ”, a “ disfavor of international unionism ”, and the “ personal ambition of local anesthetic lambert
eaders” also informed the split.
129
Conflicts in IBEW Local 353 over the
allow model of unionism and the question of who should decide such things came to a drumhead in 1919, when a successful organizing political campaign amongst munici
pal hydro and electrical workers was undermined
by the International Office ’ s imperativeness that a lot of the newly organized membership be transferred to other craft unions. Sections of the Toronto
membership “vigorously opposed” this directive.
130
This
discontented was exacerbated by “ continued raids on thymine
he local treasury along with constant levies and
assessments from head office in the USA … due to st
rikes and lock-outs of members over in the USA.”
131
As a consequence of the perception that association wisconsin
th the American headquarters was more drain than support,
117 132
International Brotherhood of El
ectrical Workers, “History Local 353 Toronto,
” n.d., online at http://www.ibew353.org/ourprofil
e/
history353.htm. local 353 was established in 1903 and continues
to exist, representing electric
al workers in the private
construction industry in Toronto. While the
IBEW’s website does not expl
ain the meaning of the term “canaries”, it may simply b
e
a play on “ Canadian ”, as those interest in
purely national unionism. There may be
an additional implication that these were
“ flighty ” or unreliable members. Ironi
cally, however, the canary has a specific
symbolic meaning in Canadian union lore: the b
irds
were brought into mines to warn the workers when there was no oxygen left. Were these ‘ canaries ’ signalling that there was no ‘ oxygen ’ left in IBEW Local 353 ? 133
Barnetson, 2.
134
The Canadian Federation of
Labour (1902-1927) is not to be confused with the Canadian Federati
on of Labour (1981-1998),
which consisted of affiliates of the international construction
trades unions who left the CLC ov
er the question of national autono
my
( Heron,
The Canadian Labour Movement
, 174; see Laxer for details of this conflict and CUPE’s role in it).
135
Barnetson, 3; Heron,
The Canadian Labour Movement
, 174-75.
all but about 35 of Local 353 ‘s membership left “ to join up
in what the [IBEW] old-timers now refer to as the
‘ Canaries ’. ”
132
The new CETU Local 1 in Toronto included out
side linemen from Toronto Hydro, the Toronto
Transit Commission, and Bell Telephone. A.M. Barnetson, a establish member of Local 1 and later National President of NOCUEW, believed that
CETU represented the first group of electrical workers in Canada
organized along the lines of industrial unionism.
133
Electrical utility worker
s from outside the Toronto area
were drawn to this approach to unionism, and were given moral confirm to set up locals in their own communities. In the absence of a rightfully national constitution in
the electrical utility sector, CETU Local 1 and
early active locals were affiliated in the interim to the canadian Federation of Labour ( CFL ),
134
which
consisted of the remnants of the Knights of
Labour and other independent national unions competing with
AFL affiliates and expelled from the Trades and Labor Congress in 1902.
135
We can infer something of
CETU ’ sulfur orientation from their membership in this
organization, although a definitive assessment is difficult
given the building complex grizzle of clashing ideas which coex
isted within the CFL. The breakaway Federation was
actively hostile to international unions, and associated me
mbership in them with a lack of patriotism. Like
CETU, members of the CFL had experienced international
unionism as an “autocratic” form of “foreign
118 136
Logan, 376; Charles Lipton,
The Trade Union Movement of Canada, 1827-1959
(Toronto: NC Press, 1966), 146. Lipton goes
therefore far as to suggest the CFL ’ s positi
on reflected a certain anti-imperialism.
137
Logan, 375, 379.
138
Ibid., 375-6.
139
Cripso, 154.
140
Lipton, 147.
141
Namely Local 1 Toronto Hydro, Local 2 Toronto Transit Commission, Local 8 York Township Hydro, and Local 11 North York
Hydro. domination ” which risked subordinating the intere
sts of Canadian workers to those from the US.
136
Personal
and bitter experiences with the internationals had informed this view, and while such grievances were not enough to generate a groundswell of confrontation to international
unionism, it did sustain the hard core of the
CFL ’ s membership.
137
The arrangement aimed to replace bury
nationals by bringing all labour organizations
in Canada together in national unions. Their motto, “ Canada for Canadians ”, signalled both a desire for independence and local control, but besides for the exclus
ion of “foreign workers”, particularly Americans,
seeking “ to replace [ Canadians ] in the production activities which should be [ theirs ]. ”
138
The CFL’s
nationalism led to an advocacy of protectionist
tariffs against imported American goods, and government
and employer recognition of canadian unions only. Their opposition to the american Federation of Labour gave them common campaign with the political elite and the canadian Manufacturers ’ Association ( CMA ), who themselves denounced the internationals ’ organizers as “ extraneous agitators ”.
139
Some argue that the CFL
was therefore led into classify collaboration, evidenced by
their alliance with the CMA and their support for the
application and extension of the IDIA and conciliation
in general as a method of resolving industrial
disputes.
140
After losing closely half of its membership in 1922 to a Bell Telephone Employees Association set astir by the employer, CETU Local 1 finally joined
with other public utility electrical workers across
Canada in July 1924 at a meet in Niagara Falls to
found the National Union of the CETU. Delegates
from CETU locals and independent unions attended from Toronto,
141
Hamilton, Niagara Falls, London,
Cambellford, Kingston, Belleville, Perth, Ottawa,
Montreal, Trois Rivieres, Winnipeg, Regina, Calgary,
119 142
Barnetson, 3.
143
Barnetson, 4.
144
Barnetson, 5.
145
Armstrong and Nelles, 219.
Edmonton and Vancouver.
142
The convention endorsed a Constitution and elected a nine-person
executive, including a Secretary-Tr
easurer to be paid by head office and district representatives from
Quebec, Ontario, Manitoba, Alberta and British Columbia.
143
Despite ostensible national representation,
however, the core of CETU continued to be local 1 at
Toronto Hydro. On the basis of this ‘national’
union, and despite the unfavorable economic and legislat
ive climate, CETU locals did make progress.
indeed, Barnetson claims that the accomplishment of such benefits as “ vacations, paid holidays, accumulated brainsick wage, pensions and minimum wage ” a early as 1927 made CETU a “ drawing card in the field of trade unionism. ”
144
CETU therefore represented an matter to and much
contradictory mix of approaches to unionism and
visions of democracy and identity, which is unsurprising given the diverse influences pressing upon it. It had opted for industrial quite than craft unionism, signa
lling a broader identification with class rather than
occupation. As well, their emphasis on independent
Canadian unionism was rooted in a desire for
democratic manipulate by the immediate membership as
opposed to control by a central office in the US.
however, such patriotism could besides indicate
tendencies towards particularism and narrowness.
furthermore, the class awareness which CETU exhibited was besides ambiguous, as was evidenced in their support for and habit of the IDIA. While this patronize was in many respects tactical and resulted in positive economic outcomes for the membership, it besides
indicated a preference for rational and harmonious
engagement with employers. This tendency may have
been reinforced once electricity was municipalized,
since strikes and their fiscal outcomes could hav
e negative impacts on the public the workers were
mean to serve. That said, electric light and exponent
workers tended to be relatively more strike-prone than
other municipal workers through the 1920s.
145
120 146
Pringle, 20, 22.
Winnipeg civil workers, in the context of a comm
unity with very sharp class divisions, had also
produced broader forms of working class solidarity. In
this process, the 1918 strike was ideologically quite
formative, particularly in terms of the manner that the red brigades
oader labour movement came to the civic workers’ aid.
The Winnipeg labor milieu was steeped in a class con
scious understanding of the specific battles between
workers and employers : according to Winnipeg Labour
Council president Fred Tipping, “[t]he existence of
barter unionism was … challenged by the capitalist intere
sts of the city.” As such, Winnipeg civic workers
learned in very practical way that solidarity wh
ich transcended occupational boundaries was the only way
that “ employers would … meet them as equals ” and
worked to create organizations that express these
conclusions.
146
however, the severe repression that play along
ed the 1919 Winnipeg General Strike made it very
difficult for Winnipeg civil workers to maintain their organizational oneness.
Municipal employers like the City
of Winnipeg besides knew that british labour party integrity which transc
ended sectionalism would pose a real threat to their
fiscal and practical control over the workplace, and they actively worked to reinforce those divisions. Having fired all civic workers for participating in deoxythymidine monophosphate
he Strike, Winnipeg city council required all those who
wished to return to sign a document in which they pledged not to join a union nor engage in any sympathetic strike actions. Called the “ Slave Pac
t”, this agreement primarily forced the white collar
workers, who were still organized by the Federation of
Civic Employees, out of their affiliation with the
broader Winnipeg british labour party movement until the 1940s. A ke
y goal of the city here was to break their
employees ’ affiliation with the One Big Union, whic
h had emerged immediately after the General Strike and
aimed to unify all workers in a park, class-consci
ous organization. In that context, the Council, “when
faced with the option of dealing with the militant OBU
or a craft union,” chose the latter. As a result, many
city workers did opt to join one of the IBEW, the Wa
ter Works Operators Union,
and the Federation of Civic
121 147
Pringle, 25-6.
148
Ewen, 104, 112.
Employees ( representing by and large blank collar workers ),
as these were the only groups with which the city
would bargain and sign agreements. however, despite these employer tactics, outside civil workers like general labourers, parks employees and garbage collector
s remained committed to the One Big Union and
were represented by them and Winnipeg General St
rike leader R.B. Russell until the early 1950s.
147
Montreal municipal workers besides strove to create
bodies that went beyond their sectional identities.
This desire can be detected not only in these locals ’ initia
l multi-occupational strike in 1918, but also in their
disregard for one of the terms of the intercede settlement to that disput
e which stipulated that “civic unions
were required to sever all ties with each other and wisconsin
th any other organizations, such as the [local] trades
and labour council. ” however, there were limits to th
is expansive consciousness: municipal workers were
amongst those sections of the Montreal labor missouri
vement which “denounced the OBU, Bolshevism, and the
[ Winnipeg ] general strike. ”
148
There were two influences which led the Montreal
ers to be both sectionalist and anti-socialist. First,
even though the municipal workers were not members
of a Catholic labour organization, the influence of
the Catholic Church and its corporatist social six
sion on the Francophone working class’ attitude towards
socialism should not be ignored. The Church “ discour
aged class conflict, preferred
arbitration over strikes,
underscore workers ’ duties to their employers,
and opposed independent political activity on the part of
workers. ” While this did not prevent expressions of meter
ilitancy by Montreal municipal workers, it did mitigate
the development of a politicize wage-earning consci
ousness. Added to this was the influence of the
autonomist orientation of the inte
rnational craft unions that dom
inated the Montreal Trades and Labour
council, the leaders of which insist
ed that “only individual unions, not the council”, could decide whether to
122 149
Ibid., 112, 118, 132.
150
Ibid., 114.
151
Logan, 294; Kealey, “State Repression,
” 307; Saul Frankel and Cranford Pratt,
Municipal Labour Relations in Canada
( montreal : McGill Industrial Relations Centre / Canadi
an Federation of Mayors and Municipalities, 1954), 3.
documentation the Winnipeg General Strike. furthermore, respect for the “ holiness of contracts ” a well as the jurisprudence worked to reinforce non-socialist forms of combativeness.
149
In early words, Montreal and Quebec City muni
cipal workers wanted “to establish organizations
that could bargain more efficaciously than craft unions
and that would include unskilled workers”, but were
reluctant to embrace some of the ideological implicat
ions of the more socialist versions of industrial
unionism stream at the clock.
150
Quebec municipal workers were also bound by their strong national identity
which intersected potently with classify, and ther
efore focussed attention on building strong regional
organizations. These efforts finally took t
he form of the Fédération Nationale des Employés
Municipaux. While these three groupings in Toronto, Winnipeg and Montreal demonstrat
ed the early capacity of
some municipal workers to create broader
(if still limited) institutionalized fo
rms of solidarity, they were the
exception that proved the rule. By far the most
common organizational form taken by municipal unions
after the first base World War was the independent local or
“federal labour union”, directly chartered by the
Trades and Labor Congress and unconnected to each other via any larger geographic or sectoral body.
151
The continuing presence of a very protective
and exclusivist unionism in the independent TLC
locals could be seen from the means in which returning veterans who had been city employees were treated by the unions which now existed in their early workpl
aces. In Calgary, for instance, a full 67% of civic
employees had been abroad, and the resulting shor
tage of labour was undoubtedly a major reason for
why a union could be formed there. however, conf
licts arose around which group of workers would be
accorded longevity. In March of 1924, the Cal
gary Federation of Civic Employees decided it would
recognize as broad employees those who had been tantalum
ken on during the war, and
therefore grant them
123 152
Bright, 143-4.
153
James Naylor,
The New Democracy: Challenging the Soci
al Order in Industrial Ontario, 1914-1925
(Toronto: University of
Toronto Press, 1991 ), 64. 154
Power Workers’ Union,
The Power Workers’ Union 50
th
Anniversary: A pictorial histor
y of the union of workers behind the
structure, operation and sustenance of
one of the world’s great power systems
(Toronto: Power Workers’ Union, 1996), 4-5.
longevity rights. many recently ( rhenium ) hired veterans w
ould therefore be let go in the city’s post-war job cuts.
152
While this very dissentious decision did not have t
he unanimous support of the membership, one can see the
lastingness and bearing of a very exclusivist unionism c
haracterized by restrictive notions of solidarity.
similarly, as Toronto civic workers strove field-grade officer
r broader organizations, they did so in ways that
maintained the sectional boundaries between different gr
oups of public sector workers. In May 1919, a
Public Utilities Council brought together
14,000 federal, provincial and muni
cipal workers (including Toronto
Hydro workers ) together in a common arrangement led by
street railway workers. Though this represented
the “ potent attraction of the motion towards am
algamation”, the PUC’s leaders insisted that “if anyone
… was to have trouble, each would have local autonom
y and it does not mean that the whole 16 [locals]
would go on hit. ”
153
Municipal workers, like other public sector
workers, were making half-steps towards
broader solidarities, but as so far unwilling to subjec
t themselves to the consequences of transferring
democratic exponent to a broader community of workers. Parallel to these developments in municipal-level
unionism was the shift in the purpose of the
Ontario Hydro-Electric Power Commission during and a
fter the First World War and its impact on work and
tug relations there. electricity shortages, risi
ng prices and industrial unemployment caused by the 1902
u coal strike provided another impulse for an “ inexhaus
tible supply of cheap power” controlled in Ontario.
From its origin to the middle of the 1930s, the H
EPC was moving from power distribution to generation.
The Commission began purchasing and building its own
generating stations in 1914, in response to
wartime increases in the need for electric
ity, with which it could not keep pace.
154
This centralization
124 155
S. Dubovoj, “Ontario Hydro,”
Canadian Company Histories
(June 1997): 2.
156
Power Workers’ Union, 5-6.
157
Armstrong and Nelles, 246.
158
Armstrong and Nelles, 245.
and expansion continued after the war, when in 1922 triiodothyronine
he HEPC built the Queens
ton-Chippewa Generating
station at Niagara Falls, then “ the lar
gest power generator in the world.”
155
The transformation of the HEPC into an elec
tricity generator was br
inging enormous numbers of
workers in concert under the auspices of an increasingl
y centralized employer. The construction of the
Queenston-Chippewa site, for exemplify, employed ei
ght thousand workers; the skilled amongst them were
members of versatile building and construction trades
unions, but repeated attempts to organize the linemen
and labourers had failed.
156
Nonetheless, in May 1919, these workers engaged in a strike under the
auspices of the Niagara District Tr
ades Federation, and successfully resi
sted the Commission ’ s reinstitution of the 10-hour day as a method acting for dealing with carbon monoxide
st overruns on the Niagara project. It seemed that
unions now had a foothold at the Hydro. however, Beck did not sit easy with unions in
his midst. Although the IDIA had ruled in the
workers ’ favour in 1919, Beck continued to believe that
it was inappropriate for the HEPC to fall under the
Act ’ randomness legal power at all. In argumentation with his agreement of
the role of Hydro in Ontario society, Beck believed
that “ the commission, as an branch of government, wa
s fully able to express the popular will … had none of
the selfish interests of a secret ship’s company but was me
rely a trustee for its member municipalities. How
could it submit to binding arbitration without sacrificing those interests if
the [IDIA] board were to find for the
unions ? ”
157
In light of the role that the 1902 coal strike
had played in the rationale for publicly-owned power,
it was not surprising that Beck and his successors
worked tirelessly to prevent their employees from
“ enriching themselves at the expense of their companion citizens. ”
158
The main proficiency used by Beck in this quest, “ corporate welfarism ”, was increasingly popular during the 1920s. Designed to reestablish or reinforc
e unilateral management control over the workplace
125 159
Margaret McCallum, “Corporat
e Welfarism in Canada, 1919-1939,”
Canadian Historical Review
71, no. 1 (1990): 46-7.
160
Power Workers’ Union, 6-7.
161
McCallum, 52.
and to secure workers ’ consent to a hierarchically integrated cultivate envir
onment, corporate welfare
programmes involved services “ provided for the comfort
or improvement of employ
ees which [were] neither
a necessity of the diligence nor required by jurisprudence. ”
159
such initiatives ranged from pensions, profit-sharing plans, leisure activities and refreshment programmes,
and a variety of other means to make the working
environment more pleasant. In the case of the Hydro, such techniques emerged early in the form of a refreshment board and fully-staffed hospital on site at the Queenston-Chippewa locate. By the mid- 1920s, the Commission contributed two-thirds of the cost of
a jointly-funded pension plan which “paid 50% of the
employee ’ s good five years of earnings after 40 years ”
of service. These programmes were successful, for
though some workers chafed under the personal and arbitr
ary control of their supervisors, and unions like
the IBEW attempted several organizing drives, “ w
idespread support for the idea of a union at Hydro
remained a outback candidate. ”
160
It is difficult to gauge the depth of this ‘consent’, for like all corporate
wellbeing schemes, these plans creat
ed no legal entitlements for employees, and were dispensed according
to rules decided upon entirely by the employer. Therefore, some employees may have disavowed unionism out of a genuinely-felt loyalty to an employer generous enough to provide what others did not, while others shied away out of a fear of disentitlement.
161
In any subject, such programmes surely had a profound effect on the development of Ontario Hydro workers ’ course hundred
onsciousness and their relationship to the rest of the
working class. What all these unions had in common in the in
ter-war period, however, was their relative
debilitation vis-à-vis management. The end of the Firs
t World War brought severe economic dislocations
as unemployment returned with the demobilization of
the armed forces and the decline in war-related
industries. furthermore, employers now faced organized workforces who had, through their combativeness, been
126 162
Craig Heron, “National Contours:
Solidarity and Fragmentation,” in
The Workers’ Revolt in Canada, 1917-1925
, ed. C.
HERON, ( Toronto : University of Toronto, 1998 ), 287. 163
Warren Magnusson, “Introduction: The Deve
lopment of Canadian Urban Government,” in
City Politics in Canada
, eds. W.
Magnusson and A. Sancton ( Toronto : Un
iversity of Toronto Press, 1983), 11.
164
Bright, 144.
165
Ewen, 118. The class identity of the police was of particular
concern not only to municipal em
ployers but also to the broader
business community : a police force that saw itself as working class and sympathized with stri
kers, as in the Winnipeg General
strike, would make it very difficult to use t
he state to control expressions of class conflict.
166
Rouillard, 150.
able to raise their wages to levels that interfered
with competitiveness and profit
ability, as well as their
unilateral manipulate over the tug action. Priv
ate employers thus “launched a concerted offensive of
union-busting and wage-cutting in an effort to reclai
m the ground conceded to labour under extraordinary
wartime circumstances. ”
162
populace employers participated in this backfire against high wages and unionize workforces. As Warren Magnussen points out, cities were left with
a heavy debt burden from war-time spending and the
province to provide relief to growing numbers of
the unemployed. Municipal governments also faced
great pressure from the business community for tax copper
ts they claimed would rejuvenate the local economy.
As a resultant role, “ cutters ” gained dominance on many councils in a invite “ to save the ratepayers from excessive burdens ”, and municipal locals endured a series of auste
rity measures in the form of both job and wage
cuts, becoming shadows of their wartime selves.
163
The loss of members and the return of unemployment
weakened these locals and made it extremely unmanageable to
strike or otherwise make gains materially or
organizationally.
164
In some cities, the power of municipal loca
ls – particularly those with broader organizational
tendencies – was directly attacked by city councils equally soon as the war-induced parturiency deficit subsided. In Montreal, for case, the city council elect
ed in 1921 was “decidedly hostile to organized labour” and
battled against the rights of patrol, firefighters and aqueduct workers to unionize.
165
The city continued to
reject dinner dress recognition of any of its employees ’ unions through the 1920s.
166
The continued deterioration
127 167
Rouillard, 149.
168
Human Resources and Development Canada, Revi
ew of Canada Labour Code, Part I, 1996, Online at
hypertext transfer protocol : //www110.hrdc-drhc.gc.ca/sfmc_fmcs/lcctr_tclcr/toc.html in working conditions and the increasing challenge
to their legitimacy sustained municipal workers’
combativeness, but this in turn provoked, in 1921, a res
trictive provincial law which regulated strikes and lock-
outs of all-important services in the municipal sector.
167
In other words, in many places the employer was
actively involved in making broader forms of solidarity and class identity very costly and unmanageable to sustain. What little legal protections municipal workers
enjoyed also vanished in the years following World
War One. As we have seen, a major joyride wh
ich, until the mid-1920s, had helped electrical utility and
municipal workers make gains was the Industrial Dis
putes Investigation Act and its powers of conciliation.
Established in 1907 and authored by William Lyon MacKenzie King, the IDIA, “ An Act to Aid in the prevention and Settlement of Strikes and Lockouts in Mi
nes and Industries Connected with Public Utilities”,
reflected the federal express ’ s growing concern to pr
event strikes in sectors upon which the public (and the
business community ) relied heavily such as ember, railways, and hydro-electricity.
168
Also known as the
Lemieux Act, the IDIA mandated that all labour-management conflicts in mine, transportation, public utilities, and industries under federal jurisdiction were
required to submit their dispute to an appointed board
of placation before a hit or lockout could take place. While the Act did not explicitly apply to municipal employees, who fell under provincial jurisdicti
on, the Federal Department of Labour had adopted the
practice of striking a Board upon reciprocal agreement of
employer and employees. Though the IDIA was part
of the federal government ’ s try to manage the ex-wife
pression of class conflict by consent rather than
compulsion, and frequently disarmed workers in their disputes with employers, many unions however advocated its use. many municipal and utility worker locals made liberal consumption of the IDIA process during the
128 169
Judy Fudge and Eric Tucker,
Labour Before the Law: the Regulation of Wo
rkers’ Collective Action in Canada, 1900-1948 (
Don
Mills, ON : Oxford University Press, 2001 ), 78-9. 170
Ibid., 79. The Quebec court turned down this challenge and
upheld the federal government’s right to intervene in such
disputes under its built-in duty
to uphold “peace, order and good government.”
171
Ibid., 134.
172
Armstrong and Nelles, 246.
173
Armstrong and Nelles, 246.
war for the purposes of engage bargain,
169
and were frequently correct in their assumption that boards of
conciliation would at least grant wage increases in
light of inflationary pressures on real wages.
increasingly, public utilities commissions and municipal governments chafed under the IDIA and the shock its decisions had on their budgets. angstrom early as 1912, public employers like the Montreal Street Railway were challenging the constitutionality of the IDIA.
170
Opponents argued their case on two fronts.
first, the Act violated the BNA Act since the state
s had exclusive jurisdiction over “property and civil
rights ” ; labor relations, in this view, were separate of
“the domain of the market where consensual relations
purportedly prevailed. ”
171
Second was an argument about which level
of government had the right to define
and defend the populace sake. Adam Beck, for example,
rejected the necessity of the IDIA’s intervention in
labour-management disputes at the HEPC, on the grounds
that “the commission, as an arm of government,
was in full able to express the democratic will ” and had to
be free from binding arbitration if it was to properly
represent the interests of the
municipal governments it served.
172
In the background, however, were the private industrial interests who had
supported the municipalisation of
utilities precisely on the basis of
receiving bum power at monetary value ; for them, the wages of
municipal electrical workers had to be kept at a
‘ reasonable ’ flat. It was, however, the beginning argument which finally
held sway. In 1921, the Toronto Hydro Electric
Commission launched a challenge to the electrical work
ers’ fifth attempt to get a wage increase through
IDIA interposition.
173
This time,
Toronto Electric Commissioners v. Snider
went all the way to Britain’s
Judicial Committee of the Privy Council which, under
the leadership of Viscount Haldane, opted for a very
129 174
G. DiGiacomo,
Federalism and Labour Policy in Canada
, working paper (Kingston, ON:
Institute of Intergovernmental
Relations, Queen ’ s University, 2001 ), 7. 175
Fudge and Tucker, 140-1.
176
Frankel and Pratt, 2.
decentralist read of the BNA Act. Rather than granti
ng the legitimacy of the f
ederal politics ’ second desire to manage labor “ disputes which could affect the
national welfare”, Haldane agreed with the Commission
“ that the Act conduct with civil rights and municipal
institutions and both were provincial matters.”
174
The IDIA
was frankincense declared
ultra vires
with respect to municipal disputes in 1925, and the federal government was
forced to amend the Act. now, the IDIA would only appl
y to labour disputes in those industries explicitly
listed in the BNA Act as under federal jurisdiction. T
he provinces could opt in to the IDIA and have it apply
to provincial jurisdiction, a course taken by Br
itish Columbia, Manitoba, Saskatchewan and New Brunswick.
however, Ontario and Quebec, with the largest num
bers of unionized municipal and utilities workers,
remained outside the IDIA until the 1930s.
175
After 1925, many municipal workers consequently
no longer had access to the conciliation process
they had used to their capital advantage, lost what short
legal protection they had, and existed in a legislative
vacuum until well into the 1930s.
176
The decision in the
Snider
case, combined with post-war political and
economic conditions, made it very unmanageable for civic em
ployee unions to establish or maintain themselves as
effective corporate dicker agents, and to expand thymine
heir membership both within locals and to other
cities. This position was only to worsen with the attack of the Great Depression. IV.
Depression, War and the Evolution
of Canadian Public Sector, 1929-1945
The Great Depression which began in 1929 bring to
a halt the brief economic recovery of the
late 1920s. The recurrence of unemployment on a multitude scale besides had a serious negative impact on coupling exponent throughout the economy. Interestingly, union me
mbership levels and density rates for this period
130 177
M. Huberman and D. Young,
Hope Against Hope: Persistent Canadi
an Unions in the Interwar Years
. Scientific Series, no. 28.
( montreal : Centre interuniversitaire
de recherche en analise des organisations
, 2000), 21. The average number of union
members between 1922-1928 was 272,000, with a density rate of
12.6%. Between 1929-1936, t
he average number of union
members was 301,000, with a density rate of 14.8 %. 178
James Struthers,
No Fault of Their Own: Unemploym
ent and the Canadian Welfare State, 1914-1941
(Toronto: University of
Toronto Press, 1983 ), 9. This decentralization of wellbeing besides served the federal government ’ second interest in ensuring that relief levels were kept in agate line with local labor market conditions, thus
that relief would not seem more economically attractive than
working. A federal plan which defined
the minimum would have to establish such
uniformity and therefore would interfere with the employment ethic ( Struthers, 85 ). 179
Alvin Finkel, “Origins of t
he Welfare State in Canada,” in
The Canadian State: Political Economy and Political Power
, ed. L.
Panitch ( Toronto : University of Toronto, 1977 ), 350. increased above the modal level in the 1920s.
177
However, this signalled both the depth of the employers’
post-war victory against the unions deoxyadenosine monophosphate well as the
way that high levels of unemployment increased
unionize workers ’ proportional parcel in the employed wo
rkforce. Moreover, the massive expansion in the
military reserve pool of british labour party restricted unions ’ ability to make gains on the footing of these levels of membership and concentration. however, it was the federal and municipal state ’ mho methods for dealing with the Depression that had a peculiarly deep impact on municipal oeuvre and munici
pal unions. The combination of the British North
America Act ’ s silence on the question of unemployment
and the poor-law tradition of making “care of the
destitute a local province ” meant that munici
pal governments were charged with distributing relief.
178
It
had been a longstanding practice to use municipal employment
ment as a means for distributing relief in periods
of impermanent unemployment and for staffing public works
projects at relatively low cost. The acute and
apparently ageless nature of the econom
ic downturn in the 1930s led to an explosion of demands for relief
and jobs on public works like never ahead. The
emergence of “well-organiz
ed and generally Communist-
led campaigns of the unemployed workers in the milliampere
jor municipalities … [s]upported by trade unionists …
presented the ghost of a revolt of the workers to
the frightened pillars of the communities in charge of
municipal councils ” ; their campaigns insisted on the dist
ribution of relief even if it meant “defaulting on the
cities ’ debts. ”
179
The issue of the state’s responsibility to
serve the class interests of workers via
employment frankincense became and significant part of the class struggle of the menstruation .
131 180
Lenihan, 162.
181
Palmer, 244.
182
Carol Baines, “The Professions and an Ethic of Care,” in
Women’s Caring: Feminist Perspectives on Social Welfare
, eds. C.
Baines et alabama. ( Toronto : Mc
Clelland and Stewart, 1991), 41, 44-48.
For municipal workers themselves, however, the practi
ce of providing municipal relief in the form of
use made it extremely difficult to maintain wages, working conditions, levels of employment and even unions, which they had been struggling to do since the end of the First World War. Relief cultivate placed a Sword of Damocles over municipal employees, for nowadays there was the ever-present screw thread of replacing permanent wave employees on public works with stand-in recipient role
s. In some communities, the sword fell: Calgary
city council “ laid off about 80 percentage of the civil employees and put them on relief ”, using federal and provincial help to pay the majority of what was the municipality ’ randomness engage bill.
180
In terms of class identity and
solidarity, municipal workers faced contradictory pressures during the D
epression. The economic crisis did
drive working conditions to a low common denominator and produced an unprecedented sense of coarse suffer and class awareness, in which “ einsteinium
verybody felt just a little bit revolutionary.”
181
however, those unionize workers who had been able to
retain a modicum of institutional presence
nurtured a defensive and sectionalist job protectionism
against those who were threatening to take ‘their
jobs ’. The practice of providing lead relief ( in the
form of payments to heads of households and families)
besides led to the growth of newfangled categories of muni
cipal work, especially social work, whose connection to
working class identity and consciousness was besides am
biguous. Along with public health officials, social
workers first gear emerged during the flower of munici
pal reform, and were initially driven by upper- and
middle-class philanthropy and the social gospel.
182
Social workers, whether under the auspices of Church
or State, saw themselves as ‘ social evangelists ’ whose mission was to create and deliver services that would soften the impact of urban industrial capitalism
on working class women and children. This mission,
carried out by women, was informed both by ideas of
noblesse oblige
and the gendered ethic of care which
132 183
Baines, 39.
184
John Weaver, “The Modern City Realized:
Toronto Civic Affairs, 1880-1915,” in
The Usable Urban Past: Planning and Politics
in the Modern Canadian City
, eds. A. Artibise and G. Stelter (Toronto / O
ttawa: Macmillan / Institute of Canadian Studies,
Carleton University, 1979 ), 65-6. 185
Ibid., 65-6.
186
Canadian Association of Social Workers, “CASW
Represents Canadian Professional Social Workers,”
CASW website
, online
at hypertext transfer protocol : //www.casw-acts.ca/ ( viewed January 14, 2005 ). 187
Baines, 56.
188
Struthers, 48-9.
defined women ’ sulfur sociable function.
183
However, over the first three decades
of the century, social work made a
“ transition from the amateurish vol
unteer guided by moral values … to a civil servant … concerned with
professional standards, advanced tr
aining, and managing agency budgets.”
184
Under the influence of the
chiefly male municipal politics reformers who we
re concerned with efficiency above all, the mentality
of “ sectarian and conversion-oriented social knead ”, with its emphasis on service, gave room to a more “ worldly and ‘ scientific ’ ” practice circumscribed
by legislation and supervised by municipal audit
departments.
185
The growing numbers of social workers were
increasingly professionalized white collar civil
servants, a status which was institutionalized in 1926 by
the formal creation of a national body to regulate
standards of drill in the profession.
186
As Carol Baines argues, this process set up serious tensions
between women social workers ’ caring
and professional / scientific identities.
187
The swerve towards professionalization and bureaucrati
zation accelerated with the onset of the
Depression. Municipal social workers were the front lineage in the mass distribution of stand-in under the 1930 federal Relief Act and its versatile provincial count
erparts, but their very small numbers – between 400 and
500 in all of Canada – quickly created a crisis in their
working conditions. Relief legislation frequently made
no planning for the costs of administering the programmes incurred by cities, and frankincense “ municipalities had no incentive to hire competent personnel or to
develop efficient structures for dispensing relief.”
188
James
Struthers argues that the effects of a lack of degree fahrenheit
ederal or provincial government aid were compounded by
local city councillors ’ electric resistance to increases in proper
ty taxes; many social workers were thus “unable to
133 189
Ibid., 48-9.
190
Ibid., 63-4, 76-7.
191
Baines, 58.
give what they considered adequate relief. ” In other
words, the immediate impact of the Depression was
“ devastating ” for social workers, “ as caseloads doubled and there was no increase in staff. ”
189
such conditions produced two authoritative and in indeed
me ways contradictory trends in this area of
municipal work : demands for more professionally
-trained social workers, well-funded and permanent
municipal social benefit departments, and the rationa
lization of the relief system, on the one hand, and the
radicalization of many social workers on the other.
Struthers shows how some social workers’ response
was to take advantage of their still-small num
bers and possession of highly-demanded expertise to
“ increase their professional condition and influence. ” These
social workers, led by Charlotte Whitton of the
canadian Council on Child Welfare, appealed to gov
ernments’ desire for economy by promoting
professionally-trained social workers as able of
managing relief programmes more efficiently than the
patchwork of second government employees and volunt
eers which filled the gap in most municipalities.
ascribable to their detail professional skill of “ inves
tigative casework”, social workers would be able to
settle who actually needed easing, which Whitton argued
was far less than those on the rolls. They often
made these appeals in alliance with business groups
and academics who were primarily concerned with
the fiscal and moral implications of the easing scandium
heme, namely the waste of taxpayers’ money and the
long-run corrosion of the work ethic.
190
separate of this professionalization process was deoxythymidine monophosphate
he emergence of a clear gender division of labour in
social study agencies. even though there was a desire
to replace traditional “female philanthropists” with
“ new scientific women ”, the reorgani
zation of social work was still premised on women’s role as “social
mothers ” whose natural ability to rear made triiodothyronine
hem “ideally suited to offering direct services.”
191
Such
notions besides legitimized paying women social
workers poorly. Men began to fill “the more elite
134 192
Ibid., 58.
193
Struthers, 51.
194
Ibid., 50.
195
Ibid., 75.
administrative positions ” that were besides more lucrat
ive, and “[s]ocial work, a profession, largely made up of
women, became a profession
under the control of men.”
192
other social workers grew critical of the relie
f system in ways out of step with Whitton’s more
cautious professional converse. These cultivate
ers had the onerous responsibility to implement the
increasingly restrictive rules developed by over-bur
dened municipalities. One of these measures was
designed to prevent “ non-residents ”, that is transient
single men who were travelling the country in search
of work, from getting on city relief rolls, or to cut
them off if they had managed to get on. Such policies
made the practice of social exploit according to public relations
ofessional values as well as the gendered ethic of care
impossible : “ [ a ] south one social proletarian said, ‘ Any humane
treatment of these men … make[s] it impossible to
eliminate their number ’. ”
193
Social workers were thus “day after day in the position of being the only person
to whom … families [ had ] to turn and so far [ were ]
absolutely unable to relieve their anxiety and suffering.”
194
The position of the button-down government,
which aimed at preventing dependency on the state and
preserving the sour ethic quite than providing suffi
cient assistance, “infuriated Canadian social workers”
who “ urged their fellow workers to ‘ take a stand for adequate respite ’. ”
195
It is also possible that the material
consequences of the sex division of parturiency contributed to
a radicalization of women social workers: elite
men were responsible for both the insufficiency of the relief system american samoa well as sociable workers ’ own poor wages. therefore, professionalism and gender identit
y provided the possibility for both opposition to and
recognition with the working classify, depending upon circ
umstances. These contradictory aspects of social
worker consciousness would clash repeatedly through the Depression, and which would take precession remained an outdoors motion .
135 196
Kealey Cummings, interview by author,
17 December, 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
197
Power Workers’ Union, 9.
198
Heron,
The Canadian Labour Movement
, 95.
199
Kealey Cummings, interview by author,
17 December, 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
Another area of populace sector work which continued
to exhibit deep contradictions was that of the
coevals of hydro-electricity in Ontario. As public relations
eviously discussed, the desire to deliver cheap power
combined with HEPC chair Adam Beck ’ s convic
tion that the Commission had the public interest at
heart to produce a series of corporate wellbeing schem
es aimed at tamping down the desire for unionization
at Ontario Hydro. The Commission ’ s most potent cor
porate welfare scheme came in 1935 in the depths of
the Depression. With a severe decay in the demand
for power, the HEPC instituted a series of wage cuts
and massive layoffs between 1930-33. Renewed matter to in and attempts at unionization which were generated by these moves were blocked, however, by deoxythymidine monophosphate
he establishment by the employer of an Employees’
representation design.
196
Like Beck before him, T. Stewart Lyon,
HEPC Chairman in 1934, “felt that a vital
public avail such as the Hydro was an inappropr
iate arena for … labour/industry confrontations.”
197
With
no marriage dues to pay and no unmanageable recognition mint
to fight, the ERP effectively undercut support for
unionization. In the view of some, the ERP was much lik
e the early provincial government employees’
organizations : a form of “ corporate beggary ” in
which the appearance of consultation and negotiations
masked the reality of the em
ployer’s continued dominance.
198
‘Negotiations’ under the Plan involved the
civilized presentation of the Association ’ s “ wish list ”, and the employer would tell them what they could have.
199
On the other side were those HEPC employees
who found this arrangement not only sufficient, but
a more modern, orderly and static method of
governing labour-management relations. This was
particularly true of “ aged employees ”, who were most
likely white collar workers or long-serving blue collar
workers who had much to lose by challenging the condition
quo. In any case, the “tangible results” of the plan
– a Commission-wide subcontract classification and engage security council
heme, and “more than a million dollars annually in
136 200
Power Workers’ Union, 8-9.
201
Lenihan, 168.
engage increases ” between 1936 and 1941 – bolstered hold for the ERP.
200
The combination of the
substantial benefits of the ERP in a context where
few were making gains, and the particular ideological
impulse behind the creation of thyroxine
he HEPC – the notion of serving the public good – had a profound
conservatising impact on the consciousness and organiza
tion of the Commission’s employees, fostering an
attachment to the employer therefore str
ong it was to keep them out of the
bona fide
labour movement for another
20 years. Public employees and their organizations came
out of the Great Depression in some ways
weakened, in some ways radicalized, but undoubtedly tr
ansformed. The depth of the economic crisis had
affected their employers and altered their worki
ng conditions in ways that pushed some to broader
identities and oppositional positions
vis-à-vis management, while others we
re incorporated into managerial
control systems that appeared to satisfy their intere
sts. The Depression also brought into being new
categories of workers who were frequently pulled between
the pride and values associated with professions and
egg white collar work and the growing awareness of a need field-grade officer
r collective action to protect against a rationalizing
and bureaucratizing employer. But these tensions could not be worked out in organizational shape until the fall of favorable conditions for unionization. The second coming of the Second World War brought
new opportunities for organizing public sector
workers. The return of full employment and lambert
abour shortages by 1942 allowed an economy-wide surge in
unionization, in which new groups of public sector wo
rkers participated. These conditions led to a second
organizing wave in the municipal sector, concentrated in easterly Canada.
201
This was reinforced by the
scatter of unionization amongst flannel collar and profe
ssional workers in the general public sector. By
1930, civil servants in the municipal, provincial
and federal governments had gr
own to 108,000, a tenfold
137 202
Graham Lowe,
Women in the Administrative Revoluti
on: The Feminization of Clerical Work
. (Toronto: University of Toronto
press, 1987 ), 31. 203
Michèle Dagenais, “Discipliner les fonctionnaires de l’administration
municipale de Montréal dans
les premières décennies du
XXe siècle : en théorie … et en buttocks
ique,” Canadian Historical Association
Historical Papers
( 1990 ) : 81-83. increase since 1901.
202
Their numbers continued to grow through the Depression and now exploded with
the expansion in express functions during the Second Wo
rld War. Many of these workers now organizing
were quite unlike from those who had organized unions
at the end of the First World War: they included
urban planners, administrators, air combat command
ountants, organizational and managerial s
pecialists, clerical staff, social
workers and day concern workers, all of whom experienced working conditions markedly different from their propertyless counterparts. The last three of these o
ccupations also included many more women. In other
words, the second wave in municipal unionization enc
ompassed a far more diverse workforce, presenting
new challenges in the quest to create a coarse
identity amongst public sector workers.
Why did egg white choker public sector workers turn
to unionism, besides the fact that wartime labour
market conditions made it feasible ? What was happening
in their workplaces to make union representation
seem utilitarian or necessary ? In effect, unionization was a reaction to a longer-term and cardinal transformation in the approach of public officials
to their employees, a process which had begun during and
immediately following the first World War and accelerated in the Second. As Michèle Dagenais argues, the ongoing growth in state functions and hence em
ployees attenuated direct contact between the
employer and employees. In other words, supervisors
could no longer rely on interpersonal relations to
ensure discipline, and fresh managerial methods were requir
ed. The response at all levels of the state was
the standardization and “ objective application ” of
work rules, and the bureaucratization of labour
relations.
203
The application of scientific management tec
hniques in the civil service emerged from the
1920s on as a method to deal with “ the long history
of inefficiency due largely to rampant patronage”, and
138 204
Lowe, 91.
205
Dagenais, 81-83.
206
Lowe, 141pp.
207
Dagenais, 79, 84.
208
Lowe, 144.
209
C. Wright Mills,
White Collar: The American Middle Classes
(New York: Oxford University Press, 1951), 309.
the systematization and standardization of position procedures that resulted caused “ considerable break and discontent. ”
204
In the municipal kingdom, for case, the tr
aditional autonomy enjoyed by white collar workers in
such matters as working time was eroded by the enforcement of uniform codes of behave and highly regimented systems for tracking punctua
lity and the amount of time actually worked. Given workload
increases during both the Depression and wartime, employees were now expected to use exchangeable rules and procedures in the performance of their dut
ies, and were less able to use their discretion or
professional judgment to deal with the specificities of detail cases.
205
Accompanying these changes
was a longer-term action in which clerical exercise
was being transformed from a highly-skilled and well-paid
occupation dominated by men, into routinized,
fragmented and deskilled work performed by poorly paid
women.
206
In all, the conditions of work in muni
cipal offices were undergoing a dual process of
bureaucratization and proletarianization. These changes in the nature of both public sector
work and labour relations were initially welcomed
by some workers, as they were happy to see the end of dim expectations, arbitrary discipline and favoritism.
207
However, the wider application of these
managerial systems was a source of increasing
dissatisfaction amongst white collar workers. even if, as Graham Lowe argues, these changes did not produce “ a mix bulk of unskilled, low-wage tantalum
sks” being performed by “a uniform administrative
lower class ”,
208
the rationalization of the municipal o
ffice and the bureaucratization of labour-management
relations however formed the footing for unionization
in many cities. While elements of the more
conservative and individualist white collar fad
ure that C. Wright Mills described remained,
209
many workers
139 were radicalized and unified by the common loss of
autonomy and thus took advantage of war conditions to
unionize in larger numbers. V.
Conclusion: The Ambivalent Identit
ies of Public Sector Workers
overall, municipal workers were moving towa
rds unionism, separation from the employer, and
broader identification with “ public sector workers ” in the period leading up to the 1950s. The homogenize effects of raw managerial techniques in the face of
larger workforces served to alienate many public
employees from their bosses and to reveal the lim
its to labour-management cooperation. The effects of
war and economic depression besides served to radicalize some workers and provide them with the opportunity to organize jointly. Some workers we
re situated in local labour movements that provided a
potent formative experience based on
the importance of working-class solidarity. Municipal workers who
found themselves excluded from local govern coalitions were more likely to see the union as a social and political movement with a broader setting and purpos
e. Finally, nationalist sentiment and a common
negative experience of the break up
nature of international unionism did produce, in some quarters, the
footing for a more expansive, if canadian, propertyless identity. As we shall see in subsequent chapters, unions most influenced by these processes became more will to centralize resources and develop forms of nat
ional leadership that would be charged with serving
supra-local interests. This process was informed
by a definition of union dem
ocracy that required self-
imposed discipline in the interest of cosmopolitan rather than particularistic concerns. however, these unions would besides come to advocate professionalized and ex-wife
pert forms of leadership which would increasingly
substitute for the conduct action of members and
would foster dependent relationships on national staff.
furthermore, such an approach was to emphasize top-
down processes of unification in which leaders
negotiated amalgamation terms to foster greater working-
class (organizational) unity. In some ways, both
140 democratic participation and accountability were to be in
creasingly constrained by these practices, and they
would come to have at odds implications for how identity and majority rule would be sympathize. however, despite these unite tendencies, there remained powerful centrifugal forces which affected most municipal workers. Given the incredi
ble array of types of work, employers, and managerial
strategies confronting them, it w
ould be unrealistic to expect public sector workers to have easily produced
a discrete and unite identity in the
early part of the twentieth century.
The paternalistic and incorporative
strategies of employers, combined with the specif
ic nature of the work per
formed, presented important
obstacles to class constitution by nurturing the dream
of harmonious and rational labour relations and joint
management of the workplace in the interests of the public. This was particularly true for municipal workers included in local backing networks, who were as a resu
lt more likely to view their union as a source of
material benefits delivered in exchange for commitment.
Such strategies continued to pull people away from
their fellow workers, whether in their immediate wo
rkplaces or in the broader labour market, and towards
the employer. flush where unions had formed, they
often moulded themselves to the locally defined
contours of their workplaces. These sectionalist tendencies, promote encouraged by the continue proliferation of public sector agenc
ies and occupations, were to continue well into the post-war period and
informed a particular agreement of union democracy. such unions were more comfortable within the or
bit of traditional craft unionism, particularly as it
was practised before the growth of centraliz
ed international business unionism. Such locals
emphatic local autonomy and were able to remain autonomous as they did not fall within the legal power of an already-established international. As such
, union democracy was to be increasingly understood as
the serve of particularistic interests and independence from
the control of a central structure. Processes
of fusion continued to emerge amongst these locals
, but were to be achieved on the basis of formal
rather than substantive integrity and would result in an underdeveloped and resource-poor cardinal
141 organization. interestingly, such constraints were
also to lead to a greater emphasis on membership
learning how to fend for themselves, and an understand of the role of union leadership and staff as educative quite than substituting for members. It
is hard to ascertain whether this approach sustained
forms of direct participatory dem
ocracy before the 1950s; however, the
image
of such practices formed the standard against which all future proposed structural changes would be judged. The bowel movement towards unionism consequently did not
lead to a consensus over the role that unions
should play for populace employees, and how it should fulfil
that role. Although workers’ diverse identifications
had begun to and would continue to consolidate organiza
tionally, their many cross-cutting relationships
would survive into the 1950s to form the basis for degree centigrade
onflicts over the questions of union function, structure
and the mean of majority rule. As populace sector oeuvre
ers moved towards the formation of national unions,
these issues would remain the subject of contes
tation both within and between the two new organizations,
the National Union of Public Sector Employees
and the National Union of Public Employees.
142 chapter 4 : The Post-War Emergence of
National Unions in the Public Sector
The trials of war and natural depression led populace sector
workers across Canada to develop different kinds
of organizations reflecting their respective identities.
Some had formed unions on the basis of an expansive
impression of solidarity and common interests, while others remained marry to very specialize definitions of community. Any project seeking to unite these wo
rkers organizationally would have to convince public
sector workers of their shared concerns and of the necrotizing enterocolitis
essity of transcending or transforming the identities
upon which they had based their original unions. Unific
ation would thus require the redefinition of the
boundaries of the democratic community in which legi
timate decisions could be made and of the bonds of
common obligation which held members to each ot
her. New structures capable of democratically
representing and managing particularisms would besides
be needed, a particularly challenging task given how,
in larger organizations, the need for efficiency makes direct and participatory democratic processes unmanageable. The economic, political and legal conditions which followed the second World War provided a lot of the raw material for such a unite projec
t, but were not without contradictory elements.
Transformations within the state, both as employer and as governor of labour-management relations via parturiency jurisprudence, and within the broader parturiency bowel movement worked to create the basis for broader identities and organizational forms, but besides multiplied the obsta
cles to expressing and consolidating them. An
unprecedented economic boom and the hegemonic condition of
Keynesian economic policies ushered in a
retain and dramatic expansion of
the state and thus of the numbers
and types of workers and potential
union members. A post-war compromise between parturiency
and capital emerged in the form of a legal regime
to govern changing labour-management relations. Labour
laws fostered union formation and recognition,
but under particular forms which reinforced the ‘ holiness
of contracts’ and redefined what it meant to be an
‘ effective union ’. These trends worked to both mix and shard, radicalize and bureaucratize, expand and incorporate canadian trade unions .
143 All this had significant effects on the public faction
or union movement, in terms of the workers and
identities contained within it, the functions and lambert
eaders seen as most important and effective, and the
organizational form deemed most allow to deal with
post-war conditions. In this period, there were
coincident pressures towards centralization
and broader organizational forms, on the one hand, and
fragmentation and minute identities on the other. Over
all, public sector unions faced the necessity of
growth and consolidation. State expansion meant it
was more important to organize the growing numbers
and types of workers, adenine well as to bring together
those already unionized. It was hoped that larger unions
would more effectively deal with a municipal stat
e increasingly capable of coordinating efforts and a
provincial department of state get down to centralize certain once municipal functions. however, both expansion and consolidation brought with them serious internal vitamin c
onflicts over how new groups should be incorporated and
accommodated within union structure and identity,
where decision-making power would rest, which
political-ideological orientation to adopt, and which marriage
functions were most important. The questions of
identity and the location of world power in the union were in
tertwined with the issue of function, for different
geomorphologic arrangements were often justified in term
s of the need to be ‘effective’ within the new legal
model for labor relations. These disagreements could be worked out in a number
of ways. The first option was to create a
new identity, which would be imposed from the top
and reinforced through material relations of dependency
on the central position. This alternative would involve southeast
rious battles with representatives of older identities,
who would have to relinquish what organizational power
they possessed. Most often, advocates of a
centralized and professionalized marriage supported this st
rategy, driven by a commitment to place general
interests over particular ones. The second option washington
s to leave the question of a new identity unanswered,
and the necessary battles to create it unfought. Autonom
y for local unions and a loose coordinating role for
144 the central office was a way to defer rather than settl
e these issues. Supporters of this model tended to be
wedded to a decentralized union led by non-expert local leaders and activists. These different approaches to fusion produced comprehensive examination
lex contradictions that highlight how class
formation does not mechanically or unproblemat
ically engender democracy. Top-down integration
processes involved negotiations between leaders and tended to exclude members from all but the formalistic processes of consent. While not democrati
c in a participatory sense, such methods could result
in the more rapid consolidation of broader struct
ures and hence class unity. However, top-down methods
could not guarantee that meaty forms of solidar
ity would result, particularly because unification deals
with other leaderships often came at the price of randomness
pecial exemptions from the broader community’s binding
decision-making power. In such situations, the dem
ocratic values of representation and egalitarianism
were brought into conflict, as some groups worked to
insulate themselves from the demands of a larger
constituency, while others sought to apply the decisions of the organization universally to the entire membership. consolidation processes which emphasized ball over
substantive unity were also contradictory.
While relatively more ‘ democratic ’ in that groups
were not forced to relinquish old identities and found it
easier to join as there was fiddling to give up, a lot
would have to be sacrificed in terms of creating deeper
bonds of solidarity. Though it was hoped that, over
time, members of decentralized structures would
gradually develop a broader awareness, attachm
ent to particularisms around which democratic
expectations had been formed create barriers to this public relations
ocess. Local identities prevented the development
of the very structures which would have forged a
more expansive solidarity. While robust democratic
organizations require both a corporate identity and a shape
al structure to process differences, the historical
processes of union formation amongst public sector workers show just how difficult it is to achieve both simultaneously .
145 populace workers ’ unions were besides faced with significant questions of leadership and its relationship to the members. Which kind of leadership was nece
ssary in these new conditions, with what kinds of
powers and capacities ? What character should the members play in a labor apparent motion facing increasingly complex employers and legal structures ? Struggles wi
thin public sector unions parallelled those in the
labor movement at big and involved a clash betw
een ‘old’ and ‘new’ types of leadership. On one side
were elected activist-organizers who had, through thei
r volunteer or poorly-paid labour, risen up through the
ranks and survived the unmanageable battles associated with
forming and maintaining unions in a hostile legal,
political and economic climate. While this type of leader did not constantly espouse participatory democratic sentiments, and could be psychologically attached to t
heir indispensability to the organization, they often
besides desire workers ’ autonomy in bargaini
ng and union affairs for both ideological and practical
reasons. Gaining ground, however, were the professor
essionalized and appointed ‘expert’ leaders, often from
outside the union, who possessed specialized forms of
training or university education and who supported
centralized forms of administration. Which type of fifty
eader would be established as dominant was a central
conflict in this menstruation, and was resolved differently in the versatile unions. While broader forms of identity,
professionalization of leadership
and legalization of union functions
were all in dominance in this menstruation, the contradict
ions within the context and the variations in the
traditions of populace employee unionism meant
these pressures were expressed and resolved
organizationally in different ways. This chapter thus examines both the nature of the post-war political- economic context and the way populace sector unions devel
oped different notions of their purpose as a result.
I.
The Post-War Context: Stat
e, Law and the Labour Movement
The post-war boom brought with it a lengthiness of
growth and bureaucratization of the state at all
levels, including municipalities. The demobilizati
on of veterans and the subsequent baby boom led to an
146 1
Crean, 41.
2
Crawford, 184-5; Crean, 47.
plosion of demands for housing and residential district services. The Veterans ’ Land Act provided grants to allow working classify families to buy modern homes at low cost, resulting in a build boom in suburban areas and the egress of many newfangled municipalities.
1
A vast expansion in the demand for municipal services
like infrastructure, schools, hospitals, libraries, recr
eation facilities, and police and fire services, not to
mention the necessitate for urban plan, clerical, and admin
istrative staff, rapidly drove up the numbers of
likely public employee union members. many municipalities dealt with these increas
ed burdens and the enlarged staff they entailed
through far systematization of
labour-management relations. Typifying these schemes were job
evaluation and categorization processes to standar
dize wage rates and merit systems which would
‘ objectively ’ determine eligibility for promotion.
2
As we saw in Chapter 3, such developments often signalled
the growing distance between employer and employees
, often ‘radicalizing’ workers and leading them to
seek unions to represent them in these comple
x and increasingly alienated labour-management relations.
however, these arrangements besides
required that union leaders develop ce
rtain kinds of expertness, and thus were a source of specialization and bureaucratization within municipal unions. At the lapp time, public employees were affect
ed by an important redist
ribution of the duties of
versatile levels of government. The convergence of Ke
ynesian economic policies, pressure from the labour
movement and overburden municipalities led the federal and provincial
governments to centralize many
functions associated with social social welfare which had
previously fallen under municipal responsibility. As
Warren Magnussen describes, the higher levels of gover
nment took charge of “[
uranium ] nemployment indemnity, old-age pensions, and hospital insurance and the former
r federally sponsored welfare programs [which]
relieved the municipalities of most of their responsib
ilities for relief.” Concretely, this meant a renewed focus
on urban infrastructure, particularly in light of triiodothyronine
he many necessary improvements deferred during the
147 3
Magnusson, 25.
4
Ibid., 28.
Depression and Second World War, and the rapid
pace of urbanization and suburbanization which was
now taking position.
3
Therefore, those municipal locals most associated with urban growth, namely the
external city workers, were entrenched in their sectionalism and
ties to municipal elites as their material welfare
continued to be determined at the local level.
However, other functions which remained formally
autonomous and local, like hospitals and schools, were increasingly governed by central bureaucracies at the peasant level, a contradi
ctory development which produced a seri
es of centralizing pressures on
workers forming unions in these sectors. The highly disconnected municipal structure, on
the other hand, placed a brake on centralizing
trends in public sector unions. Municipalities continued to live with the legacies of the first gear wave of municipal reform, which had produced a overplus of
apolitical, arms-length commissions to administer
assorted municipal services. The anti-partisan tip
ling which still pervaded munici
pal politics meant there
were no institutions to provide political
unity amongst the “independent and semi-independent … school
boards, public utilities commissions, transit authorities, caparison corporations, parks and library boards, and police commissions. ”
4
Apart from its deleterious effect on lo
cal government, this fragmentation imprinted
itself on the evolving public worker unions, many of whom thoughtlessly adopted this social organization and made it the basis of their self-definition. As a result, molarity
any communities now possessed separate locals for inside
and outside city employees, public utility program perpetration and
public transportation workers, police officers and
firefighters, librarians and school janitors. public workers ’ self-definitions and
solidarities continued to be
shaped by the constrict contours of their employers. Public employee unionism was besides shaped by l
abour law. On the basis of the unprecedented and
destabilizing mobilization of proletarian
s in the wartime strike wave, the Canadian federal state was forced to
ordain legislation that would go beyond the IDIA and more
effectively regulate the conflict between capital
148 5
Laurel Sefton MacDowell, “The Formation of the Canadi
an Industrial Relations System During World War Two,”
Labour/Le
Travailleur
3 (Spring 1977): 179.
6
Fudge and Tucker, 273-4.
7
Wells, 209-212.
8
Frankel and Pratt, 2-3.
and labor. In particular, though the IDIA made the carbon
onciliation process compulsory, it was not mandatory
for the employer to accept a board ’ s decisiveness. In many cases, IDIA boards remained merely advisory, and in instances where the employer refused to recogni
ze and bargain with the union at all, were completely
unable to resolve labour-management disputes.
5
The labour movement’s growing discontent with labour
legislation not premised on the authenticity of unions fo
rced the federal government to shift course. In 1944,
Order-in-Council P.C. 1003 established
the right of workers to be represented by bodies of their own
choose and the duty of employers to recognize and bargain with those repres
entatives. Though initially
applicable lone to “ federal and war-related industries ”, provin
ces could opt in as they did with the IDIA. After
the war and an extended struggle by the labor movem
ent, these tenets were made the core of both
federal and provincial parturiency laws.
6
As well, the Rand Formula, the
arbitrated resolution of the 1945 strike
by autoworkers at Ford ’ sulfur Windsor plant, establis
hed the automatic dues check-off and the closed shop, in
which all workers had to pay dues to the union whether or not they were members.
7
However, such rules
placid did not apply to federal and peasant civil servants. The detail legal regimen adopted had several import
ant effects for public sector unionism. First,
this order-in-council mean that municipal workers,
who fell under private sector legislation in most
provinces, could retain their organizations even t
hough the labour market conditions under which they had
initially formed had dissipated. This more supportive lambert
egislation permitted public sector unions to establish
themselves on a more solid foot and prosecute triiodothyronine
he further development of their own organizations,
something which was missing in the period after the beginning World War.
8
However, these organizations would
have to cope with the increasingly complex legal rules which now enveloped certificate, collective
149 9
MacDowell, 191. Fudge and Tucker indicate that the Ontario Colle
ctive Bargaining Act resulted in 64 certifications of “employ
ee
committees ”, half of which were actually caller unions
and therefore trumping “some of
the strongest statutory language
outlawing employer hindrance
with unions” (Fudge and Tucker, 272).
10
Palmer, 280; Fudge and Tucker, 274.
11
Power Workers’ Union, 10.
12
Ibid.
dicker and dispute resolution. As such, many pub
lic sector locals began to feel the need for forms of
expertness which they themselves did not possess
and could not afford to procure on their own.
second, and ascribable to pressure from the broader labor campaign, employer-dependent proletarian representation schemes like the Ontario Hydro ERP
were forced to become formally independent entities in
arrange to gain legal recognition as bargaining agents.
In order to appease employers, the 1943 Ontario
collective Bargaining Act did not make company
unions unambiguously illegal, but rather allowed non-
union bodies to be certified as collective dicker agents “ if they were reasonably mugwump. ”
9
PC
1003 went further and did outlaw company unions, but di
d not stipulate that workers had to be represented
by unions, only that they had the right to be represented.
10
Between 1944 and 1948, however, continued
labor mobilization led the entrenchm
ent of these wartime measures
at both the federal and provincial
levels, and a further specification of the character of ‘ bona fide ’ worker representation. In Ontario, the 1947 Labour Relations Act went further than its 1943 vers
ion, and stipulated that “[t]o be entitled to legal
recognition as a union, an organization had to be financially independent of management. ”
11
These legal changes forced the Ontario Hydro Em
ployee Representation Plan to transform itself
into an independent example of workers, therefore
becoming the Ontario Hydro Employees’ Association
( OHEA ) in 1944. Given that “ the basic features of
a union structure were already in place”, gaining legal
recognition would merely require technical c
hanges: a self-made and approved constitution and dues paid
by the members.
12
The law therefore opened the door to
unionism and pushed Ontario Hydro workers
through it, a feat not potential through more traditional
means. In all other respects, however, the OHEA
anticipated remaining the same, particularly in its relationship to management. The OHEA ’ randomness origins as a
150 13
Ibid., 10-11.
14
Heron,
The Canadian Labour Movement
, 65. The CCL was formed by a merger of those organizing informally under the CIO
streamer and the affiliates of the canadian nationalist
union central, The All-Canadian Congress of Labour.
15
Power Workers’ Union, 14.
16
Kealey Cummings, interview by author,
17 December, 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
animal of the employer had long-la
sting effects on the consciousness and politics of the local’s leaders
and members. For case, the OHEA ’ s first presiden
t, Gordon Abbott, believed that “all differences could
be resolved through discussion and compromise. ” OHEA representatives continued to be influenced by the management ’ s vision of the Hydro ’ s stat
us as a “great instrument of public service”, due to which “much of
the differentiation between Managem
ent and Employee Representatives [lost] significance.”
13
This continued resistance to the estimate of unionism can besides be seen in the OHEA ’ sulfur pitched opposition to the IBEW ’ second repeated
organizing drives between 1944 and 1956.
Over this period, the OHEA
was highly loath to join the firm of labor, ev
en as a measure to fend off raids by the IBEW. In
February 1950, for example, the Association attempted to
resolve the raiding problem by affiliating with the
canadian Congress of Labour, since 1940 the union centrum
l assembling those committed to the industrial
coupling in Canada.
14
The membership rejected this option “by a good majority.”
15
This repudiation of any
dealings with the mainstream of the labor drift washington
s led by those who felt “their relationship with the
boss was fine ”, and that they did not need to belong to
a union, a position seen to be especially true of the
white collar workers in the head office.
16
In other words, financial independence did not automatically result
in psychological independence from management, or in
an adoption of a union identity, and in many ways
the OHEA continued to be a company union in spirit, if not in name. The new legal government had the foster effect of
creating a single-employ
er single-establishment
model of authentication which served to institutionaliz
e and freeze locals into small, fragmented units. The
emerging consensus amongst labor relations boards
now empowered to certify legal bargaining agents
was to define bargaining units according a preferably sodium
rrow understanding of “community of interest” which
151 17
Judy Fudge, “The Gendered Dimensions
of Labour Law: Why Women Need In
clusive Unionism and Broader-based
Bargaining ” in
Women Challenging Unions: Femi
nism, Democracy, and Militancy,
eds. L. Briskin and P. McDermott (Toronto:
University of Toronto, 1993 ), 234-5. 18
Frankel and Pratt, 7, 24, 28.
19
Crean, 44.
much took for granted the “ employer ’ sulfur initia
l decision about how to organize” the workplace.
17
Given the
highly disconnected structure of the
municipal state, many public
employee locals had narrow boundaries
that instilled and reproduced very
limited bonds of solidarity.
finally, provincial variations in the application
of labour law to municipal and public employees, a
site entrenched by the Judicial Committ
ee of the Privy Council’s 1925 decision in the
Snider
case,
affected the consolidation of unions in this sector.
While most provincial labour relations acts included
municipal workers under the lapp provisions as privat
e sector employees without caveat, in two provinces,
Ontario and New Brunswick, municipal governments were
given the discretionary power to decide whether
they would submit to the Act and permit corporate bargai
ning. While these opt-out clauses did not formally
prevent unionization, they did allow for anti-union molarity
unicipal councils to refuse any dealings with union
representatives and discriminate agains
t those who engaged in union activity.
18
This refusal to grant union
recognition could besides be used selectively, depending upon thyroxine
he relative power of the local in question: for
case, the Township of North York had bargaining relations with its external workers in local 94, but had refused to bargain with the female-dominated Local 373 until 1953.
19
The impact of this practice was in
some cases to keep groups operating as associations ra
ther than unions, but in other instances it was the
source of big dissatisfaction and gr
owing militancy. Moreover, these laws also signalled in a concrete
room that the origins of and the remedies to
public employee problems were not purely local.
Another herculean influence on the evolution of
public sector unionism was the increasing
bureaucratization of the Canadian labour movement moment
re generally. Although certainly full of important
variations, the overall tendency in the british labour party movem
ent in this period was to reshape union activities
152 20
Heron,
The Canadian Labour Movement,
79-80.
21
Wells, 196.
22
Heron,
The Canadian Labour Movement
, 80.
towards “ negotiating and administering contracts ” and
away from “mobilizing masses of men and women.”
20
At the local anesthetic level, the acceptance of an “ orderly,
rule-bound regime based on contract with grievance and
arbitration procedures ” substituted for “ actor milit
ancy” and direct action, changing the kinds of union
leaders that would be required.
21
Both individual parent unions and labour federations significantly
expanded their full-time staff in the areas of education
and research, so as to provide technical support for
corporate bargain and other engagements
with the new labour law apparatus.
22
This change in the
conventional wisdom about which union functions we
re most important now
promoted the expert labour
professional as central to labour ’ sulfur build up. In
such a context, nascent public employee organizations,
already looked upon suspiciously by their private sector
counterpart as latecomers to the struggle, could
not help but see professionalization of their activiti
es as a means to being taken seriously in the labour
movement. Public proletarian organizations thus faced a common
and contradictory set of challenges in the post-
war period. The general course was towards consolidation of broader identitie
s and professionalization of
union functions. however, countervailing pressures
existed which worked against these dominant trends,
and interacted with the particularities of union cultur
es and traditions. We now turn to those organizations
to see how they coped with these issues. II.
From CETU to NUPSE: The Dream of Expansion
Those who had already developed broader organizations after the beginning World War were further expanding their setting at the end of the Second. In
1944, the surviving members of the CETU, along with
smaller numbers of municipal workers like the Ham
ilton Civic Employees Union, had recognized their
153 23
NUPSE, “Constitution and By-Laws”, October 1959: 18. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5, File 4]
24
NOCUEW Constitution, 1945: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG I234, Vol. 5, File 4]
25
Irving Abella,
Nationalism, Communism, and Canadian Labour
(Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1995), 214.
common interests and banded together in a reconceived union, the National Organization of Civic, Utility and electric Workers ( NOCUEW ). This new union was
based explicitly on the principles of industrial
unionism and welcomed all classes of workers.
23
NOCUEW’s objective was “to unite all workers employed
by the municipalities, public and puerto rico
ivate utilities, and in the electrical industry”, an expansionist commitment
indicated by the inclusion body of civic workers in the coupling ’ s very name.
24
Indeed, the desire for expansion and
a authentically national union in the public sector was the
primary preoccupation of the union in this period.
What was driving this bay for a national marriage ? No doubt, the estimate of a common industrial identity, which had long been a potent copper
rrent in the CETU, was at play here. NOCUEW continued in this
commitment via their affiliation to the Canadian Congr
ess of Labour in 1947, which put it amongst some of
the most active, quickly expanding and brawny labour
organizations of the period. However, various
hardheaded concerns were equally potent. CETU
’s and NOCUEW’s membership in the CCL brought with
it authoritative pressures to create
a union in the public sector which would effectively compete with and
finally displace those affiliated to the Trades and Labour Congress. even though the CCL had always pursued closer ties, cooperation and joint action wisconsin
th the TLC, overtures which had been consistently
rebuffed by the latter,
25
there was no doubt that the CCL leader
ship believed the industrial union model
would well serve the interests of canadian proletarian
s. CETU’s limited concentration on public utilities
therefore had to be superceded in order to attract
new members. Expansion, its limits and its ensuing
conflicts were central problems faced by NOCUEW in this menstruation. NOCUEW ’ south ambitions were greater than its alternating current
hievements, however, and the organization was
unable to attract members in the numbers t
hat had been hoped. Between 1945 and 1952, the issue of
expansion was constantly on the agenda at executive
meetings, but the discussions were centred on
154 26
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, June 18, 1950: 4;
October 15, 1950; December 3, 1950; February 23, 1952. All
CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 2 ] 27
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, December 3, 1950: 1.
28
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, October 15,
1950; February 11, 1956; CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol. 6, File 4 ] ; September 9-10, 1960. CUPE Fonds
[NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 6]
29
Little quoted in Thomas, 63. NOCUEW’s 15 locals in 1952 were
: Local 1 Toronto Hydro, Local
2 Toronto Transit Commission
electricians, local 3 Sault St Marie Public Utilities Commissi
on and civic, Local 4 London civic,
Local 5 Hamilton civic, Local
6
Sudbury Civic, Local 7 Guelph civil, local 8 York Township Hydr
o, Local 9 Kingston civic, Local
10 Timmins public works, Local
11 North York Hydro, Local 12 Chatham curie
vic, Local 13 Chatham water works, Local 14 Forest Hill / Strathroy Hydro, and Local
15 Brockville civil. potential members rather than ac
tual organizing victories. An
organizing drive begun in 1950 amongst
Ottawa civic and hydro workers produced nothing despi
te staffer Lionel Gladu’s reports of “making good
advance ” after two years of attempt.
26
Talk of using activists from Locals 4 and 5 to draw TLC-affiliated civic
employees in London and Hamilton into the Union fluorine
aded by the end of 1950 as NOCUEW could not find
any organizers interest in the task.
27
The idea of having the civic workers’ unions in Winnipeg and
Montreal function as regional offices of NOCUEW washington
s but a distant hope only to be realized in the late
1950s.
28
As a result of this accumulation of false st
arts, the Union had organized or attracted only 15 locals
between 1944 and 1951.
29
There were growing worries inside and outside the Union that NOCUEW was
permanently stalled. What explains this failure to expand, given the
fairly ripe conditions for unionization and the support
of the CCL ? The leadership had a litany of explanations
for NOCUEW’s difficulties, discussed at length in a
December 1950 Executive Board suffer. In particular,
T.F. “Stevie” Stevenson, business agent of Toronto
Hydro Local 1, NOCUEW Secretar
y and Toronto-area servicing repr
esentative, was the person most creditworthy for servicing and organizing and therefore was front and center in attempts to justify NOCUEW ’ s disappointing results frankincense far. The rela
tively high per capita levied by NOCUEW made it much
less “ competitive ” in comparison with directly c
hartered TLC locals: while the TLC charged 10 cents to
affiliate, NOCUEW charged 75 cents, having barely increas
ed its per capita by 50% at the 1950 Convention.
ironically, this relatively high gear per caput was itself
partly generated by the failure to expand, for this union
155 30
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, December 27, 1950: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 2];
Barnetson, 1965 : 5. Barnetson reports that he resigned as President of Local 1 in 1947, when he was appointed to the Personnel Department of Toronto Hydro at
the request of the union to carry out the
design of a new job classification scheme
( Barnetson, 5 ; Ashworth, 205 ). According to NOCUEW docum
ents, however, that he continued on as President of NOCUEW
until 1950, when he was replaced at the 1950 convention by James
Clark. It seems that for 3 years, NOCUEW was led by a
member of management. One wonders at the
implications of this for the union’s dev
elopment in the period. On the question of
organizing, given that, by this clock, attempts to raid TLC
locals in London and Hamilton had already commenced to no avail, the
trouble was not merely one of will or
an overly burdensome sense of ethics.
31
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, December 27, 1950: 1.
32
Henry Rhodes was the CCL’s main organizer in Ontario in
this period (Abella, 1973: 96). Rhodes conducted an investigation
for the CCL to determine the nature of local anesthetic 7 ’ mho grievances
and what if anything could be done to keep them within NOCUEW.
After meeting with the local, Rhodes determined that Stevenson wa
s the problem, and that the local would go to the TLC unless
( continued … ) with a little number of locals felt it had to fund organizing efforts from the centre. The Union ’ s miss of emergence besides had to do with the ‘ saturation ’ of thei
r still narrowly defined jurisdiction. Stevenson argued that
the Union had organized about every group of municipal
and public utility workers in Ontario cities larger
than 15,000 people. At this point ( in 1950 ), Stev
enson contended, “the only field left open to extend our
membership in the Province was in raiding triiodothyronine
he Trades and Labour Congress of Canada affiliates.” For
Stevenson himself, this site would have constitu
ted no barrier; rather, it was Albert M. Barnetson,
president of both the Toronto Hy
dro local since 1923 and of NOCUEW from its inception, who did not
consider it “ good ethics ” to raid the TLC. With
Barnetson replaced by James Clark at the 1950 Convention
in Hamilton, “ the straight-jacket was nowadays off ” and the Union would attempt to attract the already- organized.
30
The inability to expand was besides fuelled by growing
internal dissatisfaction. Several of the union’s
locals had begun complaining to the CCL of poor people service over the by two years.
31
Unlike Local 1, most
NOCUEW affiliates did not have their own business
agents and were serviced directly by the national
union. With the head office in Toronto, and the majori
ty of locals clustered in Southern Ontario, such
servicing was promptly provided. however, triiodothyronine
he CCL had been hearing complaints from the London local
since 1948, and had received at the end of 1950 an applicat
ion for direct affiliation from NOCUEW Local 7,
representing civil workers in Guelph.
32
This news arrived on the heels of the Sudbury local’s expression of
156 ( … continued ) the CCL offered them a send charter, which they did in early 1951 ( H. Rhodes, “ Report
on Meeting with Guelph Branch of
NOCUEW ”, January 3, 1951 : 4 ; NOCUEW, National Executive B
oard minutes, January 26, 1951:
1-2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc.
MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 2 ] ). 33
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, October 15, 1950.
34
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, December 27, 1950: 1.
35
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minut
es, December 3, 1950: 1; Thomas, 63.
a desire to leave NOCUEW due to the CCL ’ mho ejection of
the International Union of Mine Mill and Smelter
Workers.
33
In 1951, the two Chatham-area locals also attempted to decertify. These internal problems were
obviously turning off likely members a well, w
ho were wary “due to stories they had heard about the
administration of [ the union ’ s ] affairs. ”
34
These inner conflicts partially concerned the major difficulties faced in expansion, namely the symmetry of might between old and new groups in the union, and the challenge that fresh groups posed to established identities. Despite the gestures to a red brigades
oader scope, CETU’s originating local continued to play
a identify function : not alone did Local 1 call the meet to
form NOCUEW, it also provided the union’s top two
officers for about a ten, with Barnetson as Pr
esident, and Stevenson as Secretary. The historical
meaning of this local was not lost on its own
representatives. Stevenson was happy to remind others
that the germinal function of local 1 in the constitution
of CETU gave it both a special responsibility and a moral
stature to which other locals should aspire.
35
This sense of importance and the way it informed the actions
of the union ’ s early leaders was not constantly fruitful in
building an inclusive organization, and fostered the
conflict between the original and new locals, which happened to be coincident with divisions between the central and local administrations. This clash was besides expressed in terms of who in the union should have the exponent to decide what kind of information would be given to the penis
ship. In 1949, for instance, Stevenson ignored the
decisions of both the National Executive and the 1948
National Convention and wrote directly to local
branches in an undertake to receive a mandate from deoxythymidine monophosphate
hem to increase his salary. Leaders of the Guelph and
157 36
H. Rhodes, “Report on Meeting with Guelph Branch of NOCUEW”, January 3, 1951: 2.
37
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, December 27, 1950: 1.
38
NOCUEW, National Executive Boar
d minutes, December 3, 1950: 1-2.
London locals, both of whom sat on the National Ex
ecutive which had denied the increase, objected
strenuously to this tactic and refused to read the request to
their respective memberships. In this they were
supported by then-President Barnetson, whose interpre
tation of the powers of lo
cal presidents – that they
could select which communications were read to the
membership – was at complete odds with that of
Stevenson.
36
Stevenson persisted in communicating directly wi
th the locals, leading to, in his words, “a
despiteful campaign against the Secretary. ”
37
The CCL and local NOCUEW representatives absolved
ly believed the Union’s stagnation was due to
problems with leadership, namely Stevenson
himself, who had been Secretary-Treasurer,
de facto
union
organizer, servicing congressman and negotiator of
collective agreements for the better part of a decade.
As the only full-time elected officeholder, he in effect func
tioned as chief administrator of the organization with all
the smell of expertness and see that implies. Hi
s stamp on the early recor
ded history of the Union is
undeniable. As Secretary, Stevenson
routinely depicted himself in a most favourable light in the debates at
the National Executive Board ; indeed,
few others appear to have spoken if his minutes are to be believed.
constantly in high dudgeon, Stevenson frequently and paternalistically dressed down others who were in his view insufficiently aware of how the Union did
and should operate. Two colourful episodes stand out. In
one, a dispute with local 8 over the amount which
should be paid to fulfill a special assessment to help
Hamilton Local 5 after their 39-day hit for the 40-
hour work week in 1950, Stevenson implied that the
York Township local did not understand they we
re part of a national union, bound by the National
Convention ’ sulfur decisions, and that they were unwilling to
help Hamilton members in their time of distress.
38
In
158 39
H. Rhodes, “Report on Meeting with Guelph Branch of NOCUEW”, January 3, 1951: 2.
40
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, December 27, 1950: 2.
41
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, December 3, 1950: 2.
42
H. Rhodes, “Report on Meeting with Guelph Branch of NOCUEW”, January 3, 1951: 4.
another, in response to a section of Guelph Local 7 ‘s willingness to accept an 8-cent quite than 10-cent engage increase, Stevenson called them as a “ bunch of
hicks” who did not know what they were doing.
39
Underneath the veneer of self-promotion found
in the minutes, however, one detects undeniable
and growing dissatisfaction with Stevenson ’ mho leadership st
yle. In dispute was not the appropriate functions
to be carried out by the cardinal office, but rather thyroxine
he type and style of leader who was carrying them out. It
was Stevenson ’ s sense of omniscience and his preference for unilateral military action and direct appeals to members over the heads of local leaders that had led
directly to the Guelph local’s exit from the
administration. Questions were besides being asked about Stevenson ’ randomness ability as an organizer and negotiator, not about whether the central function should be in
volved in local affairs. NOCUEW had been unable to
procure agreements for the locals in Kingston, Bellev
ille and Cornwall, with the Town Council of Belleville
refusing to deal with Stevenson as negotiator. Stevenson was unwilling to sign “ poor people ” agreements “ to satisfy a cheap group of Politicians in any Municipality. ”
40
Even when put in diplomatic terms by York
Township Local 8, who “ believed a certain total of
difficulty could be overcome [in Toronto] … if a part-
time Representative was engaged to relieve the Secretar
y of some of his duties, in order that the
membership … could get more service ”, Stevenson r
eplied that the Toronto membership should grow up
and take province for their own negotiations and objec
ted to the decision to employ President Clark as
the part-time rep.
41
Dispatched by the CCL to investigate
the claims of the Guelph local and assess
whether to grant them a target rent, Rhodes ’
conclusion in January 1951 was clear: “there was no real
grievance against the National Organization of Civic,
Utility and Electrical Workers, but rather, their
grudge was directed entir
ely at Brother Stevenson.”
42
159 43
Mills,
The New Men of Power
, 100, 105.
44
Ibid., 97.
While these conflicts appear on the surface to be
personal in nature, they reflect the growing
consensus that a fresh type of leadership was required if
the union’s central office was to carry out its duties
effectively. The kinds of leaders which emerged
out of the CETU era, represented by Stevenson in
particular, were there from the beginning, had ri
sen up through the ranks and had endured struggles for
union survival. They had developed a smell of indispensability, accustomed to being decision-makers and to the condition that accompanied t
heir long tenure in the movement.
43
Others, however, were beginning to
advocate a ‘ new ’ and more professional kind of leadership armed with cognition and a facility for persuasion, based on what was emerging in the rest
of the labour movement and especially in the CIO /
CCL unions.
44
As in all unions, it took a fight to determi
ne which style would prevail in NOCUEW. In the
end, a consensus emerged around what were seen as
the “practical needs” of the organization and what
was required to meet them : the superintendent
session of the old model of leadership.
The publish came to a capitulum in 1950. With new members uninterested and existing members dysphoric, something had to be done. At a meeting held
at the end of the year,
CCL Secretary-Treasurer
Pat Conroy and organizer Henry Rhodes were expressi
ng concern that NOCUEW was not fulfilling its role
and was losing the field to the TLC. The failure to expand in Ontario was a likely threat to the growth of a truly national union for municipal
employees within the CCL. If NOCUEW couldn’t
draw in and keep new members in their home province, how could they hope to draw in groups from Quebec or the Prairies ? As a solution of these concerns, Conroy and
Rhodes recommended to the December 1950 Executive
meeting that a full-time Organizing Director be appointed, with the CCL to foot the bill. This decision led to an important shift in NOCUEW, both in terms of drawing card
ship and of organizational success. Specifically, it
precipitated the passing of Stevenson, who clearly sa
w this new staff position as a threat to his own
160 45
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, December 27, 1950: 4.
46
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, January 28, 1951: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 2]
47
H. Rhodes, “Report on Meeting with Guelph Branch of NOCUEW”, January 3, 1951: 3.
48
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, January 28, 1951: 3.
49
NOCUEW, National Executive Board minutes, May 5, 1951: 1; J
une 3, 1951. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File
2 ] centrality in the administration, as indeed it was. He dec
lared to the National Executive that, if they were to
harmonize to the CCL ’ second marriage proposal, “ they must first underst
and this so-called Director was not going to be in
charge of the Secretary-Treasurer in his office ; if that was sol … [ he ] would resign immediately. ”
45
Despite this
menace, in January 1951 the Executive Board accepted t
he CCL’s offer subject to their approval of the
campaigner to become Director of Organization.
46
In the six months that followed the meet with Conroy and Rhodes, the Executive believed they faced a choi
ce between the growth of the union and the personal
ambitions of Stevenson. While many local leaders, most notably those from London and Guelph, had agreed deoxyadenosine monophosphate early as 1949 that Stevenson had to be remo
ved, such a move was postponed as there was no
suitable refilling for him at the clock.
47
Moreover, his continued presence, the cause of so much turmoil,
deterred anyone from stepping up to ta
ke on this important position.
48
The Executive Board opted to wait
for Stevenson to hang himself. After intentionally faili
ng to inform a new executive member of the May
1951 meet, Stevenson was instructed by the Executive to apologize. This ‘ Stevie ’ would not do : he insisted that he would not work with James Walke
r, the representative from
London Local 4, and that the
executive choose between the two men. W
hen the Executive again demanded an apology, Stevenson
resigned, and his subsequent attempts to call an hand brake conventionality to consider the battle were rejected.
49
At this moment, a new type of leadership eclips
ed the old. With the creation of the appointed and
functionally differentiated place of Director of Organization, NOCUEW had
clearly stepped onto the road
of professionalization and bureaucratization of leadership.
In the moment, this move made sense in terms
of the motivation to decrease the excessive and irrational prisoner of war
er of a particular individual, and to give specific
161 50
D. Downey, “CUPE Boss Tripled Union’s Membership: Foundi
ng President Took His Workers ‘From an Era of Collective
Begging to Collective Bargaining ’ ”
Globe and Mail
, 19 May 2000: R6; Committee for Stanley
Little, “ Think Big, Vote Little ”, tract, 1967. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46, File 11 ]. Interestingly, the NEB minutes are far less detail after short became Secretary, an east
ation to be adopted by CUPE after 1967.
51
The Public Employee
9 (3), Fall 1988: 4; NUPSE, “Consti
tution and By-Laws”, October 1959: 18.
52
Little quoted in Thomas, 63.
attention to organizing. indeed, this variety did us
her in a period of aggressive and relatively more
successful expansion. Although the leadership struggle was about more deoxythymidine monophosphate
han changing personnel, this factor also turned
out to be very authoritative. The passing of Stevens
on opened up the space for another strong personality to
imprint himself on the organization. Stan Little had been a fabric worker blacklisted for leading a strike in 1931. In 1941, he became a member of Local 8, Yo
rk Township Hydro, and was elected as NOCUEW’s
Secretary-Treasurer at thyroxine
he September 1951 Convention.
50
A mere two months after his election, Little was
named Director of Organization and besides took on the function
of Acting Secretary for another two years. Now in
charge of NOCUEW ’ s organizing direction, Little placed ex
pansion at the centre of the union’s activities.
little set immediately to work on further expandi
ng the union’s self-definition and organizing scope.
In September 1952, less than a year after his
appointment, NOCUEW metamorphosed into the National
Union of Public Service Employees ( NUPSE ) at a “ establish convention ” attended by civic employees and hydro workers from Toronto, Sudbury,
London, Sault Ste Marie and St Catharines.
51
In an interview years
later, Little said they changed the name because “ NOCUEW was a pain to say. ”
52
However, the new name
besides signalled an even broader invention of the coupling ’ s ju
risdiction: now, they would aim to organize all
workers in the public service, an border on which pushed past industrial to general unionism. NUPSE would more actively pursue municipal, hospital
and board of education workers, and workers beyond the
Ontario molding, diluting reasonably the control condition held historically by electrical utility workers and generating some serious home conflicts This expansion of
scope would also eventually bring the union into direct
162 53
Ibid.
54
MacDonald, a member of the United Minewor
kers of America, became Secretary-Tr
easurer of the CCL (and later the merged
CLC ) after Conroy ’ sulfur resignation in 1951 ( Abella, 203, 208 ). 55
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes
, September 11, 1952. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 2]
56
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, November 1, 1952. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 2]
57
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, December 6, 1952. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 2]
conflict with the early unions in the field, namely its soon-to-be counterpart in the TLC, the National Union of Public Employees. however, Little besides faced the CCL ’ s contradictory access to the question of public employee organizing. Although in 1950 the CCL had been implemental
creating the ‘right’ internal conditions for
expansion and the amalgamation of assorted components into a national coupling in the jurisdiction, their side on who precisely would organize the populace sector
was not clearly formulated at this point. In 1953,
the CCL clearly had a “ union broadcast ” to conso
lidate its public sector affiliates into a national
organization which would initially include unions from Ontario, Saskatchewan and Manitoba.
53
However,
despite the name switch and newly personnel, doubts lingered about NUPSE ’ s ability to live up to expectations. CCL officials continually delayed determining which union would be chosen to do the unionize, and between 1952 and 1955 refused to expand NUPSE ’ s legal power beyond Ontario. In late 1952, Donald McDonald
54
of the CCL indicated to Little that the
union’s attempt to organize workers in Fort
San, Saskatchewan was beyond their jurisdiction.
55
This seemed in direct contradiction with the pressure
received from Conroy and Rhodes good two years earlier
to get the Union in a position to organize outside of
Ontario. As a solution, NUPSE was forced to make a form
al application to the CCL to clarify its jurisdiction.
56
Six months passed with fiddling progress, despite a
CCL committee set up to review organizing in the public
sector.
57
By April of 1953, and perhaps tired of waiti
ng, NUPSE applied for a transfer of all directly
163 58
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, April 11, 1953. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 2]
59
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, June 9, 1953. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 2]
60
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, May 8, 1954. CU
PE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 3]
61
Frankel and Pratt, 3; Pringle, 57.
62
The Vancouver Civic Employees Union,
formerly Local 28 of the TLC, approached NUPSE in April of 1955 interested in
affiliation. however, both NUPSE and the CCL were extremely washington
ry of taking this group in, as
they had been expelled from the
tender loving care in 1950 for having come under the “ Communist determine ” of
the Labour Progressive Party ( R. Rintoul, letter to NUPE
Executive Board members, Secretaries of
Local Unions and Provinci
al Organizations, November
26, 1956: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 3 ] ). small believed that t
he union was “basically sound” save for one staffer “obviously using
his
military position to promote Communist party petty officer
litics.” Evidently, however, Little was
more concerned with numbers than ideology, and
he likely believed that these elements could be controlled
or eliminated once inside NUPSE. The CCL, on the other hand,
seemed less uncoerced to put ideology aside for the sake of num
bers: though Joe MacKenzie (later the CLC’s Director of
organization ) argued that NUPSE could not enter
tain the VCEU’s application to affiliate since its jurisdiction was confined to
lake ontario, it is probable that this was an excuse to keep the B.
C. Communists out (NUPSE, National
Executive Board minutes, June 5,
1955 : 2. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 3 ] ). In any case, the VCEU did not affiliate with NUPSE at this tim
e,
and only reentered CUPE in the later 1960s as local 1004. 63
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, December 5, 1955. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 3]
chartered public employee groups in the CCL.
58
Again, the Union was put off with the prospect of a
conference on a national union for public employees
to be held in Winnipeg in June of that year.
59
The Winnipeg Conference led to the formation of
a Public Service Organizing Committee (PSOC),
modelled on the CIO/CCL twin body organizing st
eelworkers, the Steelworkers Organizing Committee
( SWOC ) so successful in the 1940s. It was hoped
that PSOC would bring about the national union so
many desired ; indeed, NUPSE ’ mho per capita tax increas
e at its September 1954 convention was explicitly
tied to the need to support this committee and realize the union of public employees groups.
60
The
PSOC brought NUPSE, and Little in particular as the Union ’ s
representative, into direct contact with several
early groups later authoritative in the Union ’ s expans
ion, namely the Winnipeg Civic Federation which had
south korean won documentation for all of Winnipeg ’ s municipal employees in 1949.
61
The Union ’ s higher profile outside of Ontario besides attracted interest from curie
vic workers in Montreal and Vancouver.
62
However, the PSOC does
not seem to have produced much in the way of newfangled or
ganizing; rather, it seemed to function as a meeting
place for already existing unions in the lapp jurisdiction. furthermore, it seems to have collapsed by the end of 1955 with Winnipeg workers leaving in frustration
and instead considering a direct affiliation to NUPSE
itself.
63
164 64
This local has over the years undergone seve
ral transformations reflected most obviously in its name, which can lead to some
total of confusion. between 1935 and 1944, the workers were
members of the Hydro Electr
ic Power Commission Employees
representation design ( HEPC ERP ). After 1944 and until 1956, they
were the independent Ontario Hydro Employees Association
( OHEA ). With the entrance into NUPSE and the bona fide deal union
movement, the Association changed its name to the Ontario
Hydro Employees Union ( OHEU ), by which it was known until 1963.
With the formation of CUPE in 1963, the union came to be
known as local 1000, until 1996 when, under the leadership of
John Murphy, the name Power Workers’ Union was adopted.
( continued … ) Given the difficulties faced in organizing new wo
rkers, Little embarked on a new strategy which
was to alter NUPSE ’ s character and inner dynamics. Rather than focus on organizing the unorganized, little turned his attention to courting big and already organized groups of public sector workers who had, until nowadays, remained outside of the mainstream of
the Canadian labour movement. It was believed that
such a scheme would result in a rapid and relatively low-cost increase in NUPSE ’ mho membership, power and status. however, the techniques required no longer
placed emphasis on convincing each member to join
the union and adopt its identity as their own ; quite,
assimilation of already-existing groups meant direct
negotiations and deal-making with leaders. not only were these talks typically outside of the membership ’ sulfur examination, they besides involved particular kinds of comprehensive examination
romises which usually involved retention of the group’s
autonomy, distinct identity and model
of unionism, and financial resources. While such arrangements were
intended as transitional measures to meet the pragm
atic goal of expansion, individuals easily remained or
became invested in the power these structures prov
ided them. However, with these implications
unforseen, NUPSE initiated this newly approach to gr
owth by turning to a much sought-after group
historically aloof to the labor movemen
t: the Ontario Hydro Employees Association.
III.
Courting the OHEU: Autonomy comes to NUPSE
NUPSE ’ second expansion into early public sector workplaces between 1952 and 1956 did attenuate slightly the office of members from the hydro southeast
ctor. However, these developments could not hope to
counter the determine that would be exercised by what
would become NUPSE’s largest affiliate, the Ontario
Hydro Employees Association.
64
The entry of OHEA into NUPSE in 1956 reinforced the union’s orientation
165 ( … continued ) Changes in the union ’ s mention reflect authoritative
shifts in identity and self-definition, as well as their connection to other levels of
CUPE and the canadian tug bowel movement. 65
Power Workers’ Union, 15.
66
OHEU, Coordinating Committee minutes, J
anuary 30-31, 1958: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 11]
to electric utility workers, but besides introduced
a powerful and vehement advocate of local autonomy into
NUPSE ’ s midst. As a holocene history produced by the lo
cal points out, “[f]or several years, there were more
members in the Ontario Hydro Employees Union deoxythymidine monophosphate
han in the rest of NUPSE, making OHEU a dominant
power. ”
65
Despite sharing an identity as hydro workers wi
th many NUPSE members, employees of Ontario
Hydro cling to autonomy, not least because of their committedness to a more conciliatory approach to union- management relations. In other words, OHEA was cutting
to maintain a distinct structure and identity in
NUPSE ’ s midst because of their different ideas about unions ’ allow functions. The importance of OHEA to NUPSE ’ s organizational health frankincense made the symmetry between autonomy and central restraint a key issue facing the union. Though the majority of OHEA ’ s membership was message with a formally freelancer organization that put rational number cooperation with management firs
t, there were forces which eventually pushed the
Association into the orbit of NUPSE and the labor missouri
vement. Despite the overwhelming votes to remain
out of the IBEW and the CCL, there was constantly a
substantial minority – about a quarter – of the
membership who were pro-union. Their presenc
e, combined with heightened membership expectations
emerging from the contest
with the IBEW, forced the OHEA to behave in ‘unionate’ ways and to
prove they were not a ‘ party union ’. T
hese union-like activities entailed more aggressive
negotiating positions, demands for the close shop, and the expansion of staff, including a full-time organizer. furthermore, these members argued that
there was an “increasing need … to share interests
and responsibilities with early organized labor groups. ”
66
These trends were reinforced by the changing
attitude of management towards the EA, which c
ould be seen as early as 1945, when the company
166 67
Power Workers’ Union, 11-3.
68
OHEU, Coordinating Committee
minutes, January 30-31, 1958: 2.
69
John Williams,
The Story of Unions in Canada
(Toronto: J.M. Dent and Sons, Ltd., 1975), 192.
70
C. Jodoin, letter to S. Little, May 2, 1963: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 12]
suddenly stopped deducting Association dues after three months of having done so. The Hydro ’ south discomfort with an independent administration continued to grow, and in 1951, the HEPC management signed a collective agreement with several trades unions
in Niagara, and even provided time off to sign up
members, in an undertake to divide the work force in
to different – and hopefully less effective – unions.
These moves resulted in the OHEA ’ s successful fight
for the union shop, but also led to a disenchantment
with management amongst the EA ’ s members and a recognition that the support of the labor bowel movement might be increasingly necessary.
67
ultimately, however, the most convincing arkansas
gument for the OHEA joining NUPSE centred around
the hope to save on the costs of defending agains
t repeated raiding attempts by the IBEW while
preserving their autonomy and particular
approach to labour-management relations.
68
With the merger of
the TLC and CCL approaching by 1954-55, the question
of affiliation to the broader labour movement
became more urge, and the desire to be covered
under the ‘no-raiding’ pact which was signed the two
federations ’ Unity Committee in 1954 propelled the
OHEA executive to revisit their options in 1954.
69
however, direct affiliation to the CCL, which
had been contemplated and rejected in 1950, was no longer
available. indeed, the CCL leadership explicitly deni
ed direct affiliation to OHEA to help NUPSE, as CLC
president of the united states Claude Jodoin pointed out in a communication wisconsin
th the latter: “It was the pressure exerted upon
them by officials of the CCL and that torso ’ s absolute
refusal to accept them as a separate affiliate (to
protect your jurisdictional rights )
that forced them to join NUPSE.”
70
OHEA therefore had to look to an
already-affiliated coupling to join .
167 71
Power Workers’ Union, 14.
72
OHEU, Coordinating Committee
minutes, January 30-31, 1958: 2.
73
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, April 27, 1957: 3. CUPE
Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 4]. I have not
been able to determine if there was any real number terror by the CL
C leadership to unilaterally di
sband NUPSE; however, Little clearl
y
believed such an inevitability was in the offing if he did not takes steps to prevent it. NUPSE was a logical choice for OHEA, given the
large number of municipal hydro locals already
present there.
71
Indeed, OHEA felt a “common bond” based on their status as “employees of public
administrations ” angstrom well as members of
industrial rather than craft organizations.
72
NUPSE also made
sense as a little union desperate for members and therefore
more likely to negotiate a merger agreement to
get OHEA in at closely any cost. While NUPSE ’ s ost
ensible motivation for pursuing OHEA was “to better
coordinate our efforts to increase the benefit of
municipal Hydro and utility employees”, its immediate
concern was preventing its eliminati
on from the new CLC. With the CLC merger, there were now three
other unions competing for members with NUPSE – the
smallest and most vulnerable of the four to being
disbanded. As was distinctly recognized by Little at
the time, the “proposed disposal [of NUPSE] was
stopped alone because the employees of the Ontario Hydro
decided in sufficient time prior to the Congress
amalgamation to identify themselves with our union. ”
73
In other words, NUPSE was fighting for its life. OHEA
leaders were well mindful that, in these conditions, they
could get themselves a significant amount of space
inside NUPSE, particularly given their proportional size.
They believed they could get the protection of CCL
membership without having to comp
romise their own brand of unionism.
The terms on which OHEA joined NUPSE, subsequently the capable of much remark and controversy, reflected just how search after thes
e workers were. OHEA clearly had the upper hand in this
amalgamation, since with approximately 10,000 members,
OHEA would triple NUPSE’s membership overnight
and arguably boost its ability to attract new members. The Memorandum of Understanding reached between NUPSE and OHEA was “ singular in canadian labor hello
story”, according to the local’s own account
forty years later .
168 74
Power Workers’ Union, 15.
75
The Council of Chief Stewards was originally the Committ
ee of Employee Representatives
and functioned as part of the
advisory process under the Empl
oyee Representation Plan. When t
he OHEA became an independent union, they
maintained this representative structure.
The Council consists of representatives el
ected for four-year terms from the various
regions where Ontario Hydro workers are
employed, and meets every fall to elect t
he union executive and set union policies. It
is
the Council of Chief Stewards which leads the local to claim it
is “one of the most democratic unions in North America” (Power
Workers ’ Union, 32 ). 76
Power Workers’ Union, 15, 13.
77
C. Jodoin, letter to S. Little, May 2, 1963: 1.
78
J.R. Walker, “Report of Meeting on Jurisdiction and Unit
y between OHEU and NUPSE”, April 20, 1959: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 3 ] ; OHEU,
Coordinating Committee minut
es, January 30-31, 1958: 2.
The Association was to enjoy entire autonomy to conduct
its own affairs without any interference from NUPSE.
It would service its own members, not call on NU
PSE resources at all, and would not be bound by any
decisions made by the NUPSE Executiv
e Board or Conventions, on any matter. The ten cents monthly per
head paid to NUPSE would go wholly to pay the
CCL’s per capita, making NUPSE little more than an
amateur collection means for the CCL
.
74
In a realization of their ‘ new ’ condition and identit
y upon joining NUPSE, however, the OHEA did change its
appoint to the Ontario Hydro Employees ’ Union ( OHEU ). interestingly, however, this highly fa
vourable deal, though recommended in 1955 by OHEA’s
“ fantan ”, the Counc
il of Chief Stewards,
75
was approved only by a narrow margin in December of that
year. This ambivalent result spoke to the cont
inuing and deep divisions that remained within the Hydro
membership over identity and what kind of unionism they desired. These forces had opposed the home changes which threatened what some hush viewed as
their “generally amicable relationship with the
Commission. ”
76
Joining NUPSE and the CCL would only furt
her exacerbate the “decline” in labour-
management cooperation, and many were not lament. J
odoin reminded Little years later that “[t]he Ontario
Hydro Employees ’ Union wanted protection from raiding a
ll right, but they were anything but anxious to join
NUPSE to get it. ”
77
Many within the OHEU called this “labour blackmail”, and even the leadership wanted
not to merge, but to move “ only far enough in to get the IBEW off [ their ] backs. ”
78
The presence of anti-
union forces resentful of being pushed into organiz
ed labour created an ever-present threat of OHEU
leaving NUPSE, which subsequently cast a shadow
over the organization and was to have a profound
169 79
OHEU, Executive Board, November 8, 1957: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 8]
influence on the amalgamation terms belated negotiated with NU
PE. A condition of NUPSE’s own survival was that
OHEU would constantly have to be satisfied and kept in the union at all costs. But this section of anti-union membership would al
so prove useful to the OHEU leadership as a
breakwater against full integration into the NUPSE stru
cture and a means to preserve the scope of their
control. In November 1957, the OHEU membership ’ sulfur “ miss of awareness ” of the benefits of belonging to a larger union structure was offered as
justification for not moving closer
to NUPSE over the biennial period of their agreement of Understanding.
79
While the ostensible reason given for the lack of “educational work”
was the necessitate to fight off the Hydro Commission ’ s c
hallenge of OHEU’s bargaining rights through 1956, it
was besides the “ democratic restraint ” of the membersh
ip which prevented full integration, a restraint that
OHEU leaders were not in a rush to dismantle. however, the inner geomorphologic changes made by NUPSE as a circumstance of OHEU ’ south entrance into the union muddied the rendition that a amalgamation had not
taken place. The Executive Board was expanded
significantly and the now three Vice-Presidents eac
h headed the three newly created Divisional Advisory
Boards set up for members in the hydro-utility, megabyte
unicipal, and hospital and school board sectors. In other
words, NUPSE was moving towards sectoral structures
which were intended to “deal with servicing and
organizational problems ” of these groups of proletarian
s and which reflected the basis of OHEU’s strong
identity. however, NUPSE besides plac
ed important limitations
on the extent to which OHEU could participate
in the broader coupling ’ s decision-making bodies, indeed as
to prevent their overwhelming the union via their
superior numbers. representation to convention washington
s calculated on a different basis, and OHEU members
could alone be eligible for top administrator positions a
fter serving for two years as a member-at-large on the
executive board. While the latter restrictions were seen by OHEU as evidence that they had affiliated
170 80
OHEU, Coordinating Committee
minutes, January 30-31, 1958: 3-4.
81
Lenihan, 168, 175.
“ under terms that did not subordinate [ them ] to the
NUPSE Constitution”, the natur
e of the representational
relationships indicated that they were now region of a ‘ parent body ’.
80
little ’ second scheme to expand the coupling via the relati
vely centralist means of merger negotiations with
already established organizations therefore resulted in
some important decentralizing trends. Though the
agreement with OHEU was a leadership affair, the
process introduced into NUPSE’s midst a group with a
preexistent identity and smell of what a union shoul
d do, and thus a force for autonomy from the National
agency and Convention. The pressures inside OHEU
against full integration into NUPSE would haunt the
marriage well into the future, and threaten to undo what one had already been constructed. The equivocal nature of the Memorandum of Underst
anding would fuel the debates over whether OHEU was actually part
of NUPSE, and rate an important obstacle in the way
of future expansion, namely with its soon-to-be
counterpart in the TLC, NUPE. IV.
Locals Create a National Union: NUPE’s Municipal Unions and Local Autonomy
If expansion was the major preoccupation of NU
PSE and its predecessors, then consolidation of
the boastfully archipelago of already-existing public em
ployee unions haunted those in the TLC. In many
respects, expansion was not a real problem for the TLC,
for many locals in municipalities, school boards,
hospitals and even universities continued to form on deoxythymidine monophosphate
heir own and directly affiliate to the craft-union
federation. The real challenge was how to get thes
e locals together. While there had been idle talk about
the idea since the 1940s, “ identical little had been done to bring it into being. ”
81
Such discussions took place in
the context of mighty centrifugal forces. There were a number of strong pressures that kept the TLC-chartered locals apart. First was the power of geography : locals were spread from coast to
coast across a large array of municipalities, and
171 82
N.A. (Rintoul / NUPE Merger Committee), “Statement
on Merger of NUPE and NUPSE by the National Union of Public
Employees ”, May 12, 1961 : 2. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 27 ] 83
N.A. (Rintoul / NUPE Merger Committee), “Statement on
Merger of NUPE and NUPSE by the National Union of Public
Employees ”, May 12, 1961 : 2. 84
Gregor Murray, “Steeling for Change: Organization and
Organizing in Two USWA Districts in Canada,” in
Organizing to Win:
New Research on Union Strategies
, eds. K. Bronfenbrenner, et.al. (Ithaca, NY
/ London: Cornell University Press, 1998), 323.
could often not afford to attend the conventions where they could meet and discuss their common difficulties and interests. Added to this was the longs
tanding nature of many of
the locals and the tradition
of autonomy and autonomy they had developed. In
particular, the larger and older locals formed
sui
generis
in the crucible of the First World War mainta
ined autonomy as their central organizational principle,
a commitment which held a set of carry. furthermore, as
directly chartered members of the TLC, municipal
locals had paid a very low per caput – between 5
and 10 cents per month – and had received “very limited
direction, servicing, or aid from the TLC. ”
82
To fill this gap, many locals had elected or hired full-
time business agents, who themselves felt a sense of
ownership over their locals’ affairs, having become
accustomed to complete autonomy “ equally far as poli
cy, contract settlements, negotiations etc.” were
concerned.
83
Such a staffing arrangement was typical of uni
ons in the craft tradition, preferred because it
tied such employees to the local anesthetic union, making them
“directly accountable to it, and more often than not,
driven by its political imperatives and electoral timetables. ”
84
Therefore, conflicting forces existed within
these locals : though sometimes led by individuals
committed to building a national organization, others
continued to nurture a desire for local anesthetic autonomy. besides contributing to a reluctance to create larger
structures was a lack of self-confidence. Pat
Lenihan, business agent of the Calgary municipal Local 37
and long-time socialist activist in the West, was
cardinal in pushing for a national organization within the
TLC, and felt that other workers’ reticence was the
product of their diffidence. He described one of the first base m
eetings to form a National Federation in this way:
We were all, in the independent, strangers to each other.
We had a lot of discussion about forming some kind of
arrangement. It was pro and memorize for awhile [ sic ]. Some
thought that we couldn’t handle it, that we were better
off the way we were with the Congress. All kinds
of backward thinking. Nobody was satisfied with the
172 85
Lenihan, 170.
86
Ibid., 170-1.
87
NUPE Educational Services, “The Origin
and Growth of the National Union of P
ublic Employees”, October 1958: 1. CUPE
Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 10 ] service or assistant they were getting from the C
ongress, but yet they didn’t have enough confidence in
themselves and their capabilities.
85
The approach of the TLC to the question of a national
union in the public sector was also a factor in
delaying its emergence. They seemed in no finical hur
ry to form such an organization, and in this their
position diverged from that of the CCL and hence
removed an external source of pressure for
consolidation. In fact, the TLC leadership had to
be convinced over a number of years that a national
public sector coupling was viable in the 1950s.
86
far reinforcing local attachment and concenter was the nature of the legal
regime that governed
municipal work in particular, and certificate in general. municipal workers fell under the legal power of provincial tug relations acts, which varied subst
antially. The law was therefore simultaneously unifying
and break up of municipal workers ’ organizations. Wh
ile provincial labour laws meant that “cooperation
on a provincial … basis was debauched becoming a necessity for public employees ”,
87
variations in these laws
fostered fragmentation along regional lines. Insofar as
broader forms of solidarity were in the offing, they
were foremost at the provincial level. While an impor
tant step in creating the basis for even wider forms of
designation, the construction of
provincial-level organizations set up centres of power and alternative
bases of identity and common interests which woul
d compete with any national union for members’
commitment. Another potential stumble block to one was thyroxine
he wide variety of leadership styles and ideological
positions present within the municipal unions. Some
, like Lenihan, were committed to the dream of a “One
Big Union ” for Canadian public employees due to their socialistic ideological commitment to working class
173 88
Lenihan had been involved in a number of socialist and radical
organizations located in the West, including the Communist
Party of Canada and organizations of the
unemployed during the Great
Depression, and had been interned for this activity.
89
Lenihan, 164, 173-4; Gilbert Levine, Interview by author, 16 December 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
90
Lenihan, 175.
91
Babcock, 13.
one.
88
Others’ motivations were less lofty: Bob Rintoul,
for instance, was seen to be attracted to the status
and career possibilities that a position in a national
union would offer. President of his Calgary transit
workers ’ local, the Calgary Federation of Ci
vic employees and the local Labour Council, Rintoul’s
commitment to the labor motion was par
t of his search for a “better job.”
89
Still others, like Garnet
Shier, drawing card of the Toronto City Hall workers ’ uni
on, Bill Buss, an employee of East York Township, and
Bill Black, business agent and organizer for the british
Columbia Hospital Workers’ Union, sought unity
amongst populace employees out of a combination of
principled commitment to solidarity and a pragmatic
desire to form an constitution that could help t
hem be more effective in collective bargaining.
90
Given these
divers orientations, one might expect more overt
conflict between these leaders. However, they were
unified in their desire for consolidation, whatever t
he reason, and as such set the tone for dealing with this
process : defer the working out of substantial diffe
rences until after the formal organization was created.
This approach besides made feel in the context of thymine
he TLC’s tradition of apoliticism, a Gomperist policy
which aimed precisely at avoiding partisan
divisions within workers’ organizations.
91
What besides united this diverse group of people
and local unions was a common understanding of the
basic function they wanted carried out by a national
organization, namely servicing and coordination. While
some had a more expansive view of unionism, it was the desire to do something about the “ minimal measure of serve and aid ” from the TLC around which people coalesced. The motivation for a home structure which could provide this service brought the drawing card
s of municipal and hospital workers together in 1948.
A small informal meet between Shier, Black and Al
Brunton of Calgary City Hall Local 8 at the TLC
convention in Calgary that class explored the possi
bility of some kind of structure amongst the civic
174 92
Lenihan, 170.
93
NUPE Educational Services, “The Origin
and Growth of the National Union of Public Employees”, October 1958: 1. The BC
Joint Council of Public Employees, belated to
become CUPE BC, was formed in 1943 (Lenihan, 175).
94
Lenihan, 170. The Alberta Joint Council of
Public Employees, later to become CUPE
Alberta, was formed in 1949-50; its first
meet was held in the Calgary Labour Temple with del
egates sitting around a tub full
of beer (Lenihan, 1998: 166).
95
Ibid., 175.
employees unions.
92
These three agreed that while a national union within the TLC was the ultimate goal,
at this consequence focus should remain on building the provin
cial level structures already in existence, like the
british Columbia and Ontario Federations of Public Employees.
93
Since these bodies were already up and
running, they could begin the provide the serv
icing and coordination functions immediately.
obviously, the decision to work at the peasant lupus erythematosus
vel was effective: by the time these locals met
again in Montreal in 1949, Saskatchewan and Alberta
had also established Federations of Public
Employees.
94
These bodies had taken on responsibility for servicing, organizing and educational work in
their respective provinces, and were supported by
grants from the TLC. The early development of a
provincial structure and identity amongst public sector
workers was to form the basis for the NUPE (and
later CUPE ) structure. Lenihan saw these provinci
al organizations as central in developing support
amongst autonomous locals for a national arrangement :
their work “indicated to our members the great
value of cardinal bodies and the military service that could be given to local unions. They paved the room for the setting up of the national consistency. ”
95
however, provincial federations besides
had a contradictory effect: by taking
on these functions, the need for – or at least the function
of – a national-level organization was diminished.
They besides established the basis for identities and intere
sts attached to sub-national structures that could
finally contest the home marriage ’ s clai
m to decision-making control and legitimacy.
In any character, a home union was still a few y
ears away, primarily due to the TLC leadership’s
assessment of the express of populace employee unionism.
The coalition of public employee groups moved to
the following phase by appointing a probationary Organizing
Committee at the 1951 TLC Convention in Halifax.
175 96
In addition to Shier, the Provisional Or
ganizing Committee consisted of Bill Black of
Local 180, Al Brunton of Local 8, and Pe
te
Lake and Jack Leam of Local 38. local 37 was not represent
ed at the 1951 TLC Convention, but was being spoken for by
Brunton ( Lenihan, 170 ). 97
NUPE Educational Services, “The Origin
and Growth of the National Union of Public Employees”, October 1958: 1; Lenihan
1999 : 170. 98
Lenihan, 168-69.
99
Ibid., 170-171;
The Public Employee
9 (3), Fall 1988: 3; NUPE Educational Serv
ices, “The Origin and Growth of the National
Union of Public Employees ”, October 1958 : 2. The Committee was led by Shier and charged to approach the TLC for a National Union charter.
96
They
were turned down, with the TLC ’ s judgment that
the time was not yet ripe for a national union.
97
No explicit
reason for this defense is to be found ; however, Lenihan ’
s allusions to the prevalent perception amongst the
dominant secret sector unions that civic employee organizations were not “ substantial ” unions, and therefore treated as “ second-class citizens ” or “ step-children ”, offer a possible explanation.
98
not to be deterred, the locals called a confer
ence of all TLC public employee unions at the 1952
convention in Winnipeg to see whether the proletarian
s and leaders thought the time was ripe for a national
union. With over 50 local representatives now calling for a federation of public employees, the TLC was less able to deny some form of national administration.
Lenihan’s connections with TLC Secretary-Treasurer
Gordon Cushing, with whom he had worked closely in
Calgary and helped to elect as city alderman, also
greased the wheels. The TLC ’ s former decisiveness was thus reversed and a charter for the canadian federation of Civic Employees ( CFCE ) was granted. Th
is charter bestowed the right to charge per capita,
which was set at 5 cents, and to hold conventions, but
not to issue charters to locals: this power, and the
responsibility for servicing, remained with the TLC.
The TLC officers agreed to a national organization of
public employees, but only if 17,000 members could be s
hown to support the initiative. In the meantime,
the CFCE was a idle federation which left the autonomy of
the locals almost entirely intact. There would
be a bunch of work to do to gather the want back for a actual national union, peculiarly amongst those like the BC Hospital Workers, who already possessed
a provincial structure and who, at this point, were
“ not prepared to go along. ”
99
176 100
Lenihan, 172.
For two years the CFCE functioned under these terms, with Shier as President, Lenihan as First Vice-President and Aubrey Dixon of the City of Regina
inside workers Local 7 as Secretary-Treasurer. The
fact that each of the executives was working in comprehensive examination
letely different parts of the country may have seemed
an hindrance, but the national coverage afforded by
the CFCE’s diffuse nature was an asset given the
undertaking of reaching as many TLC locals as possible ,. The Federation ’ s chief drive was “ to try and coordinate and to get in touch with as many civic locals as possible throughout Canada, and encourage them. ” This they did themselves on a next-to-volunteer basis, “ working about day and night at it ”, and through the TLC ’ s field representatives. For the first clock
, locals exchanged collective agreements and were able to
compare wages and working conditions in the sector. Visiting those locals who had been absent from the TLC conventions and convincing them to affiliate to
the CFCE was a particular priority. Evidently, the
CFCE activists were successful : by the end of
1953 the Federation had affiliates representing 12,000
members.
100
continue progress, however, relied upon the CFCE bei
ng able to perform functions useful to local
unions. Without the ability to organize and charter modern locals, to service members and support them in negotiations, to compile, analyze and make meaningful
the information now being shared amongst locals, a
national structure ’ second entreaty would remain limited.
The CFCE’s September 1954 Convention thus decided to
push ahead and form a National Union, presenting the TLC administrator with a plan for finance and operation based on a 20-cent per caput. A refe
rendum amongst the TLC locals in November 1954
indicated that 70 % of civil unions
representing about 17,000 members were in favour. Seven years after
the idea of a national organization was initially rais
ed at the 1948 Convention, the CFCE was thus awarded
its National Charter by the TLC in May of 1955,
changing its name to the National Union of Public
Employees ( NUPE ) at its founding convention in Winds
or, Ontario. The 1954 vote amongst TLC-chartered
177 101
Ibid., 172-3, 175.
102
Kealey Cummings, interview by author,
17 December, 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
103
Lenihan, 183.
locals to form NUPE brought closely 60 locals into the fresh union, with a membership triple that of NUPSE ’ second at the time. Its numerous and more regionally r
epresentative membership made NUPE a more genuinely
“ national ” union in some respects : locals spanned the
country from British Columbia to the Maritimes, and
typify workers in many more sectors. In thyroxine
he seven months that followed, the membership expanded
to 23,000 in 110 locals, as more directly chartered TLC unions began to join. Garnet Shier from Toronto local 79 was elected as president of the united states and Robert Rintoul
from Calgary Local 37 was appointed as the full-time
National Director to run the newly
set-up National Office in Ottawa.
101
Reaction amongst the NUPSE adherents to the form
ation of NUPE was less than keen. Some
charged that NUPE was “ hurriedly slapped t
ogether” by the TLC at this time.
102
No doubt a significant shift
amongst the TLC leadership had taken place, as they
were now anticipating the creation of a merged
canadian Labour Congress in a mere two years and watt
anted to create a national public employee union in
the TLC custom to compete with NUPSE. Giv
en this and NUPE’s recent appearance on the scene, one
could see why Little and other NUPSE activists were
sceptical of the neophyte organization, having
preceded it by over ten-spot years. however, not alone was NUPE many years in the maki
ng, the product of much activity not visible to
NUPSE leaders, it was besides relatively successful
in NUPSE’s own terms. NUPE continued to grow by
leaps and bounds in a way that NUPSE just had no
t. By the end of 1956, the union had over 30,000
members to NUPSE ’ s 15,000, despite NUPSE ’ randomness holocene skill of the OHEU.
103
One wonders if there
was not a bite of dark grapes here amongst NU
PSE leaders, especially since NUPE’s organizational
structure and leadership dash flew in the front of metric ton
he emerging conventional wisdom about the requisites for
successful unionism. little clearly believed that a c
entralized, professional leadership was necessary for
178 104
MacMillan, 141.
marriage expansion and collective bargain effectiveness,
and NUPE’s successful use of activist-organizers,
working on an about tennessean footing, challenged this
belief. NUPE’s relative popularity and its incredible
growth rate demonstrated that it was possible for
a union to do much with very limited and decentralized
resources, tied in the era of a
professionalizing labour movement.
There are respective significant reasons why NUPE was
relatively successful in this period, and all of
them related to the leadership ’ s prioritization of courtly ( if not substantial ) consolidation ahead of any desires for centralization, conformity or profe
ssionalization of leadership. NUPE left locals’ autonomy
virtually intact, and focussed on voluntary cooperation preferably than the imposition of criterion approaches. affiliation to intermediate bodies like provincial divi
sions and district councils remained purely voluntary,
although many organizers vigorously encouraged the locals they organized to join.
104
Similarly, per capita
was left very low, making NUPE relatively easy to join,
permitting locals to retain control over their financial
resources, and ensuring that the national leadership had
little material power over locals to enforce a
central line on bargaining or political questions. As
a result, NUPE’s membership expanded significantly
without an overarching set of goals, besides
the desire for mutual self-protection.
NUPE ’ s approach to staffing and its function in relation
to the membership also revealed different ideas
about the national union ’ second appropriate serve. Fo
r quite some time, the number of full-time and
professional leaders was kept to a minimum, and the
union relied heavily on part-time officials and activist-
organizers. This was of course related to the lim
its on national revenues, but also to the philosophy of
some of NUPE ’ s leaders, namely Lenihan, who replac
ed an ailing Shier as National President in early
1956. In Lenihan ’ mho position, the locals and members shoul
d be taught to use the strength which came from
their immediately larger numbers. In his first conventi
on speech as National President, Lenihan acknowledged the
increasingly complicated nature of unions ’ functions, but
insisted that the goal was to “find the means of
179 105
Lenihan, 181-3.
106
Ibid., 178, 181-184; R. Rintoul, letter to Secretaries of all
Chartered Locals, “Was It A G
ood Union Meeting” questionnaire,
November 17, 1955. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 2 ]. 107
NUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 22-23, 1958: 5.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 6]
raising the department of education level ” of NUPE members rather
than substituting experts on their behalf. While many
locals themselves clamoured for aid from the Nati
onal Office in the form of national representatives,
the leadership prioritized the technical side of
Research Director over servicing, which Lenihan
envisioned as a support for local bargain efforts.
105
Even when three national representatives – Jim
murray in BC, Bill Acton in Ontario, and John ‘ Lofty ’ MacMillan in the Maritimes – were hired in early 1957, the vehemence remained on supplementing quite than r
eplacing local leaders’ knowledge. Where it was
apparent that members did not have the cognition
and experience to be effective bargainers and local
leaders, home representatives were to provide bot
h technical and political education, particularly on how
to run a “ good ” meeting and absorb in effect
ive and democratic collective leadership.
106
The national
representative ’ s conduct function in local affairs was thus
envisioned as temporary. The supplementary status of
staff was far reflected in the union ’ s prohibiti
on against staff’s participation as voting delegates in
convention and the political process more broadly.
107
ultimately, locals and individuals were afforded a signifi
cant amount of political space in the tradition of
pragmatic sanction non-partisanship associated bot
h with the TLC and with the civil service, and as such allowed for
the concerted coexistence of everyone from So
cial Credit adherents like Bob Rintoul to Communist
organizers interned during the second World War like Pat Lenihan. As a TLC coupling, NUPE fell formally within the eye socket of american english trade unionism. The implicat
ions of this affiliation are rather more complex than
one would expect through a superficial glance at Gomperism and commercial enterprise unionism, however. NUPE did mirror the TLC ’ s commitment to pragmatic non-par
tisanship; indeed, the 1956 NUPE Convention adopted
resolution 15, submitted by the Alberta Federation of Public Employees ( Alberta Division ), which committed NUPE to “ a not enthusiast attitude on Polic
ies regarding politics” and to have “no future
180 108
NUPE, 1956 Convention Proceedings:
19. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 2, File 7]
109
R. Rintoul, letter to NUPE Executive Board members, Secret
aries of Local Unions and Prov
incial Organizations, November
26, 1956 : 1, 2. 110
NUPE, 1961 Convention Proceedings:
112. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 2, File 11]
111
The Public Employee
9 (3), Fall 1988: 3,5; Crean, 53.
relationship with any Political party. ”
108
Moreover, there was no shortage of
anti-communist sentiment in the
union, as the discussion of Local 28, Vancouver ( later to become CUPE Local 1004 ) reveals. As Rintoul explained in a circular to provincial and local drawing card
s, in 1950, before the form
ation of NUPE, the 66th
annual convention of the TLC expelled local 28, the V
ancouver Civic Employees Federal Union, due to its
having come under “ communist determine ” of penis
s of the Labour Progressive Party, like Jack Phillips,
the local ’ s business agent. The TLC subsequently set
up Local 407 as an anti-communist alternative for
Vancouver municipal workers – which became an affilia
te of NUPE – “for the purpose of giving a haven to
those who desired to protect their penis
ship with the Trades and Labor Congress.”
109
Local 28 remained
a submit of business and discussion within NUPE, and as the debate at the 1961 convention shows, NUPE members wanted local 28 to return to the fold, but not
so long as they would continue to allow themselves
to be “ dominated by communists. ”
110
An examen of the people involved in NUPE at
the local and national levels, however, reveals
that there was some space for person socialists
and communists to gain leadership positions in NUPE
and to coexist with those who did not contribution their views. Pat Lenihan, the national president of NUPE from January 1956 to March 1957, and subsequently a field
representative in Alberta, and Western Regional
Director for CUPE until 1969, was a member of the Indus
trial Workers of the World, a supporter of the One
Big Union, and a Communist Party member in the 1930s.
111
Lenihan reports that there was a mutual
esteem amongst people of different ideological or
ientations. With a few notable anti-communist
exceptions, there was credence of Communists so
long as they were “good trade unionists.” Lenihan
said : “ I mean, they weren ’ thymine real progressive thinly
kers but they were broadminded liberals. Although they
181 112
Lenihan, 176.
113
Crean, 53.
114
Palmer, 169.
115
Lenihan, 177, 182.
had hunches, possibly, that I was a Communist, they di
dn’t let it bother them. If what I was saying made
sense, they supported me. ”
112
Gil Levine, Director of Resear
ch for both NUPE and CUPE until the mid-
1980s, was besides a member of the CPC / Labour Progressi
ve Party in his university days, which he admitted
to the NUPE hire committee when they interviewed him in 1956.
113
Bryan Palmer echoes this more
nuanced assessment of the possibilities in TLC craft
unions: “craft unionism was never some monolithic
structural process of captivity, in which work
ers were only stifled and moved in the directions that
business unionism allowed. Members of these skill
ed bodies of working men played a fundamental role in
socialist reform politics and battled at the workplace,
where they confronted a determined resistance to any
notion of unionism. ”
114
Therefore, while a strain of anti-communi
sm certainly existed in NUPE, the value of
effective and militant trade unionism was
often placed above questions of ideology.
NUPE ’ s particular way of managing differences in
order to create a national organization also had
its drawbacks, however. The diarrhea of its cent
ral direction made it appear less coherent than NUPSE,
and it was always a conflict to get locals to identif
y with NUPE. This reticence extended to the broader
parturiency movement : Lenihan noted that some, like Calgary Local 37, resisted all boost to send delegates to any events outside of NUPE. Limited nati
onal revenue, due to the low level of per capita, was
particularly burdensome, peculiarly since many of triiodothyronine
he TLC locals were unions in name only, and had to be
rebuild from the prime up.
115
With only four national representatives by mid-1957 to service locals across
the entire area, the union faced serious difficultie
s, especially where Lenihan’s approach to training the
locals was concerned. While such a strategy would
diminish the burdens on the National Office in the long
term, in the short term it was easier for the reps to
substitute themselves for local leaders, who were often
profoundly grateful .
182 In other words, creating a newly union out of a series
of locals with little experience with effective
corporate bargaining, internal democratic functioning, c
oordination with other locals or membership in a
central administration, and with vehement commitment
s to their own autonomy developed during their TLC
years, was no easy undertaking. The terms of these gr
oups’ unity resulted in serious constraints on the
development of the cardinal function and on ability of it
s representatives to do more than provide the most
basic union education. Bob Rintoul ’ sulfur position as National
Director, while ostensibly similar to Little’s, was
frankincense well less potent in practice. conventional
unification of TLC municipal workers did not lead
automatically to actual substantive one or to
centralization and professionalization: this had to be
constructed with great campaign and was the chief one
ssue to confront NUPE through the late 1950s and early
1960s. V.
Conclusion: NUPSE and NUPE on the Eve of Merger
While facing a common context of post-war stat
e transformation, the legalization of labour
relations, and the professionalization of the tug moment
vement, various groups of public sector workers
produced a kind of organizational forms, institut
ionalized different identities, and emphasized distinct
notions of union serve and majority rule. A consens
us did exist amongst the leadership in NUPE and
NUPSE that a authentically national union in their jurisdic
tion was needed; however, the specificities of each
group ’ s development meant that serious disagreements over what that
union should do and how it should be
structured were inevitable. At the open of the first fusion talks in
1956, NUPSE was a relatively small, geographically
concentrated and centralized union with its kernel of
gravity in the municipal hydro and public utilities
sector. NUPSE leaders had been able to convince most of its locals of the beneficial outcomes of a higher per capita tax. These early locals generally a
ccepted such arrangements on the basis of ideological
183 116
Crean, 95.
commitments to a broad industrial unionism, and their master of arts
terial ties to the National Union through high
levels of servicing. In general, then, NU
PSE encouraged greater dependence of locals on the central
office, and members came to expect a high charge of
service from the national level of the union.
116
The combination of industrial unionism and the
desire for membership expansion explains the
transition, through CETU to NOCUEW to NUPSE, from a
relatively narrow to a broader self-definition.
These concerns with expansion besides combined wisconsin
th a consensus around the importance of a strong
national office to create pressures for the profe
ssionalization of NUPSE’s leadership, which began with the
institution of a full-time, appointed Di
rector of Organization. Although important internal struggles had to be
fight over what kind of leadership was most appropr
iate for the union in this period, the balance was
clearly in favor of experts who would take speed of light
harge over local negotiations and the organization of new
members. fiddling venture upon this with z
eal, and he subsequently became the union’s strongest
advocate for centralization and professionalization.
However, the particular strategy Little adopted to
achieve the sought expansion introduced into NU
PSE important centrifugal forces and tensions,
primarily in the phase of the OHEU. Pragmatic c
onsiderations gave OHEU vastly more autonomy than was
normally afforded most locals, therefore eating away
at NUPSE’s unifying identity and consensus over union
function and opening the gates to NUPSE coming to embrace NUPE ’ s more decentralize structure – although not inevitably its relatively more democratic ethos. In direct contrast to its counterpart, NUPE was
a larger, more geographically dispersed federation
of historically autonomous municipal locals in whic
h autonomy was the dominant feature. In the midst of
divers approaches to politics and union function, metric ton
hese locals were united by a common desire for
servicing and aid from a National Office. More
substantive differences were put aside so that
courtly one could be achieved. however, given thei
r commitments to local control over resources, the
184 extent of servicing which could be provided on a very lo
w per capita remained limited. As a result, multiple
forms of service, at the local, provincial and nat
ional levels emerged and provided the basis for competing
identities and power relations, and it was not one hundred fifty
ear in 1956 which level would become dominant.
furthermore, the combination of constrained national
resources, the ideological
orientation of authoritative leaders, and the attachment to autonomy
meant that professionalization
of the union remained limited well
into the 1960s. As a consequence, for both ideological and virtual reasons, NUPE emphasized greater membership control over and engagement in the daily run of their locals, even if this was unevenly achieved. thus, when NUPSE and NUPE met over the fusion
negotiating table in 1956, they were both
organizations whose geological formation in terms of identity and
function was ‘incomplete.’ While particular notions
were ‘ hegemonic ’ in each union, they were hush the subjec
t of internal struggles. The processes of resolving
the issues of identity, serve and structure were megabyte
ade infinitely more complex once the merger of these
two identical different organizations was in the works.
While the next phase of public employee unionism was
to centre on questions of structure, both identity
and function continued to reappear, particularly as these
cover assumptions about what constitu
ted democratic and effective trade unionism.
185 1
Power Workers’ Union, 16. After serving in the Navy during
the Second World War, Cummings went to work in the mines of
Northern Ontario and then was hired as a cons
truction worker for Ontario Hydro in Timmins in 1947. He was active in the
OHEA/U from 1952 onwards, first as a stewar
d, then Chief Steward, and later Second Vice-President. He was elected as the
first
full-time
OHEU President at the age of 30.
2
OHEU, Executive Board minutes, August 21,
1957: 10; December 16, 1957: 6. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7,
Files 8 and 9 ] chapter 5 : The Merger Process and Union Democracy I : The Initial Blockages, 1956-1959 By the 1950s, there was momentum for a amalgamation
amongst public sector unions. The two national
unions in the field, pressed by unifying trends in
the broader North American labour movement, soon had to
confront the necessity of combining what were tw
o very different organizations. Not only did NUPE and
NUPSE own divergent ideas about effective unionism
, the definition of good leadership, the appropriate
character of the membership, and the nature of the obligat
ions tying workers together, the unification process
brought into clear respite competing visions of union democracy. Some conceived union majority rule as based on a broad understand of the democratic constituency and workers ’ interests being served. This vision tended to be shared by the National tied leadership of both the unions, but was most clearly
expressed by OHEU’s president since 1956, Kealey
Cummings. As the son of a Northern Ontario miner
active in the Industrial Workers of the World,
1
it made
common sense that, for Cummings, workers were best served by
unity in the labour movement. Fragmentation and
sectionalism constituted a barrier to the effective
realization of workers’ democratic will and interests,
understand as socio-economic advancement and democrati
c participation in workplace decisions via
corporate bargaining. The one required for this intend that already-organized workers had obligations to the general interest, even when that conflicted with
particularist concerns; OHEU, for instance, thus
possessed “ a duty to sacrifice vitamin a far as possi
ble and at the same time provide leadership with the
object of realizing a hard national
union for all public utility workers.”
2
Those who remained outside of
these obligations, so far sought to benefit from labor moment
vement action, were “freeloaders”. In other words,
union democracy was tightly connected to outcomes, to
notions of redistributive justice in which more
186 3
Cummings’ role as representative of OHEU to the broader st
ructures of the union and his accountability to the Local 1000
membership frequently forced him to represent a more
sectionalist politics than this position would imply.
4
K. Munnings, “The Responsibility is Yours!” (circular), n.d. (1959)
: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 4]
herculean groups assisted weaker ones, and to the inte
rests of those beyond the immediately visible and
vote constituency.
3
Others, typically the leaders of boastfully and long-st
anding sub-units within the two national unions,
had a more proceduralist notion of democracy rooted in
protecting a pre-existi
nanogram mood of representing a given community of workers. Ken Munnings, OHEU ’ s
First Vice-President in 1957 and 1959, expressed this
notion of majority rule inherently connected to autonomy as
“the right to conduct our business in a way which
… the penis decides we should. ”
4
Already constituted membership groups thus possessed an absolute
and implicit in right to self-govern, to determine what
broader obligations they would and would not submit
to, and to place their finical needs ahead of those of an as-yet-unrealized wide community. however, union would require more than a
simple choice between one or other of these
visions. For both personal and political reasons, neither leadership group was will to adopt the others ’ model of unionism, and NUPSE in particular, as the
smaller of the two unions, placed major roadblocks in
the way of fusion until they could establish a
stronger bargaining position for themselves. Further
complicating the situation was the
fact that these conceptions of democracy were not neatly distributed
between the two national unions. rather, each marriage wa
s also possessed of important sub-units who held
flying to views at variance with those of their national leaders. As we saw in Chapter 3, the accommodation of these different claims produced particular balanc
es between centralism and autonomy, each with their
own contradictory implications. Any process which brought these two unions together would have to deal with and find new resolutions to these dilemmas. Spec
ifically, the nature and ext
ent of reciprocal obligations would have to be redefined, and structures which w
ould operationalize these obligations in a way that
187 5
Crean, 95.
balanced the needs of existing and future members would have to be constructed. As we shall see, given the competing democratic ( and other ) logics at work, this was to be no easily task. I.
First Steps and Opening Positions: The First Year of Merger Talks, 1956-57
NUPE and NUPSE had to have something in coarse beyond similar jurisdictions for the amalgamation summons to be contemplated at all. Some compelli
ng shared goals fostered in each a desire for merger, not
least of which was the resulting union ’ s potential prisoner of war
er and prestige within the Canadian labour movement.
Both NUPSE and NUPE wanted to create a union with national coverage and a hearty base in Quebec which had eluded both until now. Both unions had endured the dis
dain of fellow unionists for whom public sector
workers were not “ real number unionists ”, and the arroganc
e of employers who often possessed the upper hand
legally and strategically. Given the persistent grow
th in public sector employment and potential for
unionization, “ [ i ] t was plain to both executives that,
combined, they would add up to something substantially
greater than the sum of their two organizations, forg
ing a credible national force and acquiring unassailable
condition as the new exponent forget in canadian labor. ”
5
A growing sense of the irrationality of the francium
agmented structure of Canadian public sector unionism
besides drove the fusion. The being of paralle
l unions organizing in the same jurisdiction had become
distinctly inefficient : there was duplicate of work
, resources wasted fighting each other rather than
spreading organization even further, and a growing fear that disunity would give employers a strategic advantage. As Grace Hartman, CUPE ’ s National Pr
esident between 1975 and 1983, later recalled, it was
“ a farcical way to operate. The staff representativ
es from the two unions were like ships passing in the
nox. One would be going into Hamilton to look a
fter a civic group there and the other might be coming
aside from Hamilton after meeting with a hospital. We began to feel it was nonsense … it was expensive …
188 6
Grace Hartman, “Organizing Public Se
rvice Workers in the Sixties,” in
We Stood Together: First Hand Accounts of Dramatic
Events in Canada ’ s Labour Past
, ed. G. Montero (Toronto: James Lorimer and Co., 1979), 185.
7
Crean, 94.
8
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure Submitted by the National Director at the Request of the National
Executive Board ”, National Union of Public
Employees, April 1960: 4-5. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 9]; R.
Rintoul, National Director ’ s General R
eport, NUPE, 1961 Convention Pr
oceedings: 20-1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol. 2, File 14 ] and neither union was actually able to pr
ovide properly for the membership.”
6
“It was no secret” that NUPSE
and NUPE were organizing the like workers,
7
but this picture of amicable and mutually indifferent
coexistence did not always reflect conditions in thyroxine
he field. Competition between NUPE and NUPSE could be
ferocious, specially in the hospital sector. many felt
it unreasonable for unions who were now affiliates of the
same labor central to fight over the lapp work
ers, with the resulting waste of financial and human
resources, not to mention the employment
ers who could have been organized instead.
Both NUPSE and NUPE besides faced common external pressures as well. First, employers were continually transforming themselves to deal with
their growing and unionizing workforces. Gone were the
days when a municipal local had only the City Council to worry about, as public sector employers were becoming more effective at coordinating dicker and legi
slative efforts. Municipal employers were using
“ experts who formulate a uniform policy and tactical
plans for negotiations” with locals, with the goal of
establishing a inadequate design for settlements by bargaining wisconsin
th weaker locals first. Employer associations,
like the canadian Federation of Mayors and Municipalit
ies established in 1937, were also increasingly
effective at providing collective bargaining resear
ch for its members, planning a coordinated negotiating
strategy, and obtaining anti-labour legi
slation at the provincial level.
8
In this context, a fragmented public
sector union drift was a good liability. A second informant of atmospheric pressure came from
the newly-minted Canadian Labour Congress. From
today ’ second advantage point, it is difficult to see
how the merger between NUPE and NUPSE could have been
avoided once the TLC and CCL merged to create the CLC in 1956. The CLC ’ second policy was to rationalize the
189 9
Williams, 198.
10
Crean, 94.
11
Rogers, or “F.O.”, as he liked to be called, was Recording Secr
etary of Local 5 from 1949 to 1978. He also served as a NUPSE
vice-president and a penis of NU
PSE’s merger committee (Thomas, 38).
labor movement through the promot
ion of mergers where possible.
9
In a context where the historic differences between the TLC and CCL had been put aside,
affiliates were similarly expected to build
bridges with their former competit
ors. Crean argues that the pressure
from the CLC to form one national
public employees ’ union was capital,
10
and the particular pressure on public sector unions to merge may
have been because the CLC had little oscilloscope to implement its rationalization policy in jurisdictions dominated by U.S.-based unions. As NUPE and NUPSE
did not have to answer to international head
offices, a amalgamation between them would be significant
ly less complicated. Bringing together the purely
national public sector unions was thus seen as an easy way to achieve systematization and one in a labor apparent motion distillery characterized by structural and political
fragmentation. Given this external pressure from
the CLC, both unions had to ensure a amalgamation would ta
ke place on terms they could each live with, and thus
had to be actively involved in their own negociate summons. therefore, the mind of a NU
PE-NUPSE merger was a convergence of shared general aims and
common external pressures for union. In the context of the “ spirit of oneness ” generated by the TLC-CCL amalgamation, a “ get-acquainted meeti
ng” between representatives of
NUPE and NUPSE was held during the
CLC ’ s founding convention in April 1956. By common
agreement of the two unions and the CLC executive, a
joint fusion committee was created. The central fifty
eadership figures in both organizations were charged
with the responsibility for negotiating fusion : NUPE s
ent President Pat Lenihan, Vice-President Bill Buss
and National Director Bob Rintoul, while NUPSE wa
s represented by President James Clark, Frank
Rogers, Recording Secretary of
Hamilton Civic Workers Local 5,
11
Director of Organization Stan Little, and
an changing example from local 1000 ( at this
meeting, then-OHEU president A.W. Snell).
190 12
Lenihan, 179.
13
G. Cushing and J. MacKenzie, “Merger Proposal: a proposed basis of merger of the
National Union of Public Employees and
the National Union of Public Service
Employees”, submitted by
the Canadian Labour Congress, August 1, 1957. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 23 ]. Gordon Cushing
was a CLC Executive Vice-President and long-time friend of Pat
Lenihan, while Joe MacKenzie was the CLC ’ s Director of Organization. Two initial meetings in July and December
of 1956 showed that any “merger momentum” had
already dissipated, and the ‘ good will ’ which
may have existed between NUPE and NUPSE had been
superficial at best. While these beginning two conventional meet
ings were intended for the leaders to “get to know each
other ”,
12
they in fact revealed deep divisions over bot
h the kind of union that was wanted or needed, and
the method acting of creating a newly struct
ure and identity. The process of combining these two organizations
would be anything but quick or easy. Although Me
moranda of Understanding were drawn up after both
meetings, and the CLC issued a fusion marriage proposal for NUPE and NUPSE in August 1957,
13
the ‘agreement’
reached on respective issues was ephemeral. Differences
on a legion of structural and political issues were
fundamental and with few promptly available solutions.
Moreover, each of the unions had significant and
knock-down factions protective of their own interest
s in the context of a merger, and who injected their
particularist concerns into the discussions. ultimately, the CLC was concerned with the accurate form of the newfangled union, and sought to balance the desires of the tw
o unions with those of international affiliates
organizing in the same jurisdictions. The documents produced by the Unity Committee and the CLC in the first year of amalgamation discussions both provide a outline
of the substantive issues which separated the two
unions, and allow us to understand why so much fourth dimension
passed before real progress on merger was made.
To begin with, the two unions and their representativ
es did not hold each other in high esteem. For
NUPSE, NUPE was not a ‘ real union ’ – it was nothing molybdenum
re than a weak federation of locals, with little
capacity for central leadership, whether in corporate dicker or in politics. Recall that some were convinced that NUPE was a hasty and insubstantial
creation of the TLC designed to thwart NUPSE in the
modern merged CLC. Others argued that
NUPE’s greater numbers were deceiving: the majority of their locals
191 14
W.A. Whitehead, “Analysis of the Proposed Merger between
NUPSE and NUPE”, submitted to the NUPSE Unity Committee,
September 26, 1957 : 1, 2. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 11 ] 15
Lenihan, 194.
16
W. Black, letter to P. Lenihan, August 9, 1956: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 13]
were accused of not functioning effectively, and were newspaper tigers at best.
14
For NUPSE leaders,
peculiarly little, a ‘ real number union ’ had to entail cardinal c
ontrol and direction. The National Office should be the
elementary actor, dispensing cognition and resources to the locals. a army for the liberation of rwanda as Little and early NUPSE adherents were concerned, only a strong national union could foster membership identification and commitment, and attract and keep members. While surely desirous
of a larger membership, and while buying into the
equation of union size and office, in the context of
merger negotiations NUPSE r
epresentatives repeatedly emphasized the importance of timbre over size. These arguments were opportunist ampere well, for NUPSE, as the smaller coupling, was ever cowardly of submersion
into their larger and, in their eyes, less effective
counterpart. NUPE, on the other hired hand, saw NUPSE as an autoc
ratic, top-heavy and ineffective union unable to
organize its jurisdiction. Some had unplayful concerns about the quality of democracy in NUPSE, and the extent of world power held by appoint staff like Little.
Lenihan in particular was known to favour a member-run
union in which the staff was subordinate to the elected leadership.
15
Moreover, if their record was anything
to go by, a NUPSE-led union would not be astir to the
task of organizing the growing numbers of Canadian
public sector workers. Bill Black of Local 180 – the
provincial BC Hospital Employees’ Union – argued that
“ our National Union is the strongest numerically and i
deologically and we are truly national in character …
the NUPSE, to my cognition, has no persuasiveness to speak
of in Western Canada, and very little in the East.”
According to Black, NUPE should not think of the me
rger as one between equals similar to that of the TLC
and CCL.
16
In other words, union size reflected somethi
ng more than mere numbers – it indicated an ability
to appeal to public sector workers in a way that spoke
to their interests and motivated them to join. Some
of this appeal was said to be located in NUPE ’ s stru
cture. Many did not agree that the relationship
192 17
Crean, 97.
between structure, identity and growth in NUPE was as
simple as “weak National, weak identity”. Indeed,
as Grace Hartman by and by argued, NUPE ’ s decentralized
structure may have done more for the construction
of recognition with NUPE, given the function that lo
cals and members were expected to play in the union.
Hartman admitted that while “ loos
e structure and local autonomy can weaken a union as a national force,
… it besides strengthens the members ’ committedness to
the organization if they can belong and have a say.”
17
For some, the greater telescope for local inaugural and
heavier reliance on activist-organizers explained NUPE’s
successful growth, while NUPSE ’ s ongoing difficulties wi
th expansion were read as a condemnation of their
centralize model of unionism. These common evaluations and prejudices form
ed the implicit substratum of the negotiations
through which all proposals would be filtered and measure
ed. Each side therefore had powerful motivations
to avoid adoption of the other ’ mho structure and rehearse
s. This consideration was particularly acute for
NUPSE, which, as the smaller union, was facing assi
milation rather than merger. This was an imminent
possibility, for the structure
and amount of representation on gov
erning bodies proposed in the 1956-57
fusion documents distinctly gave the advantage to NUPE.
NUPE adherents saw no real problem with using
assimilation as the method for creating a new ident
ity and organization, for their decentralized practices
afforded significant space for differences between the lo
cals. Besides, as the larger union they felt they
should by rights be able to retain their structures.
However, NUPSE, and Little in particular, could not
accept such a method acting of union : while NUPSE
locals might be granted autonomy in the new structure,
they would be fragmented, ineffective to exercise the
kind of centralized and professionalized unionism to
which they had become accustomed, and, as a minorit
y, incapable of changing the union’s structure once it
had been settled upon .
193 18
NUPE and NUPSE, “Memorandum of U
nderstanding”, December 1956: 1, CUPE Fonds [N
AC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol 3, File 22]
19
NUPSE National Executive Board, “Direc
tive adopted by NUPSE National Executive
Board at their Meeting of April 27
th
, 1957
for the guidance of all concerned ; outlining this Organization ’ sulfur position towards Merger with early Unions ”. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 14 ]. 20
G. Cushing and J. MacKenzie, “Merger Proposal”, 5.
Discussions of the proportional theatrical performance of
the two unions in the new organization epitomized
these differences over how to create a raw organi
zational identity. These representational issues
concerned the appoint of the new organization, the presidency, and the number and distribution of national executive dining table seats. The matter of the new
union’s name represented the competing approaches –
assimilation versus synthesis – at a emblematic degree. For the NUPE people, the question required short think. Since they were the larger union, the ‘ m
erger’ was really a matter of NUPSE joining their
social organization ; their relative importance and world power shoul
d be reflected in the adoption of NUPE as the name of
the new union. The July proposals reflected this
logic and would have the new organization adopt NUPE
as its name “ national to legal problems arising re personnel casualty
of certification” that NUPSE locals might face with
such a name change.
18
NUPSE representatives gave their assent
initially, but soon reversed their position.
In an April 1957 directing concerning “ this Organization ’
s attitude towards Merger with other Unions”, the
NUPSE NEB agreed that, in any fusion, they would in
sist upon a new name for the organization to avoid
any sense that they were being submerged.
19
By August of 1957, the CLC itself had found the symbolic
middle ground in its Merger Proposal for NU
PE and NUPSE: the new union’s name would the
Canadian
Union of Public Employees.
20
The other issues of representation which flow
ed from these fundamentally opposed attitudes were
less promptly solvable. The presidency, a well as
the number and distribution of executive seats and their
method of election, was not to be resolved until early 1962,
six years into the merger process. Again, it
was assumed by NUPE that the first gear presidency watt
ould “appropriately” go to one of their delegates due to
their larger membership. Five Vice-Presidents woul
d, with the President, form the National Executive
194 21
NUPE and NUPSE, “Memorandum of U
nderstanding”, 1-2. What constituted “suffi
cient membership” was not defined in the
August 1957 marriage proposal, nor in any of
the subsequent merger discussions.
22
T. Lewis, letter to P. Lenihan, August 16, 1956: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 13]; Tom Lewis was a
plumber at Vancouver City Hall who Lenihan described as “ a leftist liberal
”, having been a member of the “old Socialist Party
”
( Lenihan, 176 ). 23
W. Young, letter to P. Lenihan, August 28, 1956: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 13]
24
B. Black, letter to P. Lenihan, August 9, 1956: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 13]
25
T. Lewis, letter to P. Lenihan, August 16, 1956: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 13]
Board, with three of these positions going initially
to NUPE. The full National Executive Council would
consist of the NEB and at least one spokesperson from
each province with “sufficient membership”, to be
elected by the respective provincial caucuses.
21
The existing geographic structure of NUPE would thus be
retained, american samoa would its numeric advantage on the
Executive Board and Council, since it had organized
members in more provinces than had NUPSE. obviously for some, tied this rather meager allotment to NUPSE was a concession on NUPE ’ randomness separate. Tom Lewis, NUPE ’ randomness Second Vice-President from Local 15, Vancouver City Hall, argued that they appeared to be “ conceding excessively much recognition
and consideration to a minority group.”
22
Bill Young,
NUPE administrator member from Edmonton City Hall
Local 52, wanted both the president and the vice-
presidents elected from the
floor
, even at the founding convention. De
spite knowing that NUPE’s numerical
advantage would allow them to defeat whomever
NUPSE fielded, Young insisted that “[i]f we have no
courage in our force now, we never will. ”
23
For Bill Black’s part, the proposed executive council structure
was impossible, since it was a departure from NUPE ’
s practice of electing more than one representative
from provinces with larger memberships ; he warned
that a reduction in BC’s
representation on the NEC
“ would not be possible. ”
24
Similarly, Lewis insisted upon a distribut
ion of executive seats on a “pro-ratio
basis and specially so provincially ” and pit changes to the method acting of electing peasant administrator representation.
25
In other words, both Black and Lewis wished to
retain a provincial structure which, while
apparently motivated by a desire to protect detail puerto rico
ovincial interests, would also result in an even larger
representational advantage for NUPE at the home leve
l. These positions epitomized the most extreme
195 26
NUPE and NUPSE, “Memorandum
of Understanding”, 1, 2.
assimilationist attitudes on NUPE ’ second contribution, and demons
trated a remarkable lack of concern about whether
NUPSE would be adequately represented and what effect deoxythymidine monophosphate
heir marginalization might have on the unity of
the post-merger union.
NUPSE representatives initially conceded the puerto rico
esidency to NUPE. However, while general if
doubtful agreement was expressed, it
was obvious that NUPSE was loathe to
admit the implications of its
lesser numbers and bargained for a better remainder between the two unions. consultation with the NUPSE NEB revealed they wanted a quid pro quo pro quo for relinqui
shing the presidency. NUPSE delegates now seemed
to be hedging on the question of NUPE taking the presi
dency: they reported that
the recommendation “had
received a favorable retainer inasmuch as it was recognized that alone one President could be maintained and that NUPE was the larger of the
two Organizations.” In other words, NUPSE had
grudgingly recognized the logic of the proposal, but was
not yet willing to accede to its implications. All
they would say now is that the new marriage ’ s president
should
come from NUPE. While the respective NEBs
agreed on the number of Vice-Presidents, their di
vision between NUPE and NUPSE was still unresolved.
For the NUPSE Executive Board, “ 3 of the 5 Vice
-Presidents was a requisite” in exchange for their
concessions on the name and presidency of the new union.
In this they were tentatively supported by the
CLC ’ s representative, Joe MacKenzie, at the December
meeting. NUPE, of course, continued to insist on
three VPs for themselves.
26
The size and part of the full executive counc
il was the subject of rather more debate, with
NUPSE pointing out that they woul
d be outnumbered on the full executive by twelve to four, given the
provincial distribution of NUPE and NUPSE locals.
Again, MacKenzie attempted some compromise,
suggesting that NUPE initially receive entirely six ( quite t
han seven) provincial representatives, thus reducing
their overall authority of the full administrator to nine to
six. The minutes from the December meeting do not
196 27
Ibid., 2.
28
CLC figures show that in mid-1957 NUPE had 205 locals representing nearly 35,000 members in all provinces except PEI.
NUPSE, on the other hand, had 60 locals representing around 15,
500 members on the provinces of Saskatchewan, Manitoba,
ontario and Quebec. G. Cushing and J.
MacKenzie, “Merger Proposal”, 2, 3.
29
G. Cushing and J. MacKenzie, “Merger Proposal”, 6. Interesti
ngly, while the CLC Merger Propos
al quite clearly favoured the
geographic footing for representation, Cushing and MacKenzie were united nations
willing to jettison the NUPSE sectoral structure, therefore
permitting both provincial divisions and serv
ice divisions. However, without providi
ng any structural relationship between sectoral
groupings and the decision-making structure of
the national union, adoption of this pr
oposal would have set up the conditions f
or
the eventual irrelevance of NUPSE ’ s former structure. Thr
oughout the merger discussions, the
issue of sectoral groups was
raised but always ill manage with, therefore leaving an ambivalence for CUPE to deal with in the future. 30
G. Cushing and J. MacKenzie, “Merger Proposal”, 7.
indicate any reception from NUPE : given the logic of
their position on other repr
esentational issues, it is condom to assume they rejected such an arrangement without much consideration.
27
The CLC Merger Proposal provided little consolation to the NUPSE delegates with respect to their future representation. The Proposal clearly gave the numeral and structural advantage to NUPE, despite MacKenzie ’ s more compromising gestures in December 1956. As the larger union
28
with a provincial
structure, NUPE would carry the numbers on the silicon
x-member National Executive Committee and have the
advantage at the larger National Executive Board, si
nce representation would be based on provincial rather
than sectoral lines.
29
The NEC would be the union’s main administrative body between conventions, and
would consist of the National President and five Vice-Presidents elected on a regional basis, but ‘ at large ’ at the annual conventionality. The CLC marriage proposal therefore mandat
ed one VP from the Pacific Region, two from the
Prairie Region and two from the eastern Region. The National Executive Board would consist of the NEC and a representative “ named by each ”
provincial division. NUPE would hold the presidency, and a VP
position from each of the three regions for a sum of
4 on the NEC. NUPSE, t
herefore, would hold two VP
positions, one from each of the Prairie and East
ern Regions for a total of two on the NEC.
30
The principle
used to distribute these VPs to each of NUPE and NU
PSE concerned their relative numerical strength in
each of the define regions. The circulation of the August 1957 proposals and
the clear advantage they implied for NUPE led
some NUPSE members, like OHEU second vice-president William Whitehead, to question more vigorously
197 31
W.A. Whitehead, “Analysis of the Proposed Merger”, 1, 2.
32
Lenihan, 184.
33
The BSEIU has been known as the Service Employ
ees International Union (SEIU) since 1968.
the apologize logic ’ south cogency and to posit a connect betw
een “union quality” and represent
ational rights. NUPE’s
larger membership should not automatically give them greater executiv
e board representation, let alone the
presidency. Whitehead argued that the numbers presented “ a very diagonal
ed and actually untrue picture” of
the relative military capability of the two unions. “ Numbers in
a case such as this can be extremely misleading
because 15,000 people who are actually functioning as a
Union can quite likely supply better Presidential
material than another constitution with
35,000 which are not functioning.”
31
In his basic facts, it seems
Whitehead was not army for the liberation of rwanda off, as Lenihan himself readily
admitted in his recollections that many NUPE
affiliates were locals “ in name only ” – “ hapless constitution, poor agreements, inadequate local anesthetic leadership, no patronize stewards, and no educational oeuvre to imbue the
membership with some degree of militancy.”
32
Such
weaknesses gave NUPSE some further justification for
believing they were entitled to a greater proportion
of representation in CUPE. A direct implication of NUPE ’ s continual insist
ence on the lion’s share of representation was a
dogged immunity on NUPSE ’ s part to conclude amalgamation any
time soon. Instead, in an attempt to improve
its position in the fusion talks, NUPSE embarked on a run of aggressive expansionism which brought it into conflicts with NUPE and other unions like Build
ing Service Employees International Union (BSEIU)
33
organizing in the hospital jurisdiction. Attempts
to organize groups of provincial workers, like
Saskatchewan psychiatric hospital workers and Manitoba Hydro employees, would besides bring NUPSE into address conflict with the CLC itself, which was equi
vocal at best about the organizational forms appropriate
for public employees in general. The CLC ’ s definition
of the future jurisdiction of CUPE, and whether it
would encompass NUPSE ’ s early jurisdiction as defined by the CCL, thus became a central issue for NUPSE in the fusion talks through the future several years .
198 34
G. Cushing and J. MacKenzie, “Merger Proposal”, 5.
These jurisdictional problems were triggered by
both NUPE’s initial merger stance and the CLC’s
1957 Merger Proposal. While NUPSE insisted the fresh or
ganization retain the jurisdiction of both former
unions, the CLC proposal defined CUPE ’ mho field as incl
uding “any group of workers in Canada comprised of
employees of a Civic or municipal Government body, or any sub-division thence, or of a Public Board, Commission, Hospital or Library in the Civic or Municipal field, or of any other Civic or Municipal Public governing body. ”
34
This delineation would seem to leave in ambigui
ty the status of provincial electrical utility
workers which were so significant in NUPSE. The CLC
also omitted the status of both direct and indirect
peasant politics workers, which, given its
tendency towards a more expansive identity, NUPSE also
considered within its legitimate jurisdiction. There
were future implications for the new union as well:
confining CUPE ’ s jurisdiction to municipal workers w
ould serve to limit its later growth, and thus the
influence it could wield in the broader canadian labor
movement. NUPSE was to focus nearly all of its
attention on this doubt of legal power in subsequent
merger talks, making it a major obstacle until 1961.
We will return to this central trouble in the next incision. Tensions besides existed around the definition and alloca
tion of staff positions in the new union. Both
sides accepted that the new union would need more st
aff, particularly as NUPE still relied on the CLC for
aid in servicing their locals. The immediate refer for some, like Little and Rintoul, was whether or not they would retain or improve their copper
rrent position. However, the question of what
kind
of staff was
required and the character they should play in the union alabama
so simmered under the surface. It is difficult to
divide out genuine differences in approaches to staffi
ng from the personal dislike some had of the likely
resident of a particular placement. however, it appears that NUPE favoured increase staff representatives to work with the locals, while NU
PSE would later advocate great
er numbers of expert staff
199 35
Lenihan, 182; F. Eady, “Report on Current Position re Merger
with NUPE (Confidential)”, September 20, 1960, CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5 File 12. ] 36
W. Black, letter to P. Lenihan, August 9, 1956: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 13]
37
T. Lewis, letter to P. Lenihan, August 16, 1956: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 13]
38
W. Young, letter to P. Lenihan, August 28, 1956: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 13]
39
NUPE and NUPSE, “Memorandum
of Understanding”, 2.
at the central office.
35
However, the latter issue would rema
in submerged for some time, while more
personalistic objections took immediate concentrate phase. It was initially agreed that all staff from each uni
on would be retained, along with the two top staff
positions – National Director and Director of Organi
zation – whose work would be divided accordingly and
whose condition would be equal. however, given the many
qualms expressed about the position of Director of
organization vitamin a well as the probable resident of that oxygen
ffice, Stan Little, who, during his years at NUPSE had
been relatively unsuccessful in organizing fresh members, NUPE soon rethought their place. Bill Black questioned “ the sex appeal of having a NUPSE representative fall aut
omatically into the position of Director
of Organization ”, given that “ the NUPSE organization di
d not have the ramifications of our organization.”
36
Tom Lewis opposed the Director of Organization
coming from NUPSE “unless it can be proven that
member has the best qualifications to hold such a stead. ”
37
Finally, William Young suggested that having
both a National Director and Director of Organization of
equal status was merely a way to “pacify” NUPSE,
and what was sincerely needed was a Head of Research.
38
This was not to mention the potential conflicts that
would arise as a result of two men, once accu
stomed to being in charge of their respective unions,
having to share ‘ equal ’ and ill-defined positions in
the new organization. As a result, NUPE argued in
December that “ one Officer should have the respons
ibility and authority between B
oard Meetings”, which,
not amazingly, “ should be vested in
their present National Director.”
39
Given the more specific nature of
the Director of Organization ’ sulfur function, it would make
sense to allocate general administrative responsibility
to the National Director. Clearly unwilling to imagine Stan Little taking management from Robert Rintoul, however, NUPSE inescapably resisted this trace .
200 40
G. Cushing and J. MacKenzie
, “Merger Proposal”, 2-4.
41
NUPE and NUPSE, “Memorandum
of Understanding”, 3.
The CLC ’ s staffing proposals attempted a more even-handed and legitimate approach : a full-time Secretary-Treasurer ( preferably than
National Director) and a Director of Organization would be appointed by
the NEC, each of whom would be the present NUPE
National Director and NUPSE Director of Organization
respectively. possibly instinctively understand how
poorly Rintoul and Little were to get on, the CLC
prescribed that the Secret
ary-Treasurer be located in Ottawa and t
he Director of Organization in Toronto, despite the irrationality of a geographically cleave nati
onal office. All existing staff were to be offered
employment in CUPE. In 1957, if all continued in their positions, CUPE ’ s total staff complement would have been one Researcher, nine playing field staff and four selenium
cretaries, with seven coming from each union.
40
While an restless agreement reigned on this question, more
fundamental differences over the extent and
types of staffing were to emerge at a former point in the fusion process. The CLC Merger Proposal besides raised a barbed i
ssue which had lain dormant in the first year of
discussions : that of ‘ per head ’ union dues.
The July 1956 meeting unanimously agreed that one per
caput structure should exist for the stallion organization.
41
however, the issue was not quite so simple, and two relate issues emerged to plague the fusion talks.
First, the level at which per capita would be set
was a matter of great controversy. Second, the antique
istence of groups within each union who had, up to now,
been exempted in diverse ways from the standard per hundred
apita rate, and wanted this arrangement to continue
on the grounds that they were self-servicing, was to
prove extremely problematic
. The problem of these
limited locals was the cause of major inner
struggles in both NUPE and especially NUPSE between
1957 and 1960. The CLC Merger Proposal set the manque CUPE ’ s
per capita at 50 cents per member per month.
201 42
G. Cushing and J. MacKenzie, “Merger Proposal”, 3, 4.
43
The BC Federation of Public Employees was
the precursor of the BC Division of CUPE.
however, the deviation between both unions ’ actual
per capitas and the proposed one was significant. In
1957, NUPE ’ second per caput was set at 27 cents, NUPSE ’ sulfur at $ 1.00.
42
Many NUPSE members could not
visualize how a per caput of 50 cents would permit the fresh National Union to provide them with the overhaul they had come to rely upon. The huge majority
of the NUPE membership paid dramatically less than
NUPSE ’ second per head, and an increase to 50 cents west
ould entail a near doubling of per capita. NUPE
members in general were reluctant to provide any nati
onal structure with more per capita, as this would
drain resources at the local anesthetic level, specially in
those unions unwilling to go to the membership for dues
increases. quite much, debates in both unions
about per capita had been framed in terms of cheapness
and parochialism versus generosity, indeed
lidarity and progressive thinking.
Indeed, the question of per capita
does involve views on what members owe each early, par
ticularly in redistributive terms, and thus speaks
to unlike definitions of ‘ community ’. While deoxythymidine monophosphate
hese attitudes no doubt informed the various positions, the
debate over the allow level of per head
also reflected deeper disagreements over the proper
localization of might and agency in the union, the decline
function of the union and who should carry it out, and
the necessary elements of the union ’ s structure to
be built up and how. In NUPSE’s case, per capita
reflected the laterality of a vision in which the centrum
l union provided service to locals, while in NUPE, a
majority believed that locals should retain most of
the resources and control, particularly over staff, and that
central services should be relatively limited and technical in nature. To complicate matters further, in each organizati
on, specific groups had special arrangements with
their respective national union, and did not pay the like
level of per capita as most locals. These groups,
the BC Federation of Public Employees,
43
and Locals 180, 43 and 79 in NUPE, and OHEU and Local 500 in
NUPSE, were large and mighty in their respective
organizations, and the effect of the merger on these
groups could not but be a major circumstance for metric ton
he negotiating committees. As we saw in Chapter 3,
202 44
G. Cushing and J. MacKenzie, “Merger Proposal”, 4.
OHEU per caput was a mere 10 cents, and, if made to
relinquish their special rate, joining the new union
would entail an increase of 500 %. The Winnipeg Civic
Federation, NUPSE Local 500, similarly paid at a
especial pace of 15 cents.
44
Both deemed ‘self-servicing’, these units merely paid NUPSE little more than
their CLC affiliation fees. NUPE had like problems, but
they took a different form. NUPE locals had built
up a tradition of self-servicing as directly affiliates of the Trades and Labor Congre
ss, and many of the larger
ones had long employed their own full-time commercial enterprise agents.
Many locals therefore resisted increases, and
some, like Locals 43 and 79, would demand rebates if per head was raised by even a minuscule sum. A conventional rebate organization existed in the case of the
BC Federation of Public Employees and Local 180, who
received a annually grant from the National to service thyroxine
he BC membership. Moreover, many of the full-time
business agents acted as a pro-autonomy force in NUPE,
as their power and control was situated in the
local. These locals were not to give up su
ch arrangements easily, and the question of business agents
would become a serious trouble in the late days of the fusion discussions. consequently, within both unions, unlike groups
had varying expectations of the National Union.
Their extra arrangements reflected the being
of competing identities and visions within each
administration, some centred on the local anesthetic, some on t
he sector, and some on the province. The question of
per capita would thus involve a debate over which identities should be accepted as legitimate and deserve of recognition and digest. The relative power
of these different groups was to determine the
extent to which their particular interests were to be public relations
eserved within the future union structure. For the time
being, however, approaches to the motion of financi
ng the new organization were anything but unified,
and important home battles had to be fought within each union first. interestingly, although NUPE was seen as particula
rly weak vis-à-vis its locals, nowhere was this
argue over the relative ability of different levels
of the union more protracted than in the relationship
203 45
Interestingly, Kealey Cummings, a major protagonist in the r
enegotiation of OHEU’s status inside NUPSE, completely rejected
the idea that OHEU had a special character in the fusion committee,
or was in any way an obstacle to merger( Kealey Cummings,
consultation by author, 17 December, 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON ). As
we shall see in a forthcoming section, an examination of
NUPSE and OHEU documents between 1957 and 1960 re
veals otherwise. Indeed, the Powe
r Workers’ Union’s own history
indicates that resoluteness of the OHEU-
NUPSE dispute “cleared the way for the Na
tional Union’s merger with NUPE” (Power
Workers ’ Union, 22 ). between NUPSE and its local 1000, the Ontario Hydro Employees ’ Union. While the leadership of NUPSE seemed initially subject, for pragmatic sanction reasons, to to
lerate the extensive autonomy afforded to OHEU, they
had no choice but to reconsider this position once
merger talks with NUPE began. From the outset, the
extra status of OHEU within NUPSE was viewed
as a problem by both NUPE and CLC representatives.
The being of such a big unit which did not pay wide per head and which had no obligation to adhere to decisions made by the diverse governing bodies of the union would introduce an important element of fiscal and political weakness in any unify entit
y. OHEU’s status had already exposed NUPSE to
charges from the rest of the british labour party
movement that they were not a
“real union”, especially from private
sector unions whose organizations had more substant
ial centralized control, and made them look like
hypocrites when accusing NUPE of the very thing they
also suffered in their midst. Furthermore, it was
( rightly ) feared that the being of a local paying
a “special rate” would unleash internal divisions and a
deluge of demands for similar arrangements, particularly
amongst the highly autonomist NUPE locals. For
NUPE, the NUPSE-OHEU Agreement of
Understanding was thus a serious barrier to consummating the
amalgamation.
45
NUPSE was in a delicate position as a consequence. While desiring the amalgamation, OHEU ’ s ability besides had to be appreciated and thus cautiously managed by NUPSE liter
eaders. Recall that the OHEU’s affiliation tripled
NUPSE ’ s membership overnight, and that it could leave the Union with less than 6,000 members at a moment ’ mho notice. NUPSE leaders were
therefore faced with two choices: to allow OHEU representatives to
shape the negotiations in a direction that protected their parti
cular interests, thus likely scuttling the chances of
amalgamation, or to renegotiate or even eliminate t
he 1956 Agreement of Underst
anding, thereby potentially
204 46
R. Rintoul, letter to NUPE Executive Board, January 1957:
1-2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 3, File 13]
47
NUPE and NUPSE, “Memorandum
of Understanding”, 3.
48
R. Rintoul, letter to NUPE Executive Board, January 1957: 1-
2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 3, File 13]
pushing OHEU out of the Union and ensuring the fusion
would be the assimilation that was feared. This
was a Hobson ’ s Choice, to be indisputable. It appears that, during the initial amalgamation discussions
in 1956, the first alternative was opted for. The
bearing and interventions of an OHEU spokesperson on the NUPSE fusion committee from December 1956 ahead gave the NUPE committee “ the impression that we were not discussing a possible amalgamation with NUPSE, but quite with the Hydro Employees. ” B
ob Rintoul in particular felt that “Hydro was the big
concern regarding a fusion ” and was acting as stumbling block in the action.
46
indeed, NUPSE admitted that “ it would take a limited time to have their self-s
ustaining units brought completely into accord” with a
unified per caput social organization.
47
In Rintoul’s subsequent letter to members of the NUPE Executive, however,
he reported the time needed by NUPSE to be “ considerabl
e”. In a meeting with the CLC Executive
Committee, it was agreed that “ deoxyadenosine monophosphate long as the Hydro peopl
e were involved, it was useless trying to bring
about a fusion. ”
48
Given this situation, NUPSE leaders had li
ttle choice but to contemplate the second
option : fetch OHEU under its Constitution and e
liminate the Agreement of
Understanding. The difficult
negotiations over this exit were to last three year
s, constituting another important obstacle to merger, and
will be discussed in more detail in a late part. Given the differences over the manner of me
rger and representational
issues, the important
internal divisions over per caput and ‘ limited
interests’, and the problem of jurisdiction, NUPSE
representatives indicated at the
end of 1956 that their membership w
ould not be ready for fusion until at least 1958. As we shall see, they were modest in thyroxine
heir estimate: in fact, the problems with jurisdiction and
OHEU would keep NUPSE from badly pursuing thousand
ger until 1960. After the December 1956 meeting,
the NUPE Committee concluded that the amalgamation proce
ss was at present a waste of time and money, and
205 49
Ibid.
50
R. Rintoul, Merger Report to the 1958 NUPE Convention: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 2, File 9]
decided to attend future meetings only when called by the CLC.
49
As a result, little progress was made on
amalgamation between 1957 and 1961. The perceive reasons fo
r these delays were themselves a source of
bitterness, particularly within NUPE, and reduced the parti
cipants’ drive to negotiate even further. The NUPE
Merger Committee, and Rintoul in particular, contradict
ved NUPSE was stalling until they could negotiate more
advantageous terms for themselves. Rintoul felt that
NUPSE was “merely playing the cat and mouse game
until such fourth dimension as they figure the cards are falling their way, and it is in their interests in a selfish direction to continue amalgamation meetings. ”
50
From NUPSE ’ s point of opinion, however, it is hard to
see what else they could have done but stall for
clock time. NUPE ’ mho attitude towards NUPSE ’ randomness place in
the new union presented the smaller union with an
unattractive loss of political baron, and the toleration of a union structure which they felt inadequate to their vision of ‘ effective unionism ’. Threatened with
the potential loss of present and future membership,
depending upon the consequence of jurisdictional haggle with the CLC and the negotiations with OHEU, as well as with the possibility of being swallowed up by
NUPE, NUPSE had no choice but to consolidate its
position to be considered a more actual ‘ equal ’ to NU
PE. The ‘resolutions’ found to each of these
problems was besides to have an important impact on the determine of the future union. II.
Jurisdictional Battles: Organizing Ho
spital and Provincial Workers
The desire for parity with NUPE thus led NUPSE in
to a pragmatic pursuit of more members and a
broader legal power via a vigorous campaign of expansion.
This was not the first time that expansion was
seen as the solution to NUPSE ’ s potential elimination :
remember that the addition of OHEU to its ranks in
1956 had been equitable enough to stave off NUPSE ’ s elimination by
the CLC as the smallest of the four unions
operate in the public sector legal power. At
the NUPSE NEB’s April 1957 meeting, however, Little argued
206 51
NUPSE, National Executive Board Minutes, April 27, 1957: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 6, File 4]
52
S. Little, “The Director’s Report”,
NUPSE News
1 (12): 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol 3, File 25]. Interestingly,
this phrase describing NUPSE ’ s motivations for pursuing the Montreal civic
workers is underlined in the copy of
NUPSE News
held by the National Archives of Canada. This transcript is depart of the NUPE files on the fusion discussions, and therefore one can conclude that their suspicions about NUPSE ’ s desire to
expand before concluding the
merger were confirmed.
53
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, April 27, 1957: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 6, File 4]. With the
universe of the CLC, the federation ’ second per vitamin c
apita was reduced to 7 cents. OHEU agreed to
continue to pay at the former per capit
a
degree of the CCL, 10 cents, with the solution that 3 penny
s were now going to NUPSE to
support organizing the unorganized.
that the hazard of elimination remained, particularly gastrointestinal
ven the tenor of merger talks with NUPE, and, as a
solution, the Union had to redouble its efforts to organize and expand its jurisdiction.
51
In December 1959, the
issue of expansion remained central : in the union ’ south newsletter,
NUPSE News
, Little publicly identified
NUPSE ’ second strengths and weaknesses in the respective prov
inces and pointed out the areas of potential future
arrangement. Manitoba, Saskatchewan, Ontario and
Quebec were deemed areas of strength and potential
growth. Of particular importance was the anticipated in
tegration of the Montreal civic workers’ local into
NUPSE by mid-1960, which, Little argued, “ will not onl
y add great prestige and balance to our Union, but
will besides enhance our bargaining position in future
Merger talks with our counterpart organization.”
52
however, NUPSE ’ s ability to organize had long been an
issue of some concern, both internally and
in the old CCL. “ Certain weaknesses ” continued to act as a bracken on expansion, not least of which was the unwillingness of OHEU – as the largest affiliate – to
contribute sufficient financial resources to fund
organizing campaigns and develop the world power of the National Union.
53
The use of expansion as a tactic to
improve NUPSE ’ s influence over the routine and stru
cture of the merged entity thus raised several
significant issues. First, given the NUPSE ’ s difficult
ies with new organizing, the method of expansion was
shifted to fusion with already organized groups. Su
ch a strategy entailed negotiations at the leadership
grade, with which Little felt a lot more comfort
able, and de-emphasized the role of members in decision-
making about the kind of union they wanted. The pursuit
of mergers thus reinforced a notion that members
were to be mobilized behind leadership initiatives ra
ther than represented by
those leaders. Second,
expansion brought the question of identity and park in
terests back to the fore. As new groups like
207 54
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, April 27, 1957: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 6, File 4]
55
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes,
February 11, 1956: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC A
cc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 6, File 3]; Lenihan,
188. 56
Bud Henderson was a CCF partisan from
Saskatchewan who later became Director
of CUPE’s Prairie Region. (MacMillan,
149 ). hospital workers were introduced into the union,
these challenged the prevailing ideas of OHEU in
particular regarding which workers they shared interests with, and what kind of union structure was needed to serve those interests. As well, the kinds of
compromises necessary to bring these groups into NUPSE,
largely through limited per caput rates and memory of
local servicing structures, diluted the central union’s
command over resources and required that the barium
is of unity within the union be renegotiated.
There were besides external brakes on NUPSE ’ s gr
owth. As NUPSE moved to bring more workers
into their fold, specially in the hospital and hydro southeast
ctors in the Prairies, the CLC refused to clarify
jurisdictional boundaries in the populace sector. As a result, NUPSE ’ s expansionism brought it into good conflict with the CLC and several of its affiliates,
some of whom continued to feel bitter about OHEU’s
affiliation to NUPSE and who were alleged to be actively
working to undermine the union’s credibility in the
labor movement and within the union itself.
54
The questions of NUPSE expansion, jurisdiction and the
particular condition of OHEU were therefore intertwined in complicate ways. Unsurprisingly, the problem of legal power emerged
within the first year of the CLC’s existence.
Negotiations were unmanageable given the count of
unions occupying the same space, and exacerbated by
some unions ’ avocation of expansion without waiting for
the lines to be set down by the CLC. With the
Winnipeg Civic Federation ’ s addition to NUPSE ’ second ranks
as Local 500 in mid-1956, which itself flouted a
CLC agreement to negotiate the eventual home of thymine
he former OBU unions, the Union now had a base of
operations from which they could organi
ze other workers in the Prairies.
55
In charge of this programme of
“ Western development ” was the newly-appointed Western Director, Bud Henderson.
56
Initially centred upon
organizing Saskatchewan hospital workers, the campai
gn brought NUPSE into direct conflict with both
208 57
S. Little, letter to NUPSE National Executive Board, May 30,
1957: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 7, File 2]
58
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, June 22, 1957.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 6, File 4]
59
Lenihan, 192-3.
NUPE and the Building Service Employees International Union ( BSEIU ). The CLC was obviously antagonized by NUPSE ’ second activities as good. According
to Little’s report on the CLC Advisory Board Meeting
in May 1957, “ certain officials of the Congress … ar
e not in accord with [NUPSE’s] doings and will oppose”
attempts to organize western hospital locals.
57
By June, the CLC was accusing NUPSE of raiding several
locals of provincial psychiatric hospital workers,
up to now members of the Union of Saskatchewan Civil
Servants ( USCS ).
58
A more permanent wave resolution of these tensions was obviously needed. At post here was more than NUPSE ’ south survival, aluminum
though that was certainly foremost in Little’s
mind. besides underlying these disputes about jurisdiction were conflicting notions about the kind of unionism which would take hold and become dominant in the C
anadian public sector. We have already explored in
chapter 2 the reasons why many of NUPSE ’ s founding
locals departed from the IBEW’s craft model of
unionism. similarly, BSEIU ’ s approach to labour-management relations was baffling for both NUPE and NUPSE leaders. Organizing cleaning staff in privat
e (Catholic) hospitals and separate school boards,
BSEIU was seen as a collaborator and staff-run uni
on which set up “sweetheart” unions and contracts in
collusion with management. The rivalries between NUPE and BSEIU in Alberta had led Pat Lenihan to conclude that BSEIU ’ s “ Canadian leadership was very
reactionary” and had the effect of keeping public
sector wages and combativeness down, encouraging identification with the employer, and impeding the development of working class consciousness more by and large.
59
While Little did not share Lenihan’s explicit
classify analysis, he no doubt worried about how the pres
ence of a non-militant union in the hospital worker
legal power would affect the exploitation of consequence
ive public sector unionism. Similar concerns no doubt
applied to the civil service associations like USCS,
who had jurisdiction over direct provincial government
employees and institutions and were hush widely regarded as company unions engaged in ‘ collective
209 60
S. Little, letter to NUPSE National Executive Board, July 22,
1957: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 7, File 2]
begging ’. In other words, there were substant
ive motivations for NUPSE (and NUPE) to pursue
organization of hospital workers beyond the simple desire for expansion. Under the auspices of the CLC, Public
Sector Jurisdiction Committee meetings began in
December 1956 to sort out who should be doing what wi
th respect to Western hospital workers. It took
until the summer of 1957 before the CLC had negotia
ted a one-year Memorandum of Understanding
between the BSEIU, NUPSE and NUPE on the publish of ju
risdiction in the hospital sector. In this
agreement, NUPSE and NUPE were to refrain from organizing in “ certain types of hospitals except in Saskatchewan ”, for one year ; meanwhile, BSEIU and NUPE
were to withdraw from the current campaigns
NUPSE was running in Saskatchewan hospitals. The specific logic behind this allocation is not clear, except that it would eliminate the want for worker
s to choose between more than one union, a situation
which Little obviously favoured.
60
It besides is not clear how successful this agreem
ent was: competitive organizing continued despite
the divvying up of turf by home leaders in the A
ugust Memorandum. In 1957, as NUPE’s new full-time
western representative, Lenihan was successfully or
ganizing locals in Winnipeg after the loss of the
Winnipeg Civic Federation to NUPSE. To Lenihan, it onl
y seemed fair to continue to organize given that
NUPSE had not respected the agreement
regarding the disposition of the OBU unions. In response,
Lenihan began using his old OBU contacts to sign up Winnipeg school control panel workers, the Selkirk civil employees and the Winnipeg Children ’ s Hospital.
This last endeavour crossed the line and directly
challenged the August Memorandum. Lenihan recounted that
210 61
Lenihan, 188.
62
The Saskatchewan Federation of Public
Employees was the precursor to
the Saskatchewan Division of CUPE.
63
NUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 22-23, 1958: 6. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 4, File 6 ]
64
Lenihan, 184.
We flush got into one of the locals that was aluminum
ready supposed to be with NUPSE. I’m invited there
and I spoke to them at a big meet. The result of
it was that they came unanimously to us. We passed
the cards out and got them signed up. After the meeting, I came second to my hotel. I phoned Rintoul and I made a report, telling him what I was doing, what we were
accomplishing. ‘Well, I’m not so sure, Pat, that we
should do that, ’ and this kind of talk. The next night I get a phone call from the president,
from Buss: ‘This violates everything. Give
them back their cards. Drop it. ’ I was on the ve
rge of quitting because if we had gone back, we’d have got
more. That was a death shove off to us in Winnipeg. That was Bob Rintoul.
61
This was no bare personality conflict, however ; at stak
e was the capacity of a National Director to enforce
on playing field staff an already-floundering nationally-negotia
ted agreement. Rintoul, concerned with the need to
preserve whatever good will existed with NUPSE and
the CLC leadership, also had to be seen to be in
control of the decisions over what groups NUPE woul
d organize. Otherwise, if staffers like Lenihan could
unilaterally undertake such initiatives, Rintoul
would have little credibility in future negotiations.
contest in the field continued, however.
A letter from the Saskatchewan Federation of Public
Employees
62
to the March 1958 NUPE NEB meeting point
ed out that “the methods used by NUPSE
representatives in obtaining Congress locals,
were not conducive to bringing about a Merger.”
63
These
conflicts coloured the 1958 NUPE Convention. In
his speech to the delegates, Bill Buss, now NUPE
President after Lenihan accepted a staff position as fi
eld representative in the Prairies in January 1957,
64
explained that “ acrimonious struggles ” had occurred th
rough 1957-58 which had “emanated over jurisdiction”,
despite the Agreement in force during this period.
Buss insisted that “[d]isputes have arisen because of
try raids. In most cases these disputes were
ironed out, others still remain.” While not forthcoming
with the details of these disputes, Buss was clear
on NUPE’s role in them: “[A]t no time was our National
Union creditworthy for these disagreements. We have
protected our membership but remained faithful to
the memo of understanding. ” As a result of the
failure to demarcate the territory, Buss pointed out
211 65
NUPE, 1958 Convention Proceedings: 1, 4. CUPE F
onds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 2, File 9]
66
The NUPSE NEB decided to withdraw from
the Agreement at their June 20
th
, 1958 meeting. They r
eaffirmed this decision at
their September 19
th
, 1958 meeting, explicitly rejecting a request from
Joe MacKenzie of the CLC to renew the agreement.
When the CLC convened a meet in March 1959 in another attack to renew the agreemen
t, neither NUPE nor NUPSE was
will to continue the arrangement ( NUPSE,
National Executive Board minutes, April
24, 1959 : 2. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 6, File 5 ] ). No subsequent agreement on hospita
l jurisdiction was reached in t
he period before CUPE’s emergence.
67
OHEU, Executive Board Report to Council
of Chief Stewards, November 11, 1957: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol. 7, File 11 ] 68
J.R. Walker, “Report of Meeting on Jurisdiction and Unity
between OHEU and NUPSE”, April 20, 1959: 2-3. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 3 ] 69
K. Cummings, “Joint Coordination Co
mmittee meeting between Local 1000 (OHE
U) and NUPSE”, minutes, January 21, 1958:
1. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 11 ] that NUPE would likely have to fight for changes in the hospital legal power.
65
Perhaps most indicative of the
Agreement ’ s insufficiency was both NUPE and NUPSE ’ s refusal to renew it in August of 1958.
66
undoubtedly, this ongoing direct conflict betw
een NUPSE and NUPE, and the inability to resolve
differences or cooperate efficaciously, did not build mu
ch good will at the level of the membership or the
leadership. NUPSE ’ s conflicts with the CLC over the allow
jurisdiction for provincial public sector workers
besides had serious immediate and long-run consequences
. By the fall of 1957, NUPSE was meeting with
employees of the Manitoba Hydro-
Electric Board, and by fall of 1958 with workers from three of
Saskatchewan ’ s provincial psychiatric hospitals. Thes
e groups were ‘problematic’ due to their status as
employees of provincial rather than municipal agencies.
The CLC’s literature on Public Sector Jurisdiction
indicated that they envisioned “ three National Organizati
ons for the three levels of government – Municipal,
Provincial and Federal. ”
67
Direct federal and provincial employees were the realm of civil service
associations, while rights to organize municipal empl
oyees, including municipally controlled hospitals, were
schism between NUPE, NUPSE, IBEW and BSEIU. A signific
ant grey area existed with respect to employees
of politics commissions and crown corporations, as
the CLC recognized all the unions in the field up to
this point.
68
thus neither the Saskatchewan or Manitoba
groups belonged in the CLC’s vision of NUPSE (or
CUPE for that topic ) as a union of municipal workers.
69
212 70
This interpretation is belied by the CLC’s willingness to grant pr
ovincial Civil Service Associations affiliation when many sti
ll had
condescension for the organized labor drift. 71
K. Cummings, “Joint Coordi
nation Committee meeting”, 2.
This narrow view of CUPE ’ s future legal power has
several possible explanations. Possibly, given
OHEU ’ s special condition, the CLC feared NUPSE woul
d not require new provincial employee groups to
become entire members of the labor movement
and insist on their becoming “real unions”.
70
As well, with the
CLC dominated by U.S.-based unions at the time, it could be that the interests of international unions like the IBEW and BSEIU were being protected. If NUPSE
or CUPE were given exclusive jurisdiction over
populace utility program workers, for example, the IBEW would be left to organize in the a lot smaller individual construction trades. A longer-term strategy may have been
at work, as would be Little’s interpretation later
in the 1970s when the emergence would resurface : the CLC may have been attempting to place limits on future membership and restrict the emergence of what was to
become the largest union in Canada, and a threat to the
political influence of the US-based puerto rico
ivate sector unions in the CLC. Finally, the CLC leadership may have
been content to see union structures and identities passively reflect employers ’ organizational decisions, which brought them into conflict with populace sector
union leaders who were working with broader identities in
mind. More pressingly, the CLC ’ randomness position had implications for NUPSE ’ s existing membership. A joint meet of OHEU and NUPSE leaders deem
ed “the present situation in the
Province of Manitoba … a vital
one to the future of NUPSE ” and thus committed to ta
king “all necessary steps” to secure the entry of
Manitoba Power Commission employees into NUPSE.
71
Important questions motivated and hung over this
decisiveness : if these workers were to be defined out
of NUPSE’s jurisdiction, what would be the status of
OHEU, itself a body of provincial workers ? If OHEU
was allowed to remain in NUPSE, what would happen
to them as an isolated group of provincial workers
in a sea of municipal workers? How long could OHEU
cling to their special condition in this context ? How
would this situation affect OHEU’s obligation to “extend
213 72
K. Munnings, letter to K. Cummings and OHEU Executive Board,
October 15, 1957: 6. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol. 7, File 11 ] 73
K. Cummings, Merger Report – NUPSE-NUPE
– to OHEU Executive Board, Decem
ber 12, 1957: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc.
MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 11 ] 74
R. Rintoul, Merger Report to the 1958 NUPE Convention: 3-4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG
28 I234 Vol. 2, File 9]. Interestingly,
little and Rintoul ’ s respective interpretations of this meet
couldn’t be more different. While
Rintoul clearly indicated that NUPE
was unwilling to help in NUPSE ’ randomness battles, and that their committee
was frustrated with being drawn into these problems, Little
wrote to the NUPSE NEB that their presentation “ was well rece
ived” by the NUPE delegation (S. Little, letter to NUPSE National
Executive Board, July 9, 1958 : 1. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5 File 10 ] ). constitution to the unorganized within the established ju
risdiction” if that established jurisdiction no longer
included workers ‘ like ’ themselves ? If OHEU was rest
ricted to NUPSE, but separated from other provincial
hydro workers, what kind of political
options would they have if discontent
ed with either its present or future
national union ? A gain reply on the place of provincial workers, and OHEU specifically, within NUPSE, was thus urgently needed – particularly vitamin a far as OHEU
leaders were concerned – before any fruitful merger
talks could continue.
72
The following three fusion meetings, in December
1957, June 1958 and April 1959, were as a result
dominated – some in NUPE would have said hijacked – by discussions of NUPSE ’ s jurisdictional problems. At the December 1957 meeting, NU
PSE representatives began by insist
ing on a clarification of the
jurisdiction as defined in the CLC Merger Proposal, re
iterating that their jurisdiction for non-civil servant
provincial employees under the CCL would have to
be retained in any new organization. As Cummings
reported, this was emphasized due to “ recent information
rmation regarding the Manitoba Power Commission’s
employees … conveyed to them by … [ CLC Presi
dent] Jodoin.” CLC Vice-President Cushing was able to
convert NUPSE to move the discussion to a desperate
ct meeting between them and the CLC Executive
Board.
73
Evidently unsatisfied with the results of that
meeting, NUPSE continued to urge NUPE to side with
them on jurisdictional questions before agreeing to amalgamation
terms. As shortsighted as this may seem, the
NUPE committee refused, as the jurisdictions under quarrel were not partially of NUPE ’ s field.
74
Rather than
see the expansion of legal power as serving the long-
term interests of the union and public sector workers,
NUPE focussed on the short-run terror such a change
posed to their position in the merged union. The
214 75
R. Rintoul, Merger Report to the 1959 NUPE Convention: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 2, File 10]
76
Ibid., 1-2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 2, File 10]; R. Rintoul, “Brief Resume of Merger Meeting,” April 20th, 1959:
1-3. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 25 ] NUPE delegating concluded that amalgamation talks
had been postponed not because of NUPSE’s volume of
negotiations ( as had been claimed by Little ), but because of
their attempts to alter
their jurisdiction in ways
that would shift the balance of office in the amalgamation talks. No doubt they resented being commandeered in NUPSE ’ s attempts to expand its oscilloscope. Tensions around NUPSE ’ sulfur solicitation of NUPE ’ s suppor
t in these struggles came to a head at the
April 1959 fusion meet. Intended as a forum
to discuss the draft CUPE constitution reviewed by
Rintoul and Little in Niagara Falls the previ
ous month, the meeting bogged down as the NUPSE
representatives again insisted that
“the question of the jurisdiction of the proposed merged organization
would have to be defined before any fusion could take place. ”
75
The NUPE Committee’s position was that
fusion should come before any discussion of jurisdicti
on, but agreed “in the interests of unity” to NUPSE’s
request. Over the course of the following two hours, both
unions put forward their views on jurisdiction, and the
CLC representatives, Claude Jodoin and Henry Rhodes,
made a commitment to bringing the matter before
the CLC Executive Council. When the delegates last moved on to what wa
s meant to be the main substance of the
discussion, the gulp constitution, the NUPE Committ
ee was in for a rude shock. Despite the agreement
reached between Little and Rintoul on the draft, NUPSE
proposed a long list of changes, most of which
were unacceptable to NUPE. then, with identical fiddling
discussion of merger having taken place, NUPSE broke
off the meet, despite NUPE ’ mho expectation of two days of talks for which they had planned and scheduled. The NUPE representatives were frankincense “ v
ery disappointed with the NUPSE merger committee”,
their feel of being used by NUPSE in
its struggle with the CLC exacerbated.
76
215 77
Jack Raysbrook was a Hamilton hospital worker, member of
Local 167, and according to Lenihan, “one of the most advanced
thinkers of the bunch together ” ( Lenihan, 176 ). 78
Reports of Officers, 1959 NUPE Convention: 2, 7, 9.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 2, File 10]
79
R. Rintoul, Merger Report to the 1959 NUPE Convention: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28 I234 Vol. 2, File 10]
The September 1959 NUPE Convention heard an earfu
l from several members of the merger
committee on this debacle. Bill Buss, Tom Lewis and Jack Raysbrook
77
all gave quite pessimistic accounts of the condition of negotiations. Buss
reported that the Memo
randum of Understanding on
jurisdictions had failed and that “ none of the Unions involved are prepared to waive this legal power with obedience to hospitals. ” Both Buss and Lewis agr
eed that merger would not go ahead until the CLC made
decisions regarding NUPSE ’ s jurisdictional problems,
and that it would be “useless” to continue with
meetings until then. besides provoking indignation
were NUPSE’s four pages of constitutional amendments,
which for Raysbrook amounted to the impossible “ submergence of NUPE into NUPSE.. ”
78
Strangely,
Rintoul was quite more affirmative than his colleague
committee members, though on what basis is unclear.
He reported that while not much progress had been made in the last year on amalgamation, he was of the opinion that “ the prospects of early success in this matter are
somewhat better that they were at this time last
class. ”
79
The exsert struggles over jurisdiction did not s
eem to produce results which were worth the loss
of NUPE ’ s commodity will. By the goal of 1959, the CLC had not
altered its muddled conception of public sector
jurisdiction, nor had NUPSE agreed to limit itself to the areas delineated for it. NUPSE continued to pursue the affiliation of big groups of public sector workers, wherever they were to be found, and held onto an expansive vision of a union which would one day include
both direct and indirect provincial employees.
NUPSE ’ mho request for greater numbers and power at the
merger bargaining table was not particularly
successful either : though several large groups had
been added to their union, the time and resources
wasted in fighting other unions and the CLC, and the fa
ilure to organize new groups of workers as NUPE
was, kept NUPSE in second space. The continued ambiguity regarding OHEU ’ randomness position within populace sector
216 unionism besides fuelled a serious internal dispute triiodothyronine
hat was to eat up the NUPSE leadership’s time and energy
and delay build up on fusion until well into 1960. III.
OHEU and the Entrenchment of Autonomy
While NUPSE was struggling to expand its setting to compete more effectively with NUPE in the amalgamation talks, some of those already within its gas constant
anks clung to a more narrow identity and sought to continue
the structural arrangements which reflected this. As
discussed in Chapter 4, OHEU’s entry into NUPSE
was unconventional, particularly given the latter ’ sulfur centralist tendencies. This deviation from Little ’ s vision of a potent cardinal union was a hardheaded accommodati
on to the need to expand in order to survive the
creation of the CLC. indeed, rapid expansion had becom
e so important to NUPSE that little care was being
taken to amply integrate new groups into the
union, and arrangements were being made which served to
continue new groups ’ smell of peculiarity. OH
EU in particular was exempted by necessity from
NUPSE ’ s earlier centralist methods of forging a park one
dentity, and the issue of fu
ll geomorphologic and cultural integration was deferred indefinitel
y. However, this choice soon came back to haunt Little and other
NUPSE leaders, as it introduced an impor
tant element of disunity within the union, particularly over the
questions of identity and solidarity, reciprocal responsib
ilities and obligations, and the locus of decision-making
power. OHEU ’ s enduring sectionalism was rooted in its origins as a separate constitution outside of NUPSE and based on a narrow-minded understand of who constitu
ted one’s ‘fellow workers’, which led them to
advocate structural arrangements which would keep fi
nancial resources and decision-making at the local
tied. On a hardheaded horizontal surface, OHEU ’ s reserve
meant NUPSE had insufficient funds to pursue the organizing
and servicing of new members, putting them in a re
latively disadvantageous position vis-à-vis other unions
in the field and in a deficit position internally.
On a deeper level, however, OHEU’s approach challenged
217 80
Power Workers’ Union, 17.
attempts to build broader forms of solidarity and struct
ures which would reinforce a more expansive identity
( like the redistribution of resources and the creation of common governing institutions ). The baffling nature of OHEU ’ sulfur stead
within NUPSE was raised by NUPE, the CLC
leadership, CLC affiliates like the IBEW, and NUPSE locals
like Local 1, who felt resentful of a group with
privileges which they could not besides enjoy. In light
of these constant external and internal pressures,
NUPSE leaders had to walk a preferably ticket line, attempting to balance OHEU ’ s needs with the requirements of fusion. As a result, from the begin of thousand
ger talks in 1956, OHEU’s extensive autonomy was a
major obstacle, both to further NUPSE expansion and to amalgamation with NUPE. As previously discussed, the NUPE amalgamation committ
ee felt from the outset that OHEU influence on
talks was excessive, and the local ’ south imperativeness on thymine
he continuation of special status within the new
organization was unacceptable. Since NUPE distinctly gr
anted its own locals significant independence, it was
not the
fact
of autonomy but its
extent
which was at issue: the formal exemption of the OHEU from
decisions made by the national convention and executiv
e board meant they were not really “part of the
union ” and hence were a source of weakness. As we
have already seen, NUPE made it plain to the CLC
that it was “ unwilling to extend the like independence to
the OHEU, no matter what its size or power”, and
that something had to be done about OHEU if the fusion was to be concluded.
80
pressure from other sources besides motivated
NUPSE leaders to renegotiate their relationship with
OHEU. The issue was brought to NUPSE ’ s attention
in early 1957 through some pointed prodding from the
CLC. At a meeting with the CLC executive in Marc
h of that year, Little and Cummings were informed that
“ one other interested Union is soliciting the support of affiliate Organizations to say that one large section of our membership positively will not commit themselves to meet the needs of a National Organization. ” furthermore, this campaign was not only “ gaining sympat
hy among the affiliates” of the CLC, but also
218 81
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, April 27, 1957: 3.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 4]
82
OHEU, “Executive Board Report to Council of Chief Stewar
ds Concerning our Relationshi
p with NUPSE”, November 11, 1957:
1. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 11 ] “ causing considerable disagreement among certain of
our major Locals” who were “being urged and coached
by resistance representatives. ”
81
Although the instigating union is not directly named in Little’s typically
cryptic minutes, there is little question that the refe
rence here is to the IBEW, whose antagonism to OHEU’s
affiliation to NUPSE was well known throughout the parturiency
movement at the time. As evidence for the
claim that OHEU was not actually share of NUPSE, the IBEW pointed to their highly low per head. As such, the IBEW argued, OHEU wasn ’ t truly par
t of the labour movement, but rather engaged in a
‘ security racket ’ with NUPSE to avoid being part of a ‘ real ’ union and having to fulfil its responsibilities to their boyfriend workers. Although the initial a
rrangement between NUPSE and OHEU did indeed have the
former receiving no actual per capita tax from its fresh
affiliate, this situation changed with the creation of the
CLC. The modern federation set its per head at
7 cents (less than the CCL’s),and OHEU agreed the
remaining 3 cents could remain with NUPSE in
order to assist with organizing the unorganized.
82
Read more: Clint Barton (Marvel Cinematic Universe)
however, the IBEW was pointing to a real reti
cence on the part of OHEU to engage itself in NUPSE and
the labor bowel movement. The strategy behind the IBEW ’ s attempts to provoke changes to the NUPSE-OHEU musical arrangement was most probable based on its hope that
OHEU’s trenchant commitment to autonomy would
prevent them from accepting the st
atus of a ‘regular’ local in NUPSE,
force them from the marriage, and make them vulnerable to a renewed drive to
capture at least a portion of them.
additionally, Toronto Hydro Local 1, alluded to in
Little’s report to the NUPSE Executive, was the
informant of much of the internal protest over OHEU ’ s particular condition. little attributed their criticisms to the IBEW ’ s cover determine over some Toronto Hydr
o members, but Local 1 had their own reasons to
begrudge OHEU. local 1, with a longstanding and dist
inct identity based on their original status but now
pushed from its once dominant put in part by
OHEU, saw itself as similarly self-servicing but
219 83
S. Little, letter to W. Dodge, January 14, 1959: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 3]; J.R. Walker, “Report of
Meeting on Jurisdiction and Unity ”, 4. 84
OHEU, Executive Board minutes, May 31, 1957: 11. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 8]
85
S. Little, “The Director’s Report”,
NUPSE News
1 (12): 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol 3, File 25]
unfairly denied the like fiscal and political autonom
y as the newcomers. Moreover, as previously
discussed, local anesthetic 1 besides held strong commitments to
broader organizing within the public utility sector,
evidenced by their cardinal function in the creation of CETU, NOCUEW and NUPSE. As a resultant role, the exemption of the larger and more affluent OHEU from the s
hared cost of organizing and supporting other public sector
workers rankled and was seen as selfish and unsolidaristi
c. Local 1’s discontent was to become evident at
the 1959 and 1960 NUPSE Conventions, where they were deoxythymidine monophosphate
he sponsors of several thinly veiled anti-OHEU
resolutions. little himself was besides dysphoric with the placement with OHEU, which was apparent in his approach with early locals. He always saw deoxythymidine monophosphate
he Agreement of Understanding as a short-term and
transitional accommodation to present realities wh
ich would eventually be eliminated through education of
the OHEU membership by its leaders.
83
OHEU was thus contradictory for Little: while in the abstract it fit
into his vision of a larger and more herculean union, in reality it impeded the devel
opment of a “truly national”
and centrally directed one, and did not produce the kind
of financial resources needed to fuel the campaign
for “ Western Development ” immediately afoot.
84
Little was also keenly aware that the dissension caused by
OHEU was standing in the way of consummating the fusion. In his 1959
NUPSE News
report, Little
diagnosed the bankruptcy to conclude talks as due to “ the in
ternal differences of opinion in both Unions and the
miss of joined purpose. ” He went on to suggest that
“unless we are prepared to solve these problems and
clear the decks for advancement toward Merger, we w
ill not only be dishonest with ourselves but remiss in
our duty and duty to the membership we represent. ”
85
These ‘internal problems’ no doubt referred
to the implications of OHEU ’ s especial condition in NU
PSE. The pressure of the requirements for merger was
220 86
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, April 27, 1957: 3.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 4]
87
OHEU, Executive Board minutes, May 31, 1957: 11, 12. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 8]
frankincense a useful guise for Little to pursue concessions
from OHEU which he desired but could not secure in
normal circumstances. therefore, while in 1956 the NUPSE fusion committee s
eemed content to defer to representatives of
the holocene yet knock-down summation to their organization, by
1957 a significant internal shift had taken place. At
the NUPSE NEB ’ s April 1957 meet, Little argued that
both the CLC’s ambivalence regarding provincial
workers ’ legal power and the relationship between NUPSE and OHEU were causing a crisis which required a unclutter resolution before the fall 1957 Convention. Littl
e and Cummings were to continue to meet with the
CLC over the jurisdictional interview, but more im
portantly, the NUPSE NEB passed a remarkable motion
which was to set off a chain of conflicts, negotiations, motions and counter-motions that would consume the Union until 1960. Little was directed to “ advise the OHEU Executive Board of these developments and solicit the removal of the written restrictions in
order to preserve our united Organization and to encourage
their full and unreserved digest in thymine
he over-all policy and program” of NUPSE.
86
This newspeak meant that
Little was to request the elimination of the
1955 Agreement of Understanding between OHEU and NUPSE,
and that OHEU was to become a local like any other
with the same political and financial obligations.
little ’ south discussions with the OHEU executive in former May 1957 argue that his initial willingness to find a solution that would both ‘ satisfy the critics ’
and retain the essence of t
he Agreement of Understanding
and the autonomy it afforded OHEU. The tax, as
Little saw it, was to revise the Agreement of
Understanding such that it would “ intelligibly indicate to all concerned that the OHEU was unmistakably separate and parcel of NUPSE and prepared to assume its respons
ibilities as part of a truly national union”, while
besides ensuring that the new arrangement would “ cost the OHEU no more than was presently being paid. ”
87
In
other words, Little hoped a cosmetic switch would be sufficient to ward off the CLC and IBEW and to remove the obstacles to amalgamation as NUPE saw them .
221 88
Ibid., 12.
For its part, the OHEU administrator, led by Kealey Cummings, was caught between a rock and a hard station on this issue. They recognized that, given t
heir perceptions of the OHEU membership’s attitudes,
they could neither increase their fiscal obbligato
ons to NUPSE nor withdraw from the Union and risk the
IBEW foray into that would inescapably result. however,
replacing the formal Agreem
ent of Understanding with a de facto
and unwritten arrangement would make them vul
nerable to any future centralizing moves on
NUPSE ’ second ( or the future CUPE ’ second ) part. Despite the
unpalatable choices offered by circumstances, the
OHEU executive committed to meeting with NUPSE repres
entatives to determine “the future position of this
Union. ”
88
As OHEU leaders began meeting amongst themselves to settle on a scheme for dealing with the NUPSE request, it was cursorily apparent that no substantial agreement existed within the local. Two chief positions emerged on OHEU ’ s future relationship to
NUPSE. There were those who agreed with Little and
argued that OHEU would have to make some concessions in the
form
of the arrangement set out in the
agreement of Understanding, while retaining the
substance
of the autonomy provided to them. Adherents
to this view proposed a switch to a per caput rebat
e system, in which OHEU would appear to be paying full
per capita but would regularly receive an sum in
lieu of servicing back from the NUPSE national office.
Kealey Cummings, as President of OHEU and one of
its main representatives on the NUPSE NEB, seems
to have been a main advocate of this more pragmatic po
ition. This was consistent with Cummings’ more
expansive sense of OHEU ’ south identity and function in the labor movement : for him, one in the labor movement was of primary importance, and one
ndependent unions were “freeloaders” which weakened that
movement. furthermore, OHEU in especial “ had a res
ponsibility to sacrifice as far as possible and at the
222 89
OHEU, Executive Board minutes, August 21,
1957: 10; December 16, 1957: 6. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7,
File 8 ] 90
The structural relationship between the tw
o bodies belied this argument. Clearly, NU
PSE was formally the superordinate entity
in the kinship, with OHEU representatives on its decision-making bodies, but not six
ce versa. Moreover, as OHEU formed a
powerful ( if not prevailing ) bloc in the contex
t of Convention, they could in some respects “tell NUPSE what to do” in a way that
NUPSE couldn ’ thymine given the Agreement of Understanding. 91
Interestingly, this was exactly the position of the IBEW
which fuelled so much of their criticism of the NUPSE-OHEU
arrangement. 92
K. Munnings, letter to K. Cummings and OHEU Executive Board,
October 15, 1957: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol. 7, File 11 ] 93
OHEU and NUPSE, “Agreement of Under
standing”, Appendix D, Coordinating Co
mmittee minutes, January 30-31, 1958: 16.
CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 11 ] lapp time provide leadership with the object of
realizing a strong national union for all public utility
workers. ”
89
Others argued that any alteration of the Ag
reement of Understanding would constitute an
impossible suppression of OHEU ’ s autonomy. The basis
for this view was a particular interpretation of
the entail of ‘ affiliation ’ : quite than havi
ng been submerged into NUPSE, OHEU had affiliated to
NUPSE as an equal, a partner in a mutually beneficial
arrangement that involved
neither telling the other
what to do.
90
As a result, NUPSE’s demand that the Ag
reement of Understanding be set aside was
bastard : as an actual ‘ fusion ’ had never taken place, its terms would still have to be negotiated with OHEU.
91
Consequently, NUPSE’s merger talks with NUPE,
which had precipitated this crisis in their
kinship with OHEU, had been wrongly entered into as the Union had not finished “ setting its own house in order through direct negotiations
with the OHEU Executive Board.”
92
A NUPE-NUPSE merger was
debatable because its terms would be binding on OHEU, an unacceptable consequence given their autonomous status : the Agreement
of Understanding clearly stated t
hat OHEU was “not committed to
accept or assume any undertaking other than those
over which they themselves have complete and
absolute restraint. ”
93
Therefore, not only did these OHEU parti
sans insist on the right to determine what
relationship they would have with NUPSE, they besides
insisted on a similar veto on the merger talks with
NUPE. Ken Munnings, OHEU ’ s First Vice-President, wa
s a primary spokesperson for these more hard-line
223 94
Murray later became OHEU second vice-president
between 1969-1971, and first vice-president in 1972.
95
K. Munnings, “The Responsibility is Yours!” 1.
96
OHEU, Executive Board minutes, November
11, 1957: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 8]. Consequently,
the comparable amendments designed to modi
fy the OHEU constitution and due to be
presented at the 1957 Council of Chief Stewards were dropped, as the union ’ s legal
advisor David Lewis indicated they “will not
do the job [they] wanted them to do” i
n
any font. ideas, as were James Hook and Bert Murray
94
of the OHEU’s Unity Committee. Munnings’ definition of
autonomy, “ the mighty to conduct our clientele in a washington
y which … the member decides we should” was
cover by a democratic rationale, but one in which thyroxine
he community of citizens with the legitimate right
to make decisions was restricted to the boundaries of OHEU.
95
What Little and OHEU leaders like
Cummings possibly did not anticipate was how refractory deoxythymidine monophosphate
hese sections of the OHEU would be in their
resistor to modifying the Agreement of
Understanding in even a superficial way.
In the context of these emerging differences
, the OHEU Constitution and By-Laws Committee
however drew up a series of constitu
tional amendments, for both NUPSE’s September 1957
conventionality and the annual OHEU Council of Chief Stew
ards meeting in November, designed to address
the criticism of the 1955 Agreem
ent of Understanding. These thr
ee amendments did not resolve the
difficulties one amendment was defeated, another
amended and approved, and a third carried without
amendment.
96
unable to reach a resolution through the NUPSE Conv
ention, the OHEU’s Executive Board went to
the 1957 Council of Chief Stewards seeking authorizat
ion to pursue a negotiated settlement directly with
the NUPSE leadership. A joint Coordinating Committee ( JCC ), consisting of OHEU and NUPSE representatives, was established to meet and discuss their kinship. The OHEU ’ s delegates were charged with the take after goals : “ to legally and functi
onally create the framework that will maintain all
existing membership rights for both parties ”, to secure
that OHEU would continue to service itself, decide
on the kind and level of service, set the count and di
sposition of their own staff “and bear all costs for
same ”, and to “ guarantee the democratic production of
a budget for the National Organization which will
224 97
Ibid., 4.
98
McNaughton was second vice-president in 1955, when
the group first joined NUPSE and became the OHEU.
99
OHEU Executive Board, letter to NUPSE Executive Board (first
draft), November 8, 1957: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 7, File 11 ] 100
K. Cummings, Joint Coordination Committee meeting betw
een Local 1000 (OHEU) and NUPSE, minutes, January 21, 1958: 2.
CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 11 ] indicate the degree of duty for all parties toward the costs of organizing the unorganized in the populace employee field. ”
97
In other words, OHEU’s aim was to define and quantify in very precise terms its
obligations to early workers while retaining the
maximum amount of autonomy for itself. The OHEU’s
part of the JCC, consisting of William McNaughton
98
( as president ), Ken Munnings, and Ernie Sutton ( with Cummings
ex officio
), was mandated to report to the 1958 Council of Chief Stewards with
recommendations. One of the foremost acts of the JCC
was to request, along with the OHEU Executive Board,
that “ stream integrity talks with the National Union of
Public Employees be held in abeyance until our internal
problem is solved. ”
99
The better separate of 1958 was taken up with discussions of how the NUPSE fundamental law could be modified to achieve the delicate proportion between aut
onomy and unity sought by the OHEU Executive and
endorsed by the Council of Chief Stewards. It was conceded by all that, to achieve these ends, the agreement of Understanding would have to go, and
be replaced by changes to the NUPSE Constitution.
100
The OHEU fortune of the Committee took it upon itse
lf to review the OHEU-NUPSE relationship and draw
up recommendations to be considered by both executives. Francis Eady, CCF partisan and then OHEU ’ south promotion and Education Officer and editor program of the
OHEU News
, was seconded to advise the OHEU
Coordinating Committee. Many of the documents of
this committee bear the stamp of Eady’s particular
views on the structures and functions appropr
iate to a national union and its affiliates.
The Committee established several significant princi
ples which they felt would have to guide the
constituent changes, but which in no way would resolv
e the impasse in merger talks with NUPE that the
procedure was initiated to break. The Committee determi
ned that, first, given the different administrative and
225 101
OHEU, Coordinating Committee minutes, Januar
y 30-31, 1958: 5, 6. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 11]
political requirements of a provincial employees
’ union, a national organization which encompassed both
municipal and peasant groups “ will not be able to hav
e a standard per capita for all chartered bodies”, as
had been decided at the December 1956 NUPSE-NUPE amalgamation
meeting. Second, as a result of the
impossibility of a standard per caput, a national st
ructure would have to be designed which guaranteed the
equal status of provincial unions and peasant federations of local unions. This structure “ would define equitable returns in service to all members. ” Provin
cial federations of local unions would have elected
officers and staff responsible for daily serv
icing, and would also be able to set up occupational
groups.
101
This regionalizing model would construct a parallel
provincial structure for local unions in order to
protect OHEU from future claims that it was receiv
ing a ‘special deal’ and attempts to demote it to ‘local’
status. OHEU was frankincense seeking to provide a legiti
mate basis for maintaining its distinct structure and
identity, with its different responsibilities to the national union, so as to undermine the criticisms or similar claims of other locals like local 1. Issues of fi
nancing and the relative responsibility of each level of the
union for organizing the unorganized were left aside for the consequence. however, it was precisely the question of money
– how much and controlled by whom – that would
widen the divisions inside OHEU. These differences we
re expressed in two versions of the relationship
between the still-hypothetical provinci
al federations and the national union, which were hashed out at the
OHEU Executive Board in August 1958. The majority, led by Cummings and Eady, argued that in order to minimize diversion from current arrangements and
increase the likelihood of NUPSE’s acceptance, per
caput should continue to be remitted immediately to NUPSE,
which would fund the provincial federations with a
grant. This position was expressed in
Memo A
. The minority, led by Ken Munnings and Ernie Sutton of the
JCC, argued for
Memo B
, which proposed that provincial federat
ions of local unions should collect dues
immediately from locals and remit per head to t
he national office. This independence would mirror the
226 102
E. Sutton and K. Munnings, “What About out Relationship to NU
PSE?” (Circular to OHEU Chief Stewards) n.d (fall 1958): 3.
CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 12 ] 103
NUPSE, 1958 Convention Proceedings: 14.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5, File 3]
104
Ibid., 20.
decentralization implicit in in the kinship between provincial unions like OHEU and the national union, to be preserved at all costs. Sutton and Munnings feared that the majority ’ s proposed arrangement would be a “ stepping stone ” for OHEU “ down to equal condition
with a Provincial Public Service Federation.”
102
Expressing a chasten autonomist positi
on, the OHEU Executive Board approved
Memo A
,
lead Munnings, one of the main hard-line autonomy praseodymium
oponents, to resign from the JCC. Furthermore,
having spent therefore much time sorting out the solu
tion to the NUPSE-OHEU problem, the JCC found their
progress blocked by a schedule error. Bound by their
terms of reference to present their findings to the
November Council of Chief Stewards meet first, the JCC could not prepare constituent amendments for the 1958 NUPSE Convention being held in October, resulting in another
year
of delay.
Without OHEU ’ sulfur proposed solution, a vacuum therefore existed in the broad union. With no clear management from the national leadership on how to create
the internal conditions for renewed merger talks, the
1958 NUPSE Convention was thus given over to anti-OHEU resolutions which sought to eliminate their autonomy all in all, emanating
primarily from the Toronto Hydro lo
cal. Bill Baker and John Miller from
Toronto Hydro Local 1 crusade to have the especial
per capita provisions expunged from the Constitution,
arguing that the placement “ was det
rimental to the interests of t
he organization as a whole, and created
discord by permitting a local with full rights without broad responsibilities. ”
103
When this amendment was
defeated, Baker and Miller attempted to change the per c
apita tax for self-servicing locals to 50 cents
( alternatively of the 25-cent floor proposed by the NEB
and established by the Convention) and to transfer
OHEU ’ s servicing machinery to NUPSE.
104
While these initiatives also failed, the convention did signal to
the NEB that it wanted the Agreement of Understanding eliminated
and merger consummated. Also
significant were the lessons the leadership lambert
earned about the Convention process and who should be
227 105
OHEU Joint Coordinating Committee, “Progress Report to Council of Chief Stewards”, 1958: 4, 6. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG
28, I234, Vol. 7, File 12 ] 106
Ibid., 5-6.
permitted to take the precede. The absence of alternatives
from the leadership was polarizing, and allowing the
locals their point was seen as a ‘ tactical error ’. ‘ Democracy ’ could be fractious and inconvenient if not properly managed by the central leadership. Mo
reover, OHEU leaders learned the importance of
preventing the issue of their per capita tax from ever reaching the conventionality floor again. The Council of Chief Stewards a calendar month late was no less acrimonious. Since September, Munnings and Sutton had been working to mobilize mem
bers against the JCC’s recommendations for the
council of Chief Stewards meeting. Their criti
que was both substantive and
procedural: the potential
implications of “ Memo A ” for OHEU ’ s autonomy
were problematic, OHEU members were inadequately
informed of the negotiations process, and the OHEU Execut
ive Board taken insufficient time to consider the
options. Both autonomy and democratic summons were at emergence here. Compounding the furor was the watering down of t
he principles deemed central to resolving the
OHEU-NUPSE amalgamation in the Joint Coordinating Commi
ttee’s final report to the CCS, namely structures
which guaranteed adequate servicing, and no standard per deoxycytidine monophosphate
apita. A key change was the complete deletion of
the provincial federations marriage proposal,
preventing its consideration by the Chief Stewards. This concrete
proposal, over which there had been so much contro
versy, was replaced by Eady, Little and McNaughton
in their JCC report with a obscure commitment to loca
l autonomy and the formation of a joint sub-committee
to investigate a standard per caput, besides a key about-face of the earlier OHEU status.
105
Instead of making
substantive suggestions, the composition emphasized the “ likel
y alternatives” faced by OHEU if they did not
accept these indefinite promises and returned to an “ iso
lationist position”: “raiding from many directions”,
the end of aid from and access to CLC servic
es, and the weakening of its bargaining position with
the Hydro Commission.
106
In other words, Little and Eady were attempting to manage the OHEU
228 107
OHEU Joint Coordinating Committee, mi
nutes of meeting between Local 1000 (OHE
U) and NUPSE, November 7, 1958: 2.
CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 12 ] 108
“Our Relationship with NUPSE”,
OHEU News
3(2), January 1959: 4. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 3]
109
OHEU and NUPSE, “Agreement
of Understanding”, 16.
110
K. Cummings, K. Munnings and C. Gillies, letter to C. Jodoin,
November 26, 1958: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol. 7, File 3 ] membership with aroused appeals indeed as to obtain thyroxine
heir desired result: the approval of a full merger with
NUPSE. OHEU ’ s ‘ fantan ’ was offended by these stra
tagems, and Munnings and Sutton’s critique of the
JCC ’ randomness oeuvre received support in the context of a
democratic backlash against leadership manipulation.
Munnings and Sutton opposed the deletion of the provincial
federations proposal from consideration by the
CCS, even though it had been deemed the proper
subject of NUPE-NUPSE merger talks.
107
More
importantly, however, the Chief Stewards rejected the substitution of frighten tactics for concrete solutions and rational debate, and stated that, from the report card o
ffered, it could not determine what approach was
actually being taken on the issue of OHEU-NUPSE integrity.
108
The CCS thus terminated the JCC and
replaced it with a reconstituted, autonomous, and
even more autonomist ‘Unity Committee’, made up of
Brothers Bert Murray ( as president ), James Hook
and William McNaughton, whose mandate was to negotiate
directly with the Canadian Labour Congress. The Unity Committee ’ s mandate was premised on M
unnings’ idea that the OHEU was an “affiliate”
preferably than a local of NUPSE, and
therefore retained the right to
approach the CLC without going through
the national office. This interpretation was no
invention: the Agreement
of Understanding did indeed
commit to place the union “ within the CLC on a
full and equal status with any affiliated group”,
109
a
hardheaded musical arrangement whose contr
adictory implications were now coming to the fore. The OHEU
executive therefore sought lead meetings with President
Jodoin “to determine the CLC’s firm position … [on the
legal power of ] Provincial Unions of Di
rect and Indirect Governmental Employees.”
110
As pointed out earlier,
OHEU intelligibly wanted to determine whether furt
her negotiations with NUPSE would be worthwhile,
229 111
Ibid.
112
S. Little, letter to K. Cummings, December 12, 1958: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 3]
113
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes,
February 6, 1959: 4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 5]
specially if they were to be defined out of its ju
risdiction in a few years anyway. The CCS had demanded
these meetings and an answer to the question of jurisd
iction before any further merger talks with NUPSE,
let alone NUPE. The OHEU ’ south direct appeal to the CLC pushed its relationship with NUPSE to the brink, for it potently and publicly raised the motion of which body
was superordinate. NUPSE’s NEB was driven to
take a much harder line with OHEU than they had over
the past year of frustrating talks, and its response
was swift and forceful : both the approach to the CLC and the give voice used in OHEU ’ south request were deemed wholly unacceptable. The OHEU was illegitimately
circumventing the national office to gain direct
access to the CLC, and admitting in writing that
it had never “completely” merged with NUPSE.
111
In his
response to Cummings, Little emphasized the “ good
ramifications” for NUPSE’
s “[m]erger talks with
NUPE, our Manitoba Hydro political campaign and the Congr
ess attitude with regard to our Saskatchewan
developments ”, and worried that the letter could further l
egitimize IBEW raiding efforts, since “they will
surely home out of proportion emphas
is on the references made therein.”
112
This “indiscretion” had
bring things to “ a agile boil ”, and the NUPSE NEB did not fail to let the CLC know how they felt.
113
A
batch of letters and telegrams insisted that the CLC deny OHEU ’ randomness request for a meet. Of course, the return under competition was the
precise relationship between the two bodies, and
little ’ south attack to declare by decree
that OHEU was subordinate to NUPSE came to no avail. OHEU’s resolute
imperativeness on direct access to the CLC and the inapplic
ability of the NUPSE Constitution so frustrated the
NUPSE Executive that at its Febr
uary 1959 meeting they decided the ti
me for a negotiated settlement of
the line between autonomy and integrity was over. As of
March 1959, the Board was unilaterally terminating
230 114
Ibid., 5.
115
K. Cummings, letter to J. Clark, March 19, 1959: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 3]
116
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, April 24, 1959: 2.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 5]
the Agreement of Understanding and, in a
very purposeful change of language, declaring
Local 1000
a
local of NUPSE in accord with their constitution.
114
In the inadequate term, this decision produced a some
what more conciliatory attitude on OHEU’s part.
Shifting their position and implicitly acquiescing to
NUPSE’s view of their appropriate status, Cummings
asked NUPSE to request a meet with CLC repr
esentatives, an option proposed by Jodoin himself.
interestingly, OHEU ’ s approach mirrored NUPSE ’ second attitude in talks with NUPE, namely that “ the problem of future jurisdiction of CUPE must first be decided ” before a fusion could be consummated.
115
Though wary
of carrying on double negotiations regarding CUPE, NUPSE agreed to discuss the matter and set aside the deadline for end point of the Agreement of U
nderstanding, given the seeming willingness of OHEU
representatives “ to obtain from metric ton
heir membership a more acceptable method of solving our differences.”
116
however, the CLC-sponsored meet was an exercise
in further frustration. The two groups were
there with clearly different purposes, OHEU to discu
ss only the question of jurisdiction, NUPSE to explore
methods for eliminating the Agreement of Underst
anding. After a detailed explanation by CLC Vice-
President William Dodge, in which he
admitted that the CLC’s policy on t
he public utility sector was unclear,
OHEU was deemed part of NUPSE and consequently would be
part of CUPE. Moreover, Dodge indicated that
OHEU ’ sulfur passing from NUPSE would not be supported by
the CLC, as “the Congress did not consider
itself to be an underground dragoon by which groups may
separate themselves from units to which they
belong. ” Given this definitive commitment by the CLC fifty
eadership regarding OHEU’s stat
us (if not that of its
sector ), one would have expected the logjam had been
loosened. This was not so, however. Having had
their queries addressed, OHEU representatives were
absolutely unwilling to discuss possible methods for
eliminating the Agreement of
Understanding. Repeated questions by Dodge about the nature of OHEU’s
231 117
J.R. Walker, “Report of Meeting on Jurisdiction and Unity”, 3, 5.
118
R. Rintoul, “Brief Resume of Merger Meeting,” 1-3.
119
J.R. Walker, “Report of Meeti
ng on Jurisdiction and Unity”, 4-5.
120
OHEU, Executive Board minutes, August 21, 1957: 10. CUPE
Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 8]
121
H. Murray, E. Hook and W. McNaughton, “OHEU Unity Committee
Report to the Council of Chief Stewards”, October 1959: 3-
4. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 3 ] fears, the principles they wanted
recognized, and the compromises they might be willing to make were met
by stonewalling : the delegating invoked their democrati
c accountability to their membership, insisting that
they “ must follow rigid lines of procedure and at
this meeting did not have the authority to agree to
anything. ”
117
NUPSE leaders were hotly opposed to this approach, even though they themselves would
insist on the same jurisdictional clearness, and then refuse
to negotiate details, a mere four days later at the
NUPE-NUPSE amalgamation meet.
118
To up the ante, OHEU went on to indicate
that jurisdiction and autonomy were not its only
concerns : although they would not discuss the details
, they wanted a more thorough revision of the NUPSE
united states constitution as a condition of a renewed kinship.
119
OHEU’s sudden shift to a broader critique of
NUPSE ’ s structures pointed to underlying differences orange group
er union function and its relationship to structure,
until nowadays masked by the interrogate of autonomy and the des
ire to preserve the in
tegrity of a separate
residential district. OHEU ’ s reserve to become more
fully integrated into NUPSE was also informed by
disagreements over how union functions should be carr
ied out and by whom. In contrast to NUPSE’s
practice, Munnings claimed that OHEU “ firm believed
in retaining control in elected officers and not in
staff employees. ”
120
The relative status of NUPSE’s full-time National Director and part-time National
President was seen by the Unity Committee as particu
larly problematic and “contrary to one of the basic
principles of organization. ” The National Director
was both an employee and an officer of the union with the
veracious to vote at both the National Executive Board
and Council, while the National President’s powers were
developing and ill-defined, resulting in a staff-led union.
121
OHEU’s distrust of powerful staff was
reflected in their fear of losing their assets
and servicing machinery to an unaccountable, nationally-
232 122
J.R. Walker, “Report of NUPSE-OHEU Meeti
ng”, October 6, 1959: 1-2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 5]
123
Ibid., 2.
124
Power Workers’ Union, 22.
125
J. Lee, “Referendum to be held on remaining in NUPSE”,
OHEU News
, 4 (4), April 1960: 1, 4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 3, File 26 ] 126
J.R. Walker, “Report of NUPSE-OHEU Meeting”, 3-4.
127
K. Cummings, letter to S. Little, June 8, 1959: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 4]
appointed administrator or trustee shoul
d they ever decide to leave NUPSE.
122
Of course, OHEU’s priority
remained the flat and summons of setting per capita
, fearing that a rebate system would result in
uncontrollable increases to NUPSE ’ south dowry. Although this level would be set democratically by the NUPSE Convention, some OHEU delegates could not
accept that they would no longer be able to
determine unilaterally the sum costs of thyroxine
heir membership in the labour movement.
123
In negotiations with the NUPSE administrator duri
ng the fall of 1959, OHEU’s Unity Committee
secured a rebate of $ 1.05 to support OHEU ’ s cont
inued self-servicing and NUPSE’s agreement to respect
the autonomy of OHEU and its constitution.
124
These commitments were deemed insufficient, however,
since “ NUPSE has failed to give the OHEU a wri
tten commitment guaranteeing [their] continued existence
as a self-servicing local ” under NUPSE and a future CUPE “ without the possibility of making unacceptable dues increases necessary. ” furthermore, the Committ
ee sought but did not achieve an agreement allowing
the withdrawal of OHEU if the terms of
merger between NUPE and NUPSE were unacceptable.
125
Though
NUPSE verbally agreed to these terms and promised to
fight for them in the NUPSE-NUPE merger talks,
they could not guarantee the consequence given that
they could neither control NUPE nor force upon it
arrangements negotiated with OHEU.
126
As OHEU ’ s demands on the integrity march mounted in 1959, a mutually satisfactory solution seemed far and promote away. Tensions were exacerbated by OHEU ’ s attempts to revise the
CUPE
united states constitution, claiming this was merely a hardheaded meet
hod of “eliminating duplication of effort” by devising an
arrangement which could be carried over into the newly union.
127
However, the political implications of this
233 128
W. Dodge, letter to K. Cummings, May 19, 1959: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 4]
129
Power Workers’ Union, 22.
130
J. Lee, “Referendum to be held on remaining in NUPSE”, 1.
It is around this time, between the NUPSE Convention in Fall
1959 and February 1960, that Francis Eady
‘changed sides’ and became part of NUPSE’s nat
ional staff as Little’s Executive
assistant. In his report on the 1959 Convention, Hook ( of the OH
EU Unity Committee) wrote that “at the National Board Meeting
anterior to Convention, the final detail on deoxythymidine monophosphate
he agenda concerned the transfer of Eady to t
he National payroll” at which time Cummings
“ blew his phellem, having not been previously contacted – about
a deal between Eady and Little.”
(E.J. Hook, “NUPSE Convention
London 1959 ” ( draft ), December 1, 1959. CUPE Fonds
[NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 5]). Eady’s reasons for moving to the
national function are indecipherable, but may have had to do with the
way that OHEU was obstructing the development of a more
centralized union which he, as we will late see, supported. He
was replaced by Eady’s friend
and fellow CCFer, then-IWA staffe
r
John A. Lee, who was belated to become a sociol
ogy professor of at University of Toronto.
motion were much larger, as OHEU was asserting itse
lf as the central author of the merger with NUPE and
the most crucial constituency to be satisfied. This
presumption went too far: Dodge of the CLC was “at a
personnel casualty ” and admonished them for assuming that the oeuvre
ing out of a merger with NUPSE would authorize
them to usurp NUPSE ’ south rights and work on the fundamental law for an organization not however in universe.
128
After yet another summer and fall of blind alley, the NUPSE leadership moved the matter back into the overt at the 1959 Convention, where, on a gesture francium
om the Executive, the delegates, many of whom
continued to be resentful about OHEU ’ mho condition and exponent
to hold up merger negotiations with NUPE, voted
to end the Agreement of Understanding between NUPSE and OH
EU as of April 14, 1960. From that date,
OHEU was expected to pay NUPSE ’ s wax per head
(now at $1.30) and be subject to the national
constitution if it wished to remain in the union and the CLC.
129
OHEU’s Unity Committee contended that, if
subject to the rulings of the national convention, “ t
he OHEU would no longer retain its autonomy in the strict
feel of the son. ”
130
In reply to NUPSE ’ sulfur renewed unilateral attempts
to place OHEU under its constitution, OHEU’s
council of Chief Stewards held an emergency meeti
ng in March of 1960. OHEU’s legal counsel, CCF
National Secretary and future NDP drawing card David Lewis
, supported the Unity Committee’s claim that they
were under no duty to remain in NUPSE if thyroxine
he terms of the merger agreement were unilaterally
changed by NUPSE. Lewis argued that since “ the OHEU
is not a chartered local created by NUPSE” and
“ existed ahead in its own proper ”, the “ agreem
ent between NUPSE and the OHEU [is] a contract
234 131
J. Lee, “Referendum to be held on remaining in NUPSE”, 1, 4.
132
Power Workers’ Union, 22. It is difficult to see a mer
ger after five years of ‘cour
tship’ as a ‘shotgun wedding’.
133
John Alan Lee,
Love’s Gay Fool: Autobiography of John Alan Lee
, online at http://www.johnalanlee.ca/chapters/
chapter_11.htm ( viewed January 28, 2005 ). 134
Power Workers’ Union, 22.
between partners, rather than the par
ent-child relationship applicable where the National Union has created
and chartered a Local. ” Bolstered by this legal
reading of their status, the Unity Committee now
uniquely favoured finding a way out of NUPSE.
The Committee thus recommended to the Council of
headman Stewards that the OHEU executive advise NUPSE thyroxine
hat they would cease to pay per capita after April
14, 1960. This resolving power was defeated in favor of
putting the matter to the membership without a
recommendation by the Council of Chief Stewards.
131
Those sympathetic to the Unity Committee ’ s situate
ion likely assumed that the OHEU membership
would reemphasize its fabled commitment to absolute
autonomy, and thus this would be reinforced by the
Unity Committee ’ s vigorous and nasty campaign against NUPSE in which Little, Eady and Cummings were depicted as forcing a shotgun wedding on unintentional and unwilling OHEU members.
132
However, John Lee,
the OHEU ’ s newfangled Education and Publicity Officer, was
charged by the local’s leadership with keeping the
union in NUPSE and the labor movement. obviously, Lee ’ second emphasis on how OHEU would hush retain significant autonomy, even in a nearer relationship with NUPSE, worked.
133
Contrary to the expectations of
the Unity Committee, in May 1960 OHEU ’ s membership voted 68 % in favor of remaining in NUPSE “ under the terms of the National C
onstitution and associated documents.”
134
This vote led NUPSE and
OHEU to sign a Memo on Per Capita Allowance in June 1960, setting up a rebate system which would prevent OHEU ’ s net income per capita flush from ever being
subject to the National Convention’s decision-making
power. This resolution removed the primary coil obstacle
to the merger with NUPE over the previous four
years. A not-overwhelming majority of OHEU had re
cognized that it would no longer be able to maintain
235 complete independence within the future CUPE. however, the telephone line between autonomy and one was to be constantly renegotiated in the new organization. IV.
Conclusion
intelligibly, by 1960, little headroom had been made in the me
rger process. A central barrier was the
intractability of disputes over how democra
cy would be understood and institutionalized in any new
structure. These tensions existed both between
NUPE and NUPSE, and within the two unions as well.
These internal tensions, the products of the particula
r path to unification taken by each parent union in the
years previous, meant that integrity in the canadian public house
lic sector would be nowhere near as easy to achieve
as primitively thought. The two views of democracy at play here were each persuasive in their own ways, but besides possessed internal contradictory logi
cs that made it difficult to ident
ity clearly which was in the best
interests of members. The entreaty to broader working
class interests was often twinned with a claim that
leaders knew best what members needed and should theref
ore be left to figure out how best to achieve
that. however, the ‘ democratic logic ’ of majori
ty rule via Convention could also produce moves to
overwhelm recalcitrant minorities and copper
t them out of representation. In
that sense, elite control over the
fusion process could be seen as an undemocratic proc
ess seeking a more democratic outcome than that
which could be produced by members themselves. The appeal to local autonomy besides possessed contradictions, particularly when practised by large minorities whose decisions would have a major impact
on others outside their ‘democratic community’. The
insistence on absolute control over all decisions affe
cting a particular group could easily be transmuted into
a claim for limited exemption from the obligations
binding others in the organization. As such, local
autonomy in the context of inner ability imbalances c
ould produce privileges not available to others: the
236 proper to veto, the right to design structures that
others would have to live with, and the right to negotiate
directly with leaders preferably than be bound by the de
liberations of Conventions. This would magnify
inequalities within the arrangement. As well, ‘ democracy ’, variously defined, was used as
a strategic tool by leaders in their battles with
each early. While the commitment to majority rule may have been genuine, it was besides convenient to refer to ‘ the will of the membership ’ – whether as the loca
l union or the Convention – to legitimate actions in
disputes more intelligibly linked to the personal power
of particular leaders. ‘T
he membership’, understood as
a static and given datum, could be used to put pressu
re to move forward with unification – and relinquish
sectionalist attachments – or to block the fusion
process. This manoeuvring highlighted the stakes for
leaders in the process, and made it more unmanageable to
determine what kind of resolution would best serve
public sector workers. In this discipline of conflicting visions, national and
local organizations, and leaders, some way to create
oneness and reach a consensus about how to instit
utionalize democracy was needed. The route chosen,
however, was not a product of a ‘ intellectual ’ choice
about what model of democracy would best serve the
membership, nor was it a resolution crafted and unila
terally imposed by leadership. Rather, the terms of
fusion would be based on the interaction between the
personal desires of national and local leaders, the
proportional commitment of these leaders to their respec
tive visions of a national union, and the strength of
autonomist segments of each coupling ’ s membership .
237 1
NUPE Educational Services, “The Origin and Growth of the National Union of Public
Employees”, October 1958: 2. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 10 ] 2
K. Cummings, Merger Report – NUPSE-NUPE
– to OHEU Executive Board, Decem
ber 12, 1957: 4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc.
MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 11 ] 3
NUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 22-23, 1958: 3.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 6]; R.
Rintoul, National Director ’ s General R
eport, NUPE, 1961 Convention Proceedings: 24.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol. 2, File 14 ] chapter 6 : The Merger Process and Union Democracy II : Establishing CUPE, 1960-1963 While NUPSE was getting its family in holy order, NUPE ’ s own inner processes were producing some pressures that would come to bear heavily on t
he merger process. The years between 1955 and 1960
were ones of incredible growth for NUPE : in that
time, both membership and the number of locals more
than doubled.
1
This expansion was fuelled by the gradual affiliation of between 30 to 50 TLC public
employee locals who had not joined NUPE immediat
ely upon its formation in 1955, but who had either
overcome their agnosticism or realized that triiodothyronine
he TLC would soon cease to service independent public
employee locals when there was a home union to
do the job. Indeed, once the CLC was formed, the
directly chartered locals were soon parcelled
out to NUPE and NUPSE, adding more members and locals
to service.
2
Finally, and despite their limited numbers of
field representatives, NUPE was organizing new
locals at a rapid pace, particularly in the Prairies
and the Maritimes. On the face of it, NUPE appeared to
be a healthy union. however, the pressures of growth promptly led to
demands for increased staff. NUPE’s initial staff –
a full-time National Director and a secretary – were
soon joined by field representatives in 1957, 1958 and
1960, bringing their count to thirteen.
3
Additionally, a full-time researcher, Gil Levine, had been brought
on staff in 1956, the beginnings of specialization in rhenium
sponse to the effects of the legalization of labour
relations. It was believed, by Rintoul in particular, that farther specialization would be needed, given growing complexities of “ Labour Law, labor prac
tices and the development of varying and complicated
238 4
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure Submitted by the National Director at the Request of the National
Executive Board ”, National Union of Public
Employees, April 1960: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 9 ] 5
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure”, 10-12.
methods of corporate dicker under the provincial tug relations boards. ”
4
In other words, important
changes in the union ’ s internal functions were occurring both as a reaction to expansion and as a leave of the external pressures of the modern british labour party relations regimen. Servicing, its type, choice, handiness, cost,
and, most importantly, t
he method of its delivery
became the shape in which these pressures were express
ed. Servicing was a central political issue in NUPE
for several reasons. As both Lenihan and some NUPE chromium
itics had pointed out, many of the former TLC
locals were unions in name only. additionally, many
locals were burdened with legacies of quiescence and
employer domination not uncommon in the municipal
field. Finally, newly organized locals had no
know in the labor movement. All of these si
tuations required that me
mbers and potential leaders be
educated in the ‘ ways of unionism ’ as defined by thyroxine
he national union and its representatives. In the
meanwhile, ‘ expert ’ staff were needed to carry out
a legion of important functions while simultaneously
educating locals to take over their own affairs.
5
In the short run, the slow process of education led to heavy
demands on the limited numbers of servicing staff. Mo
reover, the demands of servicing limited the time
which reps could spend extending organization to new
groups. While there was a consensus that more
servicing was needed, the wonder of how it should be
delivered was a fractious one. Three different and
frequently conflicting models were in fact in function in
NUPE, each with its proponents and beneficiaries. Different
groups in the union consequently had immediate material
stakes in the precise balance that was struck
between integrity and autonomy. As a leave, the union was plagued by the interview of how to foster identification with a broader set of interests and structures without compulsion or excessive restrictions on local control. The perseverance of mutually single
models of servicing led to a three-year period of open
239 conflict within the coupling over the kind of union structure which would suit ‘ stream realities ’ as different people saw them. While everyone attributed the stand in amalgamation tantalum
lks to the other side, there was much at stake
for each union ’ randomness leaders in a blend organization.
Leaders stalled not only because of principled stands
on what kind of union would be best for the members ; t
hey also wanted to ensure that they would occupy
an important place in the post-merger organi
zation. Leaders on both sides pursued internal
transformations so as to shore up their situation in thymine
he merger talks, and waited until such time as they felt
the stars were lining up in their favor. National and
local leaders were working hard to avoid situations in
which they would have to take orders, a goal which
informed what was put forward as principled stands on
what constituted democratic or effective unionism.
Each union had a leader that, at base, believed the
most effective unionism would feature him at the clear. however, considerations of one and the personalities on both sides would make it impossible field-grade officer
r everyone to be a position of control. Concluding
the amalgamation would require leaders to make some tr
ade-offs, to decide whether personal power or public
sector integrity was more significant. These concerns about personal power intertwi
ned with broader questions about NUPE’s internal
structures, and provoked some serious soul-search
ing within the union. NUPE’s continued success at
adding raw groups to its ranks brought to the bow thousand
any of the issues which had been deferred in order to
create a formal national administration in 1955. The conf
licting imperatives of rapid membership growth, on
the one hand, and local and provincial responsibilities for servicing on the early, set up a self-reinforcing bicycle of autonomy. As those like Rintoul who adv
ocated national servicing found themselves unable to
convert adequate local leaders to agree to per capita
increases, the gaps continued to be filled by local
business agents, zone councils and peasant divisions. The development of local service capacity, particularly by the older locals, thus placed furt
her downward pressure on national revenues, as groups
240 6
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure”, 2.
7
NUPE, 1959 Convention Proceedings.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 2, File 10]
8
NUPE, 1961 Convention Proceedings: 76.
became accustomed to having conduct master over services and began to demand per caput rebates in stead of service. Compounding these problems was the fact
that affiliation to intermediate bodies – which had
taken on important functions – continued to be voluntar
y, creating additional layers of the union’s structure
seeking money from the national coupling. This dynamic
worked to institutionalize the already powerful bases
for local autonomy, divided the coupling between ‘ centralizer
s’, ‘regionalizers’ and ‘autonomists’, and led to a
series of inflame conventionality debates about the nature of
mutual obligation in the new union and the kind of
union structure needed as a result. How these conflicts were resolved would besides shape the fusion terms and the organization that would resu
lt from it in powerful ways.
I.
NUPE Does Some Soul Searching
The majority of NUPE ’ mho locals continued to be dom
inated by autonomists. For these individuals, it
was an absolute and intact principle “ that the
autonomy of the local union should be preserved.”
6
Many
of these locals wished to maximize their control over resources, bargaining and service. local 43, Toronto external municipal workers, was luminary
in this camp, repeatedly forwarding demands and
convention resolutions along with its sister local 79 of
inside civic workers, advocating per capita rebates
for locals like them which employed full-time business agents.
7
Autonomists also opposed the mandatory
affiliation of locals to district councils and provincial
divisions, claiming that any attempt of convention “to
order to local unions ” would be resisted.
8
There were, of course, variations
within this position, particularly
between large locals who could afford to contemplate
self-servicing, and smaller locals without resources
who had to depend on national services but who had little extra for affiliations. There were besides those whose belief “ that affiliation should be voluntary
and should be achieved by education rather than by
241 9
NUPE, 1961 Convention Proceedings: 77.
10
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure”, 4, 5.
11
NUPE, 1961 Convention Proceedings: 77.
compulsion ” was rooted not in a rejecti
on of the utility or rightful role of other levels of the union. Rather, as
Harley Horne of Calgary ’ s local 8 argued, locals
should be encouraged to affiliate and identify with the
broader structures of the union, but
through political and educational work amongst the membership rather
than by decree from convention or the administrator board.
9
In the minority, but emerging as a vocal group,
were centralizers and regionalizers. These groups
advocated the tone of the more cardinal struct
ures of the union for both pragmatic and ideological
reasons. On the practical side, district councils and praseodymium
ovincial divisions were seen as important institutions
given the ‘ contemporary realities ’ of public sector collective bargaini
ng and labour law. District councils
were likely mechanisms for resisting employers ’ legal profession
gaining tactics, such as playing locals off against
each other and creating settlement patterns with the weakes
t local in a given region. District councils could
minimize the injury that locals could do and often
did one another when their actions were uncoordinated.
similarly, provincial divisions had an important political function in countering the increasingly coordinated efforts of employers to secure labor legislation restricting the rights of public sector workers.
10
In other
words, for both centralizers and regionalizers, interm
ediate bodies were the institutional expressions of
public sector workers ’ broader interests and the means
through which they could be acted upon. As such,
these bodies required sufficient resource
s and support from all the union’s locals.
11
Given the universe of these common supra-local
interests, new moral imperatives were implied.
Since these bodies were not functionless “ clubs ”,
but had a definite and important
function in the marriage from which everyone would benefit, volunteer affiliation was
at odds with the basic principles underlying local
unions ’ own organizational success : that of the Rand
Formula and of majority rule. Centralizers and
regionalizers therefore insisted that “ all who benefit from [ t
hese bodies’] activities should be obliged to pay for
242 12
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure”, 3.
13
NUPE, 1961 Convention Proceedings: 77.
14
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure”, 16.
their operation and to abide by their decisions. ”
12
Those who resisted fulfilling these obligations were
considered ‘ freeloaders ’ who were not in full committed
to the labour movement. One “could not be in the
trade union apparent motion with merely our bad toe, we had to come in with both feet. ”
13
Mandatory affiliation was
therefore a question of democratic province, reciprocal obli
gation and self-discipline in the service of unity as
well as one of hardheaded necessity. however, centralizers and regionalizers parted ways ov
er the precise role of district councils and
provincial divisions, and in detail whether they
should be involved in servicing. This conflict was
exemplified by the debate over the british Columb
ia servicing system set up in the TLC days, and
administered by the provincial part and the prov
incial union of hospital workers, Local 180. For
regionalizers, provincial control over servicing made sense both as a way to pool resources and to remain “ closer ” to the members thus as to better identify,
understand and respond to their particular servicing needs.
As such, the $ 13,000 annual grant from the national union in stead of extra national staff representatives and divided between the BC Division and Local 180
14
was seen as perfectly reasonable.
For centralizers like Rintoul, however, provinci
ally-controlled and -administered servicing was
deficient for both practical and political reasons.
Servicing grants promoted isolation and inequality
between locals, detracted from oneness, were more costly
and resulted in a lower quality of service. In the
absence of National staff, Rintoul argued, the huge milliampere
jority of BC locals and district councils “never
bothered to let [ the BC Division ] know how they were
doing, or what their final result [in collective
bargaining ] was. In particular instances, [ the BC Di
vision Secretary] had to buy their local area newspapers
to read what their settlements were. ” furthermore, Ri
ntoul pointed out, the logic of self-servicing disregarded
the necessitate for uniform or equal national servicing and bomber
tituted the principle that “the strong look after
243 15
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure”, 17-18.
16
NUPE, 1961 Convention Proceedings: 6.
17
NUPE, 1959 Convention Proceedings: 8.
themselves and … the National Union attend [ second ] after the weak. ” Such a system was besides expensive : bc locals were paying twice for servicing, once thr
ough their National per capita tax, and again through a
higher per head going to the BC Division. Despite
the higher price tag, centra
lizers argued that the actual
servicing received was of lower quality as it wa
s provided by part-time, narrowly focussed non-experts
quite than full-time experts with broader
knowledge of the sectors and the province.
15
Finally, the rebate
system generated resentment and a “ me
too” mentality amongst some lik
e Local 43, who argued that “if
grants were being given out, [ the local ] would want its share. ”
16
These different views pointed to the deep conflicts
over NUPE’s structure. In many instances,
potent identifications existed with eac
h level of the union, loyalties which
did not constantly reflect the realities of labour-management relations or the nature of the post-war legal regimen
. Regardless of the kind of union
structure unlike actors desired, the fact was that
locals were no longer self-contained units. The mutual
shock of their decisions was now more obvious, and a lack of coordination or awareness of the interests of early workers could cause serious internal
conflicts and constitute a serious barrier to further
organizational integrity. furthermore, given that some groups
were not contributing to the cost of efforts from
which they would benefit, like attempts to change restrictive peasant labor laws, there were geomorphologic bases for resentment. These conflicts took the form of a major st
ructural debate at NUPE’s 1959 convention, at which
autonomists, regionalizers and centralizers all proposed so
lutions to these issues. In particular, delegates
debated both the doubt of mandate affiliation and of per caput rebates to “ self-servicing ” locals with full-time business agents. however, neither provis
ion was adopted, with the potential merger with NUPSE
used as a rationale for avoiding major structural changes which might be untie soon enough anyhow.
17
244 18
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure”, 1.
19
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure”, 2.
This default adoption of the condition quo left NUPE in
limbo and forced the NEB to pursue ad hoc solutions
over the future two years. In the face of the 1959 Convention ’ s failure to
adopt measures definitively favouring one of the
models present in the union, the NUPE NEB was left to craft a solution to the National Union ’ s miss of “ proper rules, or even principles ” to govern the “ func
tions of the Field Representatives, … the authority of
the local unions and provincial divisions, and their
responsibilities to the Labour Movement in general and
the National Union in particular. ”
18
In early 1960, the NEB thus asked Rintoul to prepare a series of
proposals which would address these concerns. Ri
ntoul’s report was undeniably in favour of greater
centralization and professionalization. While hello
s analysis of the NUPE structure accepted the general
authenticity of local autonomy,
Rintoul argued that the
extent
of local autonomy in NUPE, as evidenced in
voluntary affiliation to marriage bodies, decrepit central mastermind
ion of staff, and grants in lieu of national servicing,
was damaging to the union on both democratic and practical grounds. The solution to these problems was to strengthen the capacity of the National
Office and to increase reliance on expert staff.
Rintoul identified NUPE ’ mho cardinal dilemma as the contradiction between
two important operational
principles. On the one pass, there was a consensus
that “there should be no unnecessary infringement on
the autonomy of the local union ”, wh
ile, on the other hand, “unity of purpose and unity of action” were
necessity to “ an arrangement designed to serve populace
employees in all parts of Canada on the District,
Provincial and National levels, a well as on the local level. ” In practice, local autonomy as practised in NUPE took an extreme form that, as a have over “ fro
m the days when we were a Federation rather than a
Union ”, was nobelium long suited to the kind of organization they were in the process of build up.
19
In other
words, the conflict between the emerging vision of
NUPE’s purpose or function and the union’s actual
structure required a fundamental re
thinking of the appropriate boundaries
of local autonomy. For these
245 20
Ibid., 7.
reasons, Rintoul advocated compulsory affiliation to uni
on structures, clear delineation of the rights and
responsibilities of each flush of the union, and
strengthening national servicing capacity through
regionalization and the elimination of servicing through the peasant divisions and zone councils. Rintoul ’ s analysis was based on a detail
understanding of the requirements of union
effectiveness. In order for the union ’ mho bodies to carry
out their roles in a context where their actions had
broader implications, a modified and less absolutis
t understanding of local autonomy had to be adopted. In
ordain to operationalize this update conception of
local autonomy, Rintoul
argued that the “rights and
responsibilities ” of each degree of the union had to be
well defined. Rintoul thus delineated a rather common-
sense oscilloscope of decision-making for each flush. The National Union was to possess assurance over matters affecting members in more than one state, and its
decisions were to be binding on subordinate levels of
the coupling, which could not establish policies “ at division with the policy of the National Union. ” Analogous powers were to be exercised by provincial divisions, di
strict councils and locals unions. As such, for Rintoul
locals would have autonomy to make “ decisions on inte
rnal policy, provided that such decisions must not
be to the detriment of members of other locals, contra
ry to policy of the District Council, the Provincial
division or the National Union. ”
20
Local autonomy would be significantly more limited, and thus Rintoul was
recommending both a meaning shift in the relati
onships of authority inside NUPE and a broadening of the
oscilloscope of reciprocal responsibilities, park interests and obligations. Rintoul ’ s apparently neat and legitimate definition
of responsibilities could not address the more
cardinal inconsistencies at work, however. When anal
ysed in the context of a concrete example, the
increased telescope for National policy-making envisioned by Rintoul remained constrained by local anesthetic autonomy, particularly because locals retained decision-making rights over their own collective dicker agendas and the practice of the strike weapon. In early words,
the problem of local autonom
y existed not only at the
246 21
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure”, 8.
22
R. Rintoul, “Recommendations on Staff and Structure”, 8-9.
level of policies, but besides at the level of implement
ation. For example, Rint
oul argued that contracting out
would be a matter of National policy, since it a
ffected members in more than one province, and locals
would thus be “ boundary to oppose ” it. however, as Rintoul then admitted, no local could be forced to take the kinds of military action which would prevent contracting out in their detail workplace : since striking would remain the prerogative of the local, no higher
level of the union could force a strike to resist contracting out.
21
Locals would be “ needed ” to oppose in principle, but not
in practice on the ground. In this sense, a ‘clear
division of labor ’ on issues was useless, since it
could not guarantee locals’ adherence to national policies
so long as a disjunction between policy-making and
policy implementation persisted. Thus Rintoul
expressed an authoritative constraint on effective national
policy-making but did not fully realize – or at least
hash out – its implications. Compounding the gap between the theory
and reality of local autonomy was Rintoul’s failure to set
out any particular method for enforcing these “ separat
ion of powers”, ensuring that unions used “every
means short-circuit of strike carry through ” to implement National united states post office
licies, or preventing different sections of the union
from working at cross purposes. He did acknowledge
that “it would … be necessary to provide that in
cases of dispute or doubt, some policeman should be des
ignated as the judge to rule on matters submitted.”
however, he did not go beyond articulation of the goal, and left the means unexpressed.
22
His injunctions
remained at the level of what locals
should
do, and thus did not transcend the central problem which led to
the report in the first space, namely to find some way to
deal with the fact that many locals were not doing
what they “ should ” in the context of a national
organization with claims on their loyalty and identity.
The report was besides concerned with the lack of vitamin e
ffective power exercised by the National Director
and advocated the professionalization of union staff.
Rintoul characterized the relationship between the
then twelve Staff Representatives in the field and the
National Director as one of “remote control.” The
247 23
Ibid., 13-15.
system of supervision did “ not permit the National
Director to pursue an uninterrupted plan for the
development of a service and organizing program for eac
h province or region”, nor to ensure that the
appropriate type and level of service was being provided to each local anesthetic. Of especial concern was the ‘ overservicing ’ of locals due to staff reps ’ failure to
educate local union officers in certain functions. Rintoul
therefore recommended increased centrum
lization in the form of regionalisation of servicing, to be
accomplished through the establishment of four regional Directors a soon as finances permitted.
23
regional Directors would be responsible to the National
Director – not to provincial division executives –
allowing Rintoul to work with a smaller group of people and implement uniform policies and practices. regional Directors, Rintoul argued, would be better
able to assess organizing potential and to ensure field
representatives were doing their jobs. Such a southeast
t up would replace provincial servicing machinery,
eliminate the practice of granting roentgen
ebates to subordinate bodies in lieu of service from the national office,
and take out of the locals ’ hands decisions about the level and type of servicing they would receive. In early words, to use resources wisely and avoid wast
e, to engage in rational planning of union growth and
development, adept leadership, organized in a well-def
ined chain of command with the National Director
on top, was required. The NUPE NEB favorably received this gain st
atement of the centralizers’ logic and proposed
structures and, in early 1961, adopted Rintoul ’ s division of labor for the different levels of the union. The NEB besides endorsed in rationale the restructure of
servicing, namely the establishment of Regional
Directors and regional offices. however, these pr
ovisions were approved in the absence of enforcement
mechanisms, a supporting cultural consensus on
the meaning and limits of local autonomy, and the
fiscal means to pay for them. In particular, as
Buss reported to the 1961 Convention, the low level of
per caput and the ongoing pressures for rebates from
locals prevented the regionalization of servicing
248 24
W. Buss, President’s Address, NUPE, 1961 Convention Reports: 9. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 2, File 11]
25
NUPE, 1961 Convention Proceedings: 5-7.
structures.
24
Both Locals 43 and 79 came to the NEB seeking grants after the 1959 NUPE Convention,
evening though the delegates there had explicitly reje
cted extending the rebate system to cover them.
however, with the electric potential loss of 7000 members at
stake, the NEB ignored the warnings of Rintoul and
the Convention and granted the two locals their reques
t. In an attempt to establish a clear policy and
permanent resolution of the issue, the NEB controversially proposed the union affect to a separate per caput tax organization which would eliminate the motivation for grants
by formally distinguishing between self-servicing
locals and those dependent on the National Union.
25
It was now up to the 1961 NUPE Convention to decide
whether they would find the means to implement a new
, more centralized vision of the union, with a formal
realization of the unlike types of organizations within
its midst, or retain the more familiar yet increasingly
incoherent and conflictual condition quo. The pressures on NUPE to address these authoritative st
ructural flaws multiplied with the renewal of
amalgamation talks with NUPSE. Fresh from their own in
ternal battles, Stan Little and Francis Eady, now a
NUPSE national staff member and a key actor on their me
rger committee, were quick to pick up on these
‘ weaknesses ’ as a new guise for foster delays in
the merger process and a way to gain the upper hand in
negotiations. NUPE leaders returned to these talks with
the image that they were unable “to put their own
house in order ” and create the kind of union needed to be effective. NUPSE leaders asked how, then, could they be expected to lead a new Canadian coupling of public employees ? II.
Shots Across the Bow: The Merger Talks of 1960-62
Over a class had passed since the last amalgamation
meeting, with both NUPE and NUPSE preoccupied
with internal issues authoritative to the amalgamation proc
ess. Both had been seeking ways to become structurally
‘ satisfactory ’ to each other and to meet on a foot of
relative equality. The attempts to eliminate these
249 26
S. Little, “Report of Merger M
eetings held in Ottawa, June 6-7-8″, 1960: 1.CUPE F
onds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5, File 12]
barriers were insufficient, however : when the thousand
ger committees met again for three days in June 1960 to
trade proposed changes to the draft CUPE Constitution,
the differences had both shifted focus and become
more fundamental. The issues which had dominated the
first four years of talks now receded into the
background. The trouble of OHEU ’ second condition and
autonomy in NUPSE had been ostensibly resolved by the
membership referendum the previous calendar month, and
the agreement setting up the per capita rebate system
was to be signed in a matter of weeks. The jurisdicti
on controversy was also more or less settled: in this
meet, NUPE representatives fi
nally agreed to NUPSE’s April 1959 proposal on jurisdiction, which would
have CUPE include both municipal and provincial workers.
26
With NUPE’s accession to NUPSE’s vision on
legal power, the two unions could now form a unit
ed front vis-à-vis the CLC’s policy on public service
legal power, where the very obstacles lay. however, though NUPE had grown, it had besides puerto rico
oved incapable of raising its per capita and
returned to the board with neither
a strengthened national servicing capacity nor organizational unity in the
form of compulsory affiliation to the union ’ second structures.
Little and Eady were thus able to refocus the debate
aside from NUPSE ’ second problems and onto what they deemed to be NUPE ’ s deficient, decentralized structure and their result inability to maintain a healthy level of
per capita to support national services. From this
meeting forward, the future administration ’ randomness per caput
was a central bone of contention. But conflicts over
finance were rooted in deeper and more complicate di
fferences over union function and structure, such
as the definition of a “ minimum ” national program, deoxythymidine monophosphate
he location of control over servicing, the status of
“ self-servicing ” locals and their function of service
grants and local business agents, and the relationship of
locals to early parts of the union. Four years in
to the merger process, the discussions were finally
250 27
S. Little, letter to C. Jodoin, “Re: Statement on Merger
between the National Union of P
ublic Service Employees and the
National Union of Public Employees ”, March 3, 1961 : 1.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 18]
28
S. Little, “Report of Merger Meeti
ngs held in Ottawa, June 6-7-8″, 1.
29
F. Eady, “Report on Current Position re Merger with NUPE (confidential)”, September 20, 1960: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG
28, I234, Vol. 5, File 12 ] 30
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes, Dece
mber 8-9, 1961: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 6]. Hikl
was a czechoslovakian immigrant, and as a leave an ardent anti-co
mmunist. MacMillan reports that Hikl was thus “always trying
to ‘ screw ’ Gil Levine as a solution of the latter ’ randomness erstwhile asso
ciation with the CPC. Former CUPE PR Director Norm Simon told
( continued … ) revealing, as Little put it, the two organization ’ sulfur
“differences in trade union outlook, philosophical and
political viewpoints in their broadest common sense. ”
27
At the June 1960 meet, NUPE pr
oposed a 50-cent per capita, with no rebates to anyone – the
lapp placement proposed by the CLC in 1957. At that
level, according to Little, the present combined
income of the two organizations would be reduced by $ 154,000.
28
NUPSE, on the other hand, advanced
$ 1.05 as the come which would allow for both
maintenance of current programs and expansion of
National and sphere staff. In the course of discussi
on, however, NUPSE held that a “basic programme” –
including a CLC per head increase, a irregular Resear
cher, an Education Director, a National Journal with
an editor program, and a Director for Ontario, with no increase to
field staff – would require a minimum per capita of
80 cents.
29
This staff complement would exclude other positions which NUPSE also felt were necessary,
such as job evaluators, travelling auditors and extra serve and organizing staff, but would have to submit for the prison term being. The parties were clearly fa
r apart not only on per capita, but also on the extent of
national staff needed for an effective union. While, for the NUPE committee, these demands s
eemed to come out of nowhere, NUPSE’s desire
for meaning bureaucratization of the National Office was a reflection of the home structural changes they had made in the intervening years. The accession of
significant blocks of members in Manitoba in 1956-
7 and in Quebec in 1960 permitted the establishment of regional offices with Directors responsible for organizing and supervision of field staff. NUPSE was besides
adding full-time staffers to the National Office,
first Eady in 1960 and then Mario Hikl as the Director of Research in 1961.
30
These staff positions had also
251 30
(…continued)
Crean that Hikl, “ to his dying day, could have passed a lie detec
tor test that [CUPE National
Secretary-Treasurer and, later,
National President ] Grace Hartman was a
Commie menace placed there by the Krem
lin ” ( Crean, 114 ). however, MacMillan says that the PhD holder “ knew legislation ” and was
a capable Legislative Director
for CUPE (MacMillan, 159).
31
The recasting of Little’s title and respons
ibilities should be understood in the context of
the earliest merger meetings, in wh
ich
Rintoul ’ s functionally broader role as NUPE ’ s National Director
was understood to place him ‘naturally’ at the top of any natio
nal
staff hierarchy created by a fusion. Alt
hough such a rationale is not explicitly noted in the documents, it is likely that Lit
tle
pursued such a transfer in order to block Rintoul ’ s
‘natural’ assumption of such a position in CUPE.
32
S.Little, letter to NUPSE Executive Board Members, “Re:
Finance and Budget”, September 10,
1958: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 4 ] 33
NUPSE, National Executive Committee minutes, September 20, 1960: 1, 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File
5 ] ; NUPSE, 1960 Convention Proceedings :
17. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5, File 6]
accumulated a lot of power, particularly the Direct
or of Organization, which was transformed into the
National Director in 1959.
31
Little, rather than part-time National
President James Clark, was routinely
charged with representing NUPSE at both home and external bodies, and not merely on technical or administrative matters. Throughout this period, constant
pressure from Little for more funding for staff, in
accession to the realities of budget deficits racked up
by 1958, served to push NUPSE’s per capita up from
$ 1.00 in 1957 to $ 1.40 in the fall of 1960.
32
Little’s vision of an “effective”, centralized and expert-led union
was bolstered by Eady ’ s arrival on the national staff,
and both worked to convince the NEB to transform the
half-time presidency into a full-time position with “ author
ity over all other officers in carrying out their duties”
and with “ voice but no right to vote ” on all of the union ’ s
subordinate bodies. The National Executive promptly
endorse Little as their candidate, who was installed in office in the fall of 1960.
33
These changes thus
upped the ante in amalgamation negotiations : as a more cent
ralized union was coming to fruition in NUPSE, Little
and Eady would fiercely resist attempts to undo thes
e developments in the process of merging with NUPE.
As such, NUPSE was promoting a larger and more powerful National Office. soon after the June 1960 converge, and despite the
optimistic cast contained in Little and Eady’s
initial reports, the NUPSE leadership began to set out
another rationale for delaying merger rooted in its
commitment to centralization. respective months of in
ternal discussion, supported by a series of analyses by
252 34
F. Eady, “Report on Current Position re Merger with NUPE (confi
dential)”, September 20, 1960; N.A. [F. Eady and S. Little],
“ Basic Problems standing in the direction of Merger between NUPSE and NUPE ” ( confidential
circular to NUPSE Executive Board),
December 6, 1960. Both CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5, File 12 ] 35
S. Little, “Report of Merger Meeti
ngs held in Ottawa, June 6-7-8”, 1.
36
S. Little, letter to C. Jodoin, “Re: Statement on Merger between NUPSE and NUPE”, March 3, 1961: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc.
MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 18 ] 37
F. Eady, “Report on Current Position re Merger with NUPE”, 3.
Eady
34
and centred around a NUPSE NEB meeting in December
1960, culminated in a memo sent by Little
to the CLC in March 1961, containing a series of sca
thing criticisms of NUPE’s structure. The main
obstacle in the way of amalgamation, according to Little,
was now “NUPE’s inability to centralize the operation of
their Union sufficiently to raise their per head. ”
35
Given this inability, “ [ i ] n the present uncertain state of matter of NUPE, by their apparent unwillingness to face up to the
problems of per capita, structure and the need for a
strong National Union, it would appear that
Merger is unlikely in the near future.”
36
NUPE ’ s access to the problem of per caput, as
Eady correctly pointed out in his analyses, was
“ unify and we will raise the per caput by and by. ”
37
NUPE’s own formation in 1955 reflected this principle,
which emphasized formal over substantial one. By
setting the per capita so low, it was thought, those
units accustomed to servicing grants from the Na
tional Union would no longer need them, and a state of
equality between locals would be established. The
strategy would leave the thornier problem of
significantly raising per head – particularly for the NU
PE locals – to the post-merger period. This approach
assumed that bringing everyone in on peer terms w
ould foster mutual ident
ification and solidarity and
make per caput increases possible after a peri
od of ‘socialization’ into the new organization.
however, NUPSE opposed deferring the fiscal wonder until after fusion, as NUPE ’ s own experience proved that organizational oneness did not
automatically produce the necessary shifts in
awareness. A proper appreciation of the balance of forces inside NUPE, which repeatedly thwarted “ sufficient ” per head and serve increases by thymine
he Convention, was cause for pessimism. For Eady,
NUPE ’ second projected numeric potency in the modern CUPE would be baffling given their track record and
253 38
F. Eady, “Report on Current Position re Merger with NUPE”, 3.
39
Ibid.
40
N.A. [F. Eady and S. Little], “Basic Problems standi
ng in the way of Merger between NUPSE and NUPE”, 1.
41
S. Little, letter to C. Jodoin, “Re:
Statement on Merger between NUPSE and NUPE”, 2.
42
N.A. [F. Eady and S. Little], “Basic Problems standi
ng in the way of Merger between NUPSE and NUPE”, 1.
the adjective requirements for changing the charge
of per capita: “What is not said [by NUPE
representatives ] is that every increase has been bitte
rly opposed in NUPE, and that once fixed a two-thirds
majority will be needed to raise it. ”
38
What Eady did not say but was no doubt conscious of was the
likelihood that NUPSE ’ s own local anesthetic 1000 would join forces with autonomists in NUPE to oppose per head increases, specially in the absence of a service
grant or rebate system. After merger, a cross-union
autonomy alliance would constitute a significant voti
ng bloc capable of hindering per capita increases in
the future CUPE. Eady ’ s analysis of NUPE ’ s reluctance to increase per
capita pointed specifically to those elements
inside NUPE who defended such extreme decentralizati
on, and were overlooked by Rintoul in his
assessment of the NUPE structure.
Eady claimed that “behind this whol
e per capita argument is the much
more basic problem of occupation agents. The fact is
that at present NUPE is controlled by locals having
business agents, and these locals are not concerned
in national programming, especially if it costs
money. ”
39
NUPSE opposed the practice of servicing via local business agents because it was “inefficient …
tends to over-service the big locals and leaves the belittled locals to fend for themselves ” due to stretching of home service staff.
40
The result of the decentralized busi
ness agent system was not a ‘proper’ union,
but “ a Federation linking a series of little Empires into a loosely constructed union without sufficient cardinal steering. ”
41
The business agent system was more than inefficien
t, however; it also led to ‘poor leadership’.
little and Eady both argued that while the system “ is
supposed to be ultra-democratic, … it works out to
mean that those creditworthy for local leadership are
more concerned with politicking for re-election than
giving leadership. ”
42
Moreover, the “starving” of NUPE’s nati
onal level had resulted in “retarded” national
254 43
S. Little, letter to C. Jodoin, “Re:
Statement on Merger between NUPSE and NUPE”, 2.
44
NUPSE, 1958 Convention, Constitutional
Amendments: 5; CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5, File 4]
45
NUPE, 1955 Constitution and By-Laws. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4,
File 2]. Article 10, Section 1 of the
fundamental law did give the National Director
the right to inspect any local’s books and records, did not empower them to take an
y
action after such an inspection. The miss of trust territory
powers was also pointed to in
a 1963 report by Rintoul on his
investigation of the activities of a local ’ second business agentive role, in
which he reminded local members that “[t]he National Union has
no
agency to place a local union under trust
eeship even on the basis of a request from
the local union president and a petition
from a hearty number of members. ” R. Rin
toul, “Report on Investigation of Winnipeg
General Hospital Employees ’ Union Local 56 ”, June 1963 : 1. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 8 ] 46
N.A. [F. Eady and S. Little], “Basic Problems st
anding in the way of Merger between NUPSE and NUPE”, 2.
47
Ibid.
48
S. Little, letter to C. Jodoin, “Re:
Statement on Merger between NUPSE and NUPE”, 2.
49
Ibid., 3; F. Eady, “Report on Current Position re Merger with NUPE”, 3.
programming, “ inadequate position facilities ” with reps
working out of their homes, “sometimes non-existent
clerical avail ”, and overwork staff repr
esentatives covering too many locals.
43
The discussion of business agents reflected some authoritative differences in views on the allow locus of control in the marriage. NUPSE was
no doubt using the kind of control established in their
own constitution in 1958 as a criterion : the NEB possessed across-the-board powers to investigate locals and place them under trusteeship.
44
NUPE had no such capacity,
45
and NUPSE leaders were thus even more
uncomfortable with a occupation agent system that meant “ five
y little control or influence is exercised over the
activities of the locals. ”
46
Such local control had resulted in cont
radictory practices and policies: locals
were “ taking action which may, in the unretentive run,
be expedient for the local but overall may have an
highly adverse effect on the Union. ”
47
This ‘lack of discipline’ had, in Little’s opinion, prevented NUPE
from being an effective player in the CLC.
48
For NUPSE, the system of business agents would have to be eliminated or brought under National
control, even though this would constitute “political suicide” for
NUPE ’ mho officers.
49
As an ardent garter of the CCF/NDP and a then
cial democratic approach to labour politics,
central control was besides crucial to Eady for ideological reasons. Bubbling under the open of the discussions, and making an casual appearance in NUPSE ’ s internal confidential documents, was the consequence of “ Communist influence ” in NUPE. Eady ’ s
December 1960 memo in particular made claims about
255 50
N.A. [F. Eady and S. Little], “Basic Problems standi
ng in the way of Merger between NUPSE and NUPE”, 2.
51
Ibid. MacMillan refers to Art Roberts, business agent for Local
8 in Calgary, as a communist, and he was likely one of the
western staffers being referred to in this memo. interestingly, MacMillan credits Little with not going after these staffers.
“When
he decided to take [ Roberts ] and other busi
ness agents on, Stan didn’t say, ‘Is he a Commie? Is he left? How far left or right
is
he ? ’ He brought them all on staff ” ( MacMillan, 160 ). however, thorium
is contradicts the experiences of other staffers like Gil Levi
ne,
who encountered a very dogmatically anti-communist Little. This might indicate that Li
ttle was capable, in certain circumstance
s,
of a more hardheaded approach path to the bequeath, not alone recognizing tantalum
lent and commitment, but the impor
tance of integrating powerfu
l
confrontation figures into the organization.
There appears to have been limits to this
, however: Little seemed absolutely unwilli
ng to
be similarly pragmatic sanction with a national sta
ffer like Levine, whose abilities were enormous, but was in a position too influentia
l for
little ’ mho taste. 52
S. Little, letter to C. Jodoin “Re:
Statement on Merger between NUPSE and NUPE”
53
NUPSE, National Executive Board minutes
, February 24-25, 1961. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 6, File 6]
the extent of communist influence in NUPE, identif
ying three Western staffers, including Alberta staff
spokesperson and former NUPE pres
ident Pat Lenihan, as Communists, and asserting that other evidence
was “ yet to be documented. ”
50
He proposed that “ the question can not be dealt with by Oaths of Office. It can only de deal with by an dependable appraisal of the
problem, and machinery provided to bar Communists
from office and means of removing them francium
om such positions as Business Agents.”
51
In other words, members themselves could not be expected to resist
the influences of Communist
activists, and therefore
needed a strong and politically aware National Office to pr
event ‘subversives’ from gaining or maintaining a
foothold in the newfangled coupling. This discussion was not,
however, included in the official version of NUPSE’s
side on fusion sent to the CLC and NUPE.
52
Indeed, the CLC via Jodoin strongly recommended its
deletion, “ so as not to confuse the basic financ
ial and structural differences” between the unions.
53
however, it was indicative of the sources of
NUPSE’s discomfort with NUPE’s decentralized structure.
Underlying these criticisms of NUPE were a seri
es of assumptions about the appropriate roles and
capacities of leadership and membership. Eady
and Little clearly believed the sectionalist NUPE
membership could not be trusted to make the ‘ right
decisions’, whether organizationally or politically, and
that their local representatives held excessively much power.
Rather than passively reflect the membership in their
err views, ‘ good ’ and ‘ potent ’ leaders should negotiate behind close up doors to secure the requirements for an effective merged marriage, namely a
higher per capita and strong national executive and
256 54
N.A. (Rintoul / NUPE Merger Committee), “Statement on
Merger of NUPE and NUPSE by the National Union of Public
Employees ”, May 12, 1961 : 1. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 27 ] 55
N.A. (Rintoul / NUPE Merger Committee), “Statement on
Merger of NUPE and NUPSE by the National Union of Public
Employees ”, 1. however, as I have shown, NUPSE ’ s delay
had much to do with the need to bring OHEU under the Union’s
constitution then as to make the fusion with NUPE happen. In this
sense, merger continued to be a priority for NUPSE, but given
the poor communication between the
two organizations in that peri
od, it appeared otherwise to NUPE.
staff, a
fait accompli
. Little and Eady clearly thought that merger
would take place despite the membership,
and effective leaders, with a sense of the ‘ general in
terest’, would do what was necessary to make it
happen. To add insult to injury, NUPSE sent a imitate of their review to NUPE ’ s national position in early May of 1961, a full two months after sending it to the CLC.
Particularly galling was the fact that this had been
NUPSE ’ s first communication since the June 1960 fusion
meeting, at which time it was agreed that
fiscal information would be exchanged.
54
Substantively, these arguments were no news to Rintoul and
early NUPE leaders, who had been arguing
many of the same things for years. Indeed, what NUPSE’s
assessments missed were the extent to which some
NUPE leaders supported centralization, and that their
negotiating counterparts were their strongest electric potential
allies. However, rather than support NUPE leaders
in their internal struggles, NUPSE ’ s report raised the
suspicions of those wary of or opposed to further
centralization, and, in depicting them as ineffective
leaders of a pathetic organization, put NUPE leaders on
the defensive. The harsh criticisms of NUPE ’ s structur
e were thus poorly received; it was clearly one thing
to have a vigorous internal argument about the flaws
of one’s own organization, and quite another to have
one ’ south weaknesses aired in public by an adversary.
As a result, Rintoul and the Merger Committee
responded promptly and defensively with their own analysis of
the obstacles standing in the way of merger.
NUPE ’ s rejoinder immediately shifted the blame
for the lack of progress back to NUPSE and their
perceived reluctance to make amalgamation a priority.
55
With entirely about eight meetings in five years, and meaning delays in between, the result personnel casualty of
continuity had made advancement difficult. Rintoul again
argued that NUPE “ has always taken the first step ”
to set up meetings and to exchange information, and
257 56
Ibid., 1, 4-5.
57
N.A. (Rintoul / NUPE Merger Committee), “Statement on
Merger of NUPE and NUPSE by the National Union of Public
Employees ”, 2. By the June 1960 meeting,
NUPE’s per capita had risen to 45 cents, near
ly to the level prescribed by the CLC
amalgamation Proposal. NUPSE ’ second per head
had increased to $1.30 from the level of
$1.00 in 1957 (F. Eady, “Report on Current
Position re Merger with NUPE ”, 1 ). In the fall of 1960, NUPE per
capita would rise to 55 cent
s, while NUPSE’s would increase
another 10 cents to $ 1.40. NUPE further raised its per caput to
60 cents at its 1961 Convention. Of course, NUPSE also raised
its per caput that lapp year to $ 1.50, milliampere
intaining the difference between the two unions.
58
Ibid., 3; G. Cushing and J. MacKenzie, “Merger Proposal”, 2.
that NUPSE had never been similarly forthcoming with
either their time or information. Especially
debatable at this particular conjuncture was the failu
re of NUPSE to provide financial information, as was
agreed at the June 1960 meeting, wh
ich had prevented NUPE from either
making an assessment of the
fiscal needs of the newly organization or evaluat
ing NUPSE’s claims about the matter. NUPSE had not
presented NUPE with any “ concrete evidence ” demonstrating that a per head of $ 1.05 was required for CUPE to be effective, and while “ [ deoxycytidine monophosphate ] ertain fiscal data regarding NUPE was passed on to NUPSE shortly after this June [ 1960 ] meet … football team months
later, we are still waiting for the financial statement
from them. ”
56
Though typical of Rintoul ’ second opinion of the negotiations
, these complaints were not the crux of the
topic, however. It was NUPSE ’ south failure to apprecia
te the difficult modifications NUPE had been making to
its internal structures which so angered Rintoul.
He emphasized that NUPE had increased its per capita on
four occasions since 1955, boosting its level by “ five
and one half times in six years”, and by 67% in the last
three years. Since 1960, per head was set at 55 cent
s, higher than the level originally prescribed by the
CLC Merger Proposal, and the NUPE NEB was going to
recommend a further per capita increase at the
approaching 1961 Convention.
57
Rintoul demonstrated that NUPE sta
ff and servicing had also grown since
the beginning of amalgamation discussions. By May of
1961, NUPE had 13 field reps, 15 locally employed
business agents, and six headquarters staff, constituting a
significant expansion compared to the four field
reps and four National staff employed in 1957.
58
The fact that NUPE had done so much with so little was a
credit to the form of organization they had adopted :
instead of being the “weak and starving” organization
258 59
NUPE’s membership had grown to 46,000 in 1961, adding a fu
ll 11,000 more members since 1957 (N.A. (Rintoul / NUPE
Merger Committee ), “ Statement on Merger
of NUPE and NUPSE by the National Union of Public Employees”, 3; G. Cushing and
J. MacKenzie, “ Merger Proposal ”, 2. 60
N.A. (Rintoul / NUPE Merger Committee), “Statement on
Merger of NUPE and NUPSE by the National Union of Public
Employees ”, 3, 4. depicted by NUPSE, NUPE had an excellent record of
organizing new locals and of negotiating collective
agreements which were, according to Rintoul, stronger than NUPSE ’ s.
59
As such, NUPE demonstrated that
there was a bang-up manage more diverseness in what it
took to be an “effective union”, and did “not need to make
apologies to anyone about its services and operations. ” however, despite these achievements, it was net from their actions that the NUPE leadership had implic
itly recognized the validity of NUPSE’s claims that
per caput was besides low, and that “ an effective and competitive union ” required more.
60
Rintoul was particularly bang-up to debunk the allegations of NUPE leaders ’ unwillingness to make crucial morphologic changes. He emphasized that
while NUPE was moving towards higher per capita and
more home program, the custom of autonomy
established during the pre-
NUPE period could not be
reshaped overnight. NUPE ’ s reluctance to raise per caput
by almost 100% to 80 cents, (not to mention
$ 1.05 ) was not a question of leadership weakness, as Li
ttle or Eady would have it, but a reflection of the
relative political weight of different groups in
the union and the continuing importance in the union of
reflecting the will of the majority, evening if leader
s disagreed with it. ‘Good leadership’ was not about
imposing one ’ second views on a overawe membership, but ra
ther involved engaging that membership in debate
about the organization and letting them decide. Given
these commitments to representative democracy, it
was pointless to agree to fusion terms which would ultimately be rejected by local anesthetic delegates at convention. In other words, Rintoul was not def
ending autonomy wholesale; his own assessment of NUPE
distinctly advocated more centralization. however, his greater sensitivity to the world power relations inside the union made him more realistic about the possibilitie
s for short-term change. Rintoul appealed to his
259 61
Ibid., 2, 4.
62
Ibid., 5, 6.
63
NUPSE, 1961 Convention Proceedings. CUPE
Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5, File 7]; italics mine.
counterparts to see centralization as a longer-term proc
ess which would have to continue after merger. If it
was to be a discipline of amalgamation, however, then a cover would be impossible.
61
ultimately, Rintoul emphasized the want for compro
mise and for finding merger terms acceptable
to both conventions. NUPE believed that, like the merged CLC, differences would be more readily resolved after amalgamation than while the two unions remained offprint organizations. Rintoul
reiterated that the other
necessary condition for the decision of successful me
rger was for NUPSE officers “to give this matter
much more serious attention than they have in the pas
t … [I]t must be given top priority, with meetings held
on a even monthly basis. ” NUPE, for its part, was w
illing to “meet with NUPSE at any time, for any length
of time, at any place. ”
62
monthly meetings were not however in the cards,
however. Instead, both unions retreated to their
respective corners to contemplate their future move
s. The tone of NUPSE’s October 1961 Convention was
quite aloof : they sensed they now had the upper hand and could wait for NUPE or the CLC to make a travel. accordingly, the NEB submitted and the C
onvention passed a rather lukewarm resolution on
fusion, which authorized the incoming Exec
utive Board “to re-open merger talks
if and when
it receives
indication that such talks will be profitable to both
parties. [The Convention] once again confirms its desire
to see a amalgamation between our two Unions, providing
the basic needs of our mem
bership are protected.”
63
It was up to the delegates at the 1961 NUPE Convention
to decide the course of the merger talks.
This convention saw the convergence of two interrela
ted dynamics, one internal and expressed in Rintoul’s
1960 composition, the early external and articulated in the 1961 NUPSE memo on fusion. Both worked to generate a renewed urgency amongst the leadership to
seek permanent changes that would strengthen the
cardinal structures of the union and silence the NUPSE
critics. Buss, Rintoul and the NEB thus came to
260 64
W. Buss, President’s Address, NUPE,
1961 Convention Reports: 8-9; R. Rintoul,
National Director’s General Report, NUPE,
1961 Convention Reports : 29. Both CUPE Fonds [ N
AC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 2, File 11]
65
R. Rintoul, National Director’s General
Report, NUPE, 1961 Convention Reports: 29.
convention prepared to put the association between per hundred
apita, structure and merger on the table: merger
would not happen unless the delegates were bequeath to vote for a solid increase in per head and a significant improvement in national services and political oneness. The NUPE leadership came out with guns blazing, and there was some hard talk about the moral and practical implications of an excessively decentralized
structure. Buss pointed to the selfishness, short-
eyesight and miss of solidarity reflected in the argument
s of autonomists. The failure to raise per capita
sufficiently at the past two Conventions had already
prevented the Union from making the changes to the
servicing apparatus recommended by Rintoul which
would have deflected many of NUPSE’s stinging
criticisms.
64
In their speeches to the delegates, both
Rintoul and Buss emphasized that merger had
received top precedence at past conventions, but this
rhetoric was unmatched by a practical commitment
amongst the membership to do what was necessary
to make merger happen. Rintoul argued that they
“ would not be in a military position to make any substantial
progress towards merger unless and until such time as
our own members are prepared to pay a
per capita tax of $1.00 per month.”
65
In a lengthy commentary on
the offspring, Buss argued that this reluctance was due
to a failure to understand the importance of the
national union to the success of local negotiations, and
to an excessive individualism which valued a few
more cents in one ’ s own scoop quite than the collect
ive power that could come from pooling resources.
He wondered why a belittled per caput increase woul
d always be vehemently opposed, while “[a] one cent
increase in the cost of your newspaper, a software of cigarettes or a box of matches would not bring loudly protests from our members. ” In the end, Buss insisted
that the decision was for the membership to make:
they, and not the leadership, would have to determine
what kind of union they wanted, how much they
wanted amalgamation, and how much they would be volition to pay
for it. Buss was clear on what he felt was the
261 66
W. Buss, President’s Address,
NUPE, 1961 Convention Reports: 8-9.
67
NUPE, 1961 Convention Proceedings: 7.
‘ correct decision ’ in order to create an effective union :
“We can only provide you with the things you are
disposed to pay for … If you want a cheap union, you will have a bum coupling. If you want a firm, effective union to serve you well, you will have to pay for it. You can not reap a harvest if you are not prepared to supply the seeds. ”
66
While the choice was ultimately for the del
egates to make, the NUPE leadership designed what
they hoped would be a feasible compromise. In an
attempt to balance the centralizing pressures
emanating from NUPSE, the matter to
s of the autonomists and regionalizers within the union, and their own
desires to increase national gross and serve
capacity, the NUPE NEB proposed a sliding scale per
caput tax structure, in which ‘ self-servicing ’ locals
would pay 50 cents, while locals reliant on the National
Union for servicing would pay $ 1.00. Such a system
would permanently replace the controversial practice
of grants in stead of servicing with a two-tier per caput structure.
67
It would also increase revenue without
antagonizing the politically herculean autonomists. The backfire against the proposal was huge.
Delegates focussed on the detrimental effects of
a split per head system on the sense of equality
and unity amongst public employees. Following close on
the heels of a heat debate about the $ 3500 granted by thyroxine
he NEB to each of Local 43 and Local 79, after
the 1960 Convention had explicitly rejected such an
arrangement, delegates’ indignation about the ‘special
treatment ’ received by locals who had unilaterally
decided “they should not pay the increased per capita
tax ” spilled over into the per head dispute. many we
re particularly resentful of the ability of large locals to
“ blackmail ” the National Union, and condemned these tacti
cs as “shameful.” The vast majority of speakers
on the question were vehemently opposed to a arrangement wh
ich would institutiona
lize a double standard that,
for many, violated the fundamental trade union principl
es of equality and of the strong helping the weak.
several mid-sized self-servicing locals, such as local 343 in Trail, BC, Local 46 in Medicine Hat, and Local
262 68
Ibid., 7-10.
38 in Calgary, opposed the plan even though they w
ould benefit from it. If the National Union needed
money, they would give up their humble serve gr
ants and pay an increase. D. Gurevitch from Calgary
local anesthetic 38 “ could not see how local 43 or any other large local could not afford to pay an increased per capita tax ” if smaller locals were volition and able. other delegates could foresee the long-run implications of such a arrangement : many more locals would attempt to
become self-servicing in order to access the lower
per capita level, but “ would not be able to provide the proper service which they could obtain from the National Union. ” A hard underfunded National Union
would also be left in the wake of this policy.
Sister J. Laurence from Hamilton
Local 794 predicted a disjuncture between political power and financial
digest : “ Under this proposal the larger unions which
were self-servicing would have the voting power in
the National Union while the smaller locals would
have the sole function of being the financial backbone.”
68
The split per caput proposal was defended by
only three speakers from the autonomist and
regionalizer camps : Bill Overkott, president of Local
43, Max Pierotti, the business agent from Vancouver
City Hall Local 15, and Bill Black of Local 180 ( BCHE
U). Overkott and Black offered the key arguments in
favor of a two-tiered per caput arrangement. For Over
kott, locals employing business agents should simply not
have to pay the same per head tax, and even if they
did, his local could not pay as the membership had
systematically turned down dues increases. Overkott, like the OHEU leadership in their debates with NUPSE, frankincense invoked the democratic will of the local
membership as way to legitimize his opposition to
increased per caput. Whether the delegates liked it or not, a hearty per head increase would force local anesthetic 43 out of NUPE. Black argued that Local 180 had
never used national services, but more importantly
that, since his local was structurally a provincial constitution, it should not be conceived in the like way as a local anesthetic confined to a finical geographic area. He invoked NUPSE ’ s split per caput, which recognized local 1000 as a provincial organization and therefor
e fundamentally different from other locals. Though
263 69
Ibid., 8-10.
70
Ibid., 10-11.
71
Ibid., 59, 76-7.
more elastic than Overkott, Black was besides setting
out a legitimate basis for distinguishing between
different types of units within the union.
69
This debate presaged the final merger discussions, in which both
Overkott and Black – with their arguments and number
s – would figure prominently in blocking the
centralizing tendencies of Little and Eady ( and Rintoul, for that matter ). At the end of this long and contentious first base day
, the Convention bounced the per capita issue to
the Provincial caucuses. The next dawn, all of
the caucuses reported they were most concerned with
preventing a separate in the coupling. The overpower carbon
onsensus was that both grants and a split or sliding
scale per capita were to be rejected as a way of drug enforcement administration
ling with the union’s financial and structural problems.
however, the politically feasible compromise whic
h emerged was not entirely palatable either, especially to
the centralizers. Groups that received rebates,
like the BC and Alberta Divisions and Local 180, were
will to give them up in the interests of one and
“statesmanship”, on the condition that the level of a
coarse per head be kept low, at a maximum of 50 cents.
70
In other words, the condition for eliminating
the rebate system was a 5-cent
reduction
in per capita tax. In this, regionalizers and autonomists found
themselves in a temp and herculean alliance.
Delegates were thus grateful for any increase, and
approved a 60-cent per caput, with the sustenance of
the servicing grant system, without debate. Now on
a roll, autonomists besides carried the day with respec
t to the resolution on mandatory affiliation, which was
opposed by all but two speakers – one of which was Grac
e Hartman, then a secretary at North York City
Hall and a member of local 373.
71
NUPE was back to square one: the minuscule per capita increase was
excessively low to make the desire improvements in national
servicing possible, too high to eliminate the rebate
system, and would only maintain the union ’ s basic needs .
264 72
Ibid., 89-92, 102.
The per caput decisiveness was besides to have a profound impingement on the manner NUPE would move forward on fusion. It was a broad two days into
the Convention before merger – and the exchange of
critiques between NUPSE and NUPE – was discussed.
Beginning on Wednesday afternoon, delegates
had both Little ’ s memo and Rintoul ’ s reaction presented to them, followed by analyses from each of the Merger Committee members. NUPSE ’ s aggressive pur
suit of centralization and bureaucratization led
some of the NEB to denounce “ top-down ” unionism and put the differences within the leadership in greater relief. Black and Jack Raysbrook focussed chiefly
on defending NUPE against Little’s charges, but they
had few practical ideas about how to move fusion
forward. A delegate who had gotten hold of Eady’s
confidential memo on amalgamation revealed that NUPSE wa
s aiming to take business agents on national staff,
which sowed more discomfort amongst autonomists. Fo
r his part, Buss now wanted to see merger “come
from the grass-roots up ” though a articulation convention
where the delegates of both unions would decide the
basis for any agreement, since it was clear that t
he leaders had as yet been unable to find terms that would
satisfy the membership. Two resolutions calling for
the immediate finalization of merger with NUPSE were
then put on the floor, and argument extended former into
and evening session. Even though the delegates were
ineffective to define the basis on which a amalgamation should be concluded, with the alone resolution on the offspring referred to the Resolutions Committee never to retu
rn to the Convention floor, the tenor of the debate
however indicated that the leadership had to find a way to get it done.
72
The ambivalent consensus at the 1961 Conventi
on was that a strong national union was desired,
but would not necessarily be achieved through higher
per capita tax, increased national servicing or
compulsory affiliation to district councils and provincial
divisions. Delegates emphatically voted for ‘unity’ and
‘ equality ’, but only if it would not cost excessively much
and would not require participation in the union’s
average bodies. In early words, NUPE ’ s oneness remained at the lowest park denominator. Per
265 head was besides low to expand the national office in
any meaningful way, while the rebate system left the
NEB to continue to make ad hoc and discretionary arrangem
ents with different parts of the union. In other
words, the structural bases of inequality and resentm
ent remained, despite the best efforts and rhetoric of
conventionality delegates. The convention did not want to
structure inequality into the per capita system in a
clear and obvious way, but by keeping national revenues
low and retaining the rebate system, they blocked
changes which could have equalized serve. Given these decisions in favor of the condition quo, NUPE ’ s Merger Committee nowadays had its hands tied. They had been instructed by the Convention to
produce a merger, whatever it took, but were sent
back to the mesa with importantly less political capital. They could not address NUPSE ’ sulfur concerns about underfunding and a weak central body. They could
not claim that the servicing machinery had been
improved. They could not demonstrate any signifi
cant and concrete willingness on the part of the NUPE
membership to accept increase centralization in deoxythymidine monophosphate
he near future. NUPE’s leaders would therefore have to
find some other room to grease the wheels and fulfill
the 1961 Convention’s instruction to get the merger
done. III.
Into the Home Stretch: 1962-63
The 1961 NUPE Convention consequently dr
amatically shifted the terrain of merger discussions. The
delegates had given the leadership their instructions
– to make merger happen – but had provided little in
concrete terms to use as an incentive to NUPSE. The NUPE Committee therefore arrived at the March 1962 talks, held under CLC auspices, with several impor
tant compromises to make. Over the next year,
these compromises led to the ‘ satisfactory ’ resoluti
on of many of the issues that had plagued the process,
at least american samoa far as the amalgamation committees were coke
oncerned. Subsequent meetings were infused with a
renewed common sense of advance and thoroughly will, and resulted in
the establishment of a working committee of
266 73
S. Little, “Report to the NUPSE National Executive Board on Merger Meeting held
March 1-2, 1962″, March 3, 1962: 4. CUPE
Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 18 ] 74
R. Rintoul, “Report of the National Director to the NUPE Nati
onal Executive Board”, October
4, 1962: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 7 ] 75
Ibid., 2.
76
S. Little, “Report to the NUPSE National Executive Board on Merger Meeting held March 1-2, 1962″, 3.
three delegates from each union to meet at
the 1962 CLC convention to work on details.
73
The committee
went on to meet in April and July of 1962, where
more detailed work on the proposed constitution was
undertake.
74
Whether these arrangements would satisfy
the two memberships remained to be seen.
What broke the blind alley was NUPE ’ sulfur offer to
relinquish the National Presidency to NUPSE,
placing Little in cable to become CUPE ’ s inaugural drawing card. NU
PE, in the person of Rintoul, would instead take the
position of full-time National-Secretary-Treasur
er, newly proposed by NUPSE. NUPE representatives
insisted that the position be equal to
that of the President in terms of
status and pay, thereby avoiding any
sense that one union ’ mho people would be answering to the
other. Moreover, it was later decided that the
National President and the National Se
cretary-Treasurer would both be appoi
nted for a term of four years,
apparently to provide “ stability and continuity in the initial years ”, but in practice besides shielding these individuals from the conventionality ’ south – and therefore
the membership’s – powers of election.
75
Interestingly, Little’s
meet minutes include no remark any on thursday
is dramatic shift in NUPE’s bargaining position;
alternatively, he presents a matter-of-fact list of the department of veterans affairs
rious positions and each union which would hold them.
little reported that the March 1962 gathering washington
s deemed “by the parties” to have been “extremely
successful ”,
76
but no-one could have been more pleased than Little himself, who was now guaranteed the
top job. Given how centrally this decision would affect the post-merger balance of world power, the muteness on NUPE ’ mho depart is deafening. Why did the NUPE delegati
on make this concession? The nature of NUPE’s
own inner leadership rivalries seems responsible, as highlighted by NUPE ’ mho 1961 Convention. Without key internal structural changes in hand, NUPE leaders
had to put their own personal power interests aside
267 77
Crean, 97-8.
78
For instance, Eady proposed a very different executive st
ructure at the June 1960 meeti
ng, one which emphasized lines of
authority rather than regional or
union representation. The NEC would consis
t of the president, a 1st and 2nd vice-presidents,
all
to be elected at large, and the two non-voting full time office
rs. The Executive Board would include 10 regional representative
s,
one from each of Alberta, Saskatchewan, Mani
toba, Quebec and the Atlantic Region, tw
o from BC and three from Ontario ( F.
Eady, “ Report on Current Position re Merger with NUPE ”, 3 ). There is no gain cause gilbert
ven why this proposal did not take hold,
except that it was excessively much a deviation from
NUPE’s regionalized Executive Committee structure.
79
NUPE / NUPSE, “Merger Agreement”, Marc
h 30, 1963: 2-3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 1]
to achieve a amalgamation that the membership widely be
lieved would improve the lives of public employees.
Membership attitudes and decisions therefore shaped how bot
h internal and inter-union rivalries could be played
out. fiddling obviously wanted the National Presidency,
and had eliminated internal rivals like James Clark
through the creation and his occupation of the full-time
elected presidency. As Crean reports, both Buss
and Rintoul were known to desire national leadership polonium
itions, and their relative institutional locations –
half-time President versus full-time National Director – made Buss uncertain about the extent of corroborate he would have in NUPE for the CUPE presidency, given
Rintoul’s experience. Thus, Buss personally had to
make the compromise forced upon the leadership by the 1961 Convention, and once he “ yielded the position to Stan Little for the sake of the fusion … everything fell into place. ”
77
NUPSE ’ randomness capture of the presidency made the disadvantageous representational asymmetry on the Executive Board a lot more palatable. Although respective unlike schemes had been suggested since June 1960,
78
by October 1962 the Committees settled on the
representational stru
cture found in the 1957
CLC Merger Proposal. The Executive Board w
ould be rounded out by three NUPE General Vice-
Presidents, two NUPSE General Vice-Presidents,
six NUPE Regional Vice Presidents and three NUPSE
regional Vice-Presidents. even without the Presi
dency, NUPE would still possess the balance of power on
the National Executive Board, with ten-spot seats to NUPSE ’ s six.
79
Agreement besides emerged on the elder staff postulate
ions deemed necessary for the new union. Using
fiscal information and the current services
of each union as a starting point, NUPSE prepared an
estimate budget for CUPE which would maintain pres
ent operation and address future expansion. Little
268 80
S. Little, “Report to the NUPSE National Executive Board on Merger Meeting held March 1-2, 1962″, 2.
81
T. Lewis, letter to P. Lenihan, August 16, 1956: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 13]
82
R. Rintoul, “Report of the National Director to the
NUPE National Executive Board”, October 4, 1962, 2.
was very careful to point out that the budget was not to
be construed as ‘final’ in any respect, but merely a
means for discussing and negotiating CUPE ’ randomness fiscal needs
. However, the budget reflected the emerging
consensus between the two leadership groups in fav
our of significant bureaucratization at the national
flat. The new union would have five Regional Dire
ctors, two Executive Assistants for each of the
President and Secretary-Treasurer, a Di
rector of Organization, Director of
Research, Director of Education
and Director of Public Relations. NUPE suggested metric ton
he combination of the Research and PR positions, but
this was rejected out of hand by NUPSE.
80
Overall, NUPE leaders seem to have become convinced that an
‘ effective union ’ would require signi
ficant numbers of ‘expert’ staff.
however, while the question of positions had been selenium
ttled, the more contentious problem of who
would do what soon arose. Though it had been agreed from
the outset of the merger process that all
current staff from both unions would be offered em
ployment, there was trepidation about mixing the two
staff complements together, not to mention retaining them in their current positions. early in the talks, NUPE was not eager to have CUPE “ saddled ” with Little
as the Director of Organization, since NUPSE was
seen as far less successful at organizing new workers.
81
This problem was dispensed with as Little moved
into the National Presidency of NUPSE and then
CUPE and the position was instead given to Buss,
82
no
doubt in separate as a reward for stepping apart. A alike reluctance on NUPSE ’ s part to have NUPE ’ s research worker, Gil Levine, become CUPE ’ s Director of
Research was evident by 1962. It had been implicitly
understand from the beginning of talks that Levine w
ould likely head up CUPE’s Research Department, even
though NUPSE had added their own Researcher, Mario Hikl, in 1961. While NUPSE no doubt had good intrinsic reasons to add the new staff position, it
did no harm in the eyes of Eady and Little to have a
campaigner to compete with Levine, whose past communist ties were probably known to the NUPSE
269 83
N.A., NUPSE, Check list of “Points to Watch”, n.d. (1962).
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5, File 14]
84
Gilbert Levine, interview by author,
16 December 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
85
F. Eady, “Report on Current Position re Merger with NUPE”, 3.
leadership. This read of events is indirect
ly corroborated by an undat
ed NUPSE document entitled
“ Checklist of ‘ Points to Watch ’ ”. This number, referring
to many of the issues still in contention circa 1962 and
used by NUPSE ’ s fusion committee, stipulated that “ the Research Director should be person from NUPSE. ” No reason is given in this document, but the
next ‘point to watch’ is “[t]he Communist issue, and
how to control it. ”
83
In other words, Little and Eady likely had knowledge of Levine’s political affiliations and
were manoeuvring to keep him out of an crucial
CUPE staff position. However, the NUPE merger
committee dug their heels in and insisted that, if Levine wa
sn’t taken on as Research Director, there would
be no amalgamation.
84
NUPSE had to give in on this one, but got a consolation prize: a wholly new Legislative
Department with Hikl as Director. The distribution of
senior National Office positions was now relatively
equal, with three going to NUPE and four to NUPSE. Wh
ile this equality was to prevent the domination of
one group over the other, it was besides to
foster a deep level of factionalism.
The appointment of staff positions was besides linked
to which intermediate structures the union should
have, and which identities should t
herefore be institutionalized and repr
esented. The Regional Directors
distinctly reflected the geographic form of organizati
on used in both unions. The question remained: would
there besides be national sectoral groups, like those f
ound in NUPSE? The issue had been raised at the June
1960 meet, where Eady proposed that each massachusetts
jor occupational group should elect a Standing
Committee at each conventionality, to act as “ advisors
to the National Executive Board on their particular
problems and as a align consistency between its locals. ”
85
At a certain point, then, both geographical and
sectoral bodies were envisioned for CUPE. While this particular format seems to have been abandoned by March 1962, NUPE suggested at that meeting the accession of
four divisional or sectoral directors, in the
270 86
S. Little, “Report to the NUPSE National Executive Board on Merger Meeting held March 1-2, 1962″, 2.
87
R. Rintoul, “Report of the National Director to the
NUPE National Executive Board”, October 4, 1962: 1.
88
Kealey Cummings, interview by author,
17 December 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
89
N.A., NUPSE, “Check list of ‘Points to Watch’”.
90
S. Little, President’s Report, NUPSE, 1963 C
onvention, September 23, 1963: 3. CUPE F
onds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5,
File 8 ] areas of hospitals, municipals, school boards and hydro.
86
This proposal is strange coming from NUPE, as
they had opposed sectoral organization from the originate.
However, by July 1962, the joint working committee
had resolved not to mandate the creation of sectoral
directors, preferring instead to invest the CUPE
executive board with the ability to engage divisional
directors “as the need and the finances dictated.”
87
No denotative rationales are provided for the
abandonment of sectoral organization. However,
sectoral groups had the electric potential to provide a knock-down
unifying identity and national infrastructure with the
capacitance to compete with CUPE and form their own national union if they ever became discontent. feel in both unions, with Locals 180 and 1000, had
shown the power sectoral organizations could
accumulate on a provincial basis – how much more ‘ debatable ’ would they be on a national scale ? In this sense, geographic representation may have been a stra
tegy to fragment the development of national
occupational identities.
88
Though provincial divisions could also be
powerful unifying forces, they were also
riven by cross-cutting occupational divisions which c
ould easily be mobilized. Furthermore, the capacity of
provincial organizations to break away from CUPE
was limited, given the unlikely acceptance of such
provincial organizations by the CLC. Lines of authority
were also an issue: since sectoral directors would
potentially clash with regional directors, as their ju
risdictions would “clash and cross”, a choice had to be
made.
89
Finally, it appears that by this time NUPSE’
s divisional boards were no longer playing any
significant function in the union ; between 1961 and 1963 t
hey did not meet, and their role was advisory at
best.
90
Perhaps NUPSE leaders were content to see a defunc
t structure fade away. In any case, since both
unions already possessed well-developed provincial
structures, basing representation on geography was
the easiest solution .
271 91
S. Little, “Report to the NUPSE National Executive Board on Merger Meeting held March 1-2, 1962″, 3.
92
N.A., NUPSE, “Constitutional Position re Service Grants”, Decem
ber 6, 1962: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5,
File 14 ] The wonder of the extent of National Office c
ontrol over local union affairs remained, and was
related to two authoritative issues. The first was t
he status of NUPE local business agents and their role in
reinforcing autonomist tendencies. NUPE drawing card
s now appeared prepared to contemplate potential
“ political suicide ” in order to bring business agents onto CUPE National ’ randomness staff, possibly because both Rintoul and Buss were now shielded from the members ’
wrath. At the March 1962 meeting, “[t]here was
some indication from NUPE that, of the 15 occupation Agents, it might be possible to incorporate a few of them more or less immediately ; and that plans milliampere
y be set out on a term basis to eliminate others.
however, it was clear that sealed units would in
sist upon continuing on the Business Agent structure for
some time to come. ”
91
Little and Eady, dead set against leaving business agents outside the National
Office ’ mho control, developed a schema they hoped would ev
entually bring them into the National’s orbit and,
more importantly, prevent new business agents from
being hired and used as a rationale for claiming per
caput rebates. NUPSE therefore recommended in Dece
mber 1962 that the CUPE NEB should have the power
to make payments to locals employing the now-18
existing business agents equivalent to the annual salary
of a national example. To prevent locals
from scrambling to employ their own business agent and
demand their wage be paid by the national office, the
merger agreement would sti
pulate that no extension
of the occupation agent system could take place unle
ss done with local revenue after meeting national per
head requirements, and that refilling of busi
ness agents would either be done at the sole expense of
the local, or by grant of a national staff representative to the loca
l. Most importantly, business agents
would be subject to the decisions of the NEC / NEB and the National Convention on matters of home union policy.
92
However, this plan did not make it into t
he final merger agreement, not least because of the
272 93
F. Eady, Article 3, Section 3, Draft Constitution for t
he Canadian Union of Public Employees, May 20, 1960: 3. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 26 ] ; NUPSE, Article 3,
Section 3, Constitution and By
laws, October 1959: 2. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5, File 5 ] 94
F. Eady, Memo on conversation with Mr. David Lewis of Joliffe
, Lewis and Osler, re Article III, Section 4 of 1962 Revised #2
draft of CUPE Constitution, March 26, 1963. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5, File 15 ] ; M. Wright, letter to R. Rintoul
,
February 27, 1963 : 1. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 3, File 20 ] major beat it would create amongst NUPE ’ south largest and
most influential locals. The autonomy-reinforcing
influence of local business agents would have to wait for CUPE ’ s post-merger consolidation. NUPSE besides attempted to bolster the National Office
’s ideological and political control over locals,
as seen in their approach to “ the Communist issue ”.
Using their own constitution as a model, NUPSE
proposed a prohibition against the affiliation to CU
PE of “[a]ny Local controlled or dominated by
communists, or fascists, or those whose policies and activities are systematically directed toward the accomplishment of the program or purpose of
any of the above mentioned movements.”
93
Such legalist
attempts to trump locals ’ decisions regarding who w
ould represent them were unsuccessful, however. Both
unions sought legal advice from their respective lawy
ers on the constitutional issue. While David Lewis,
nowadays besides NUPSE ’ s lawyer, strongly advocated ret
ention of the prohibition against Communists “for
organizational and political reasons ”, NUPE ’ sulfur adviser, M
aurice Wright, argued that such a provision would
open the union up to charges of discrimination ; in
any case, proving “communist or fascist adherence”
would be following to impossible, and would therefore vi
olate principles of evidence and due process.
94
Ultimately,
the provision was dropped. In early words, ther
e were pressures towards reformism and political
uniformity, but they weren ’ deoxythymidine monophosphate ( and ar
en’t always) entirely successful, as t
here were variations in how much
different leaders valued ‘ correct ’ ideology versus one ’ second effectiveness as a union activist. possibly ampere shocking as NUPE ’ s giving up of the presidency was their concurrence in March 1962 that CUPE ’ sulfur per head should be set at $ 1.05, then
mething they had resisted since NUPSE first proposed it
in June 1960. Why the committee felt emboldened to agree
to this dramatic jump in per capita for NUPE
members is ill-defined, specially since key blo
cs at the 1961 Convention had clearly been unwilling to
273 95
NUPSE, National Executive Committee minutes
, October 4-6, 1962: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 7, File 1]
chew over it seriously. Suffice it to say t
hat it was not an agreement
rooted in what the NUPE
membership would ultimately accept, unless accompanied by even more far-flung rebates to self- servicing locals. Thus the NUPSE Merger Commi
ttee found itself at the
October 1962 NEB meeting
recommending that CUPE ’ s per caput be set at 85
cents to eliminate rebates to NUPE locals with
business agents.
95
At this rate, the level of revenue of the two organizations would be maintained after they
were merged, with a little extra for expansion. Giv
en the significant commitments made with respect to the
expansion of national staff, finances were bound to be tight for the newfangled union. however, since both Local 1000 and Local 180 ‘s particular condition had to be dealt with, servicing grants could not be dispensed with all in all. With
their significant numbers and potential to form the
nucleus of competing sectoral organizations, both
locals would have to be content with the merger
musical arrangement. In December 1962, NUPSE developed
a plan which would both institutionalize and
legitimate the distinction between local and provincial unions, and allow the NEB to retain a degree of allowance when dealing with different groups of provincial
workers. Rather than establishing a set rate for
respective groups within the union, who would likel
y have different needs in any case, “[t]he National
Executive Board shall have the author
ity to examine the internal servicing facilities and requirements of
provincial Unions, and where appropriate Service Di
visions, and where it is deemed advisable to designate
grants sufficient to maintain such home service as is necessity in stead of direct aid from National Union Personnel. ” such tractability was deemed necessary not only to suit existing peasant unions, but besides to accommodate any possible future additions to CUPE, such as peasant government employees, a promise which Little still nurtured despite the CLC ’ s puerto rico
onouncements on the matter. Vesting these powers in
the NEB was “ the easiest way to accommodate existing groups, and at the same time leave the National Executive Board the flexibility it
needs to promote the growth of the National Union.” The “special
274 96
N.A., NUPSE, “Constitutional Po
sition re Service Grants”, 1.
97
NUPE / NUPSE, Minutes, Joint Session of National Executive
Boards, January 26, 1963: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 4, File 1 ] dispensation for Provincial groups ”, which set their per
capita at 50 cents, was thus another key element in
the fusion compromise. This would constitute an increase of 20 cents for local 1000, and 5 cents for local anesthetic 180.
96
Of run, this placement caused as many politic
al problems as it solved. The lower per capita
for the two peasant unions would plague the NUPE and NUPSE leaderships at their respective 1963 Conventions. While the recognition of provincial
unions constituted a key trade off needed to make the
amalgamation happen, some of the traditionally self-servicing locals were unable to accept the ‘ injustice ’ of the set-up. The NEB ’ s powers to make grants were subsequently expanded to include local unions as a means of pacification. Removing the eminence bet
ween provincial and local unions created the basis for
locals to continue in autonomy-seeking behaviours. How well this would work remained to be seen. The joint amalgamation working committee ’ s efforts we
re held up for scrutiny in January 1963 at a lengthy
joint session of the National Executive Boards of
NUPE and NUPSE. While both executive boards reported
solid votes in prefer of fusion, there remai
ned important reservations from local and provincial
leaders in both unions regarding “ fiscal matters ”,
and the legitimacy of making distinctions between
different types of locals.
97
At this meeting, the effectiveness of the compromise reached was challenged
from all sides, and the political tensions which CUPE would have to face were clearly expressed. NUPE autonomists, specially from the large self-servicing locals, were the most outspoken in condemning the proposed per head structure as excessive
and inequitable. At the forefront of this group
was Bill Overkott of NUPE Local 43, whose local would
merge only “on condition that it retained its local
autonomy, retained its occupation agent and
that there was no increase in t
he per capita payments. If Local
180 and Ontario Hydro got especial consideration,
Local 43 would demand equal treatment.” Overkott
275 98
Ibid., 1-2, 10.
99
Milroy was NUPE Regional Vice-President
from Lethbridge Local 70, while Robis
on was NUPE Regional Vice-President from
Vancouver City Hall Local 15. 100
Ibid., 5.
clearly did not accept the distinctions being made upon which the stallion rationale of a separate per head for provincial unions hinged. As he had argued at
the 1961 NUPE Convention, his local had monthly dues
of $ 2.50, “ which they had tried unsuccessfully to
raise on a number of occasions. He was not opposed to
amalgamation but felt that it would not be potential for him to
get his members to accept an increase of this size in
their payments. ”
98
Bill Black, A. “ Nap ” Milroy, and James Robison
99
made similar arguments on the part of
regionalizers, and with respect to the BC and Alberta
provincial divisions. All three argued that their
provincial organizations functioned much like Locals 1000 and 180 – they were identical effective at self- serve, and wished to retain this structure. They
no doubt worried that the nationalization of servicing
would significantly reduce the ability and condition of public relations
ovincial divisions. Black went somewhat further:
although he repeatedly insisted that he was in favor
of merger and of the compromises needed to make it
happen, he besides reminded those introduce that Local
180 was a very strong organization on its own.
“ possibly, ” he suggested, “ it might have been wiser
to have a national union of hospital workers.”
100
Black’s
precedence was a national consolidation of hospital wo
rkers, preferably inside CUPE; however, in the air now
was the hypothesis that, at some point, Local 180 might
reconsider their choice to go along with merger.
These autonomist positions, specially as articulated by Bill Overkott, were challenged by NUPSE local anesthetic representatives who presented the character against sectionalist concerns. For Bill Baker of NUPSE Local 1, despite besides having sought self-servicing status,
this kind of thinking amounted to maintaining “separate
little islands ” which would be an obstacle to integrity.
Instead, everyone “had an obligation to the parent body
276 101
Ibid., 2.
102
Johnson was a NUPE Regional Vice-President
from Winnipeg School Board Local 110.
103
Ibid., 6.
104
Ibid., 2, 4.
to provide the things that were necessity for everybody. ”
101
Similarly, D. Johnston
102
from NUPE Manitoba
pointed out that “ [ one ] t was not possible for people th
inking on the local level to access the problems and
difficulties which could be seen at the Merger Committ
ee level”, and that failing to think in National terms
would impede the consummation of the amalgamation.
103
OHEU representatives Kealey Cummings and Bert Murray were besides ill at relief with the terms of fusion, despite the provincial union ’ s lower 50-cent
per capita. Cummings revealed that he had voted
against the aim budget for CUPE as it set the level of per caput for locals serviced by the National besides low, which resulted in more resources having to come from local anesthetic 1000 via a 25-cent increase in their per head under NUPSE. Murray even argued that
the merger was being accomplished at OHEU’s
expense, since their contribution to the National Uni
on would increase by $50,000. Dealing with a complex
set of workplaces and employee groups, local anesthetic 1000 ( as opposed to other locals ) “ needed to maintain first rate research for their members ”, which, Murray argued,
would be impeded by the “loss” of per capita to the
National Union.
104
In other words, OHEU advocated increased c
entralization for others so that they could
retain more resources to serve their own sectionalist concerns. other NUPSE representatives indicated they would have difficulties going back to their locals after having “ sold ” the amalgamation on the basis of a proposed per
capita of $1.05. The 85-cent per capita was “on
the cheap side ” and “ fallacious ”, not providing enough field-grade officer
r staff resources and other forms of national
servicing. While everyone understood the want for compromise, respective suggested that possibly the memory of the concede system and the set of hello
gher per capita would have been a superior solution.
several NUPE representatives besides indicated that wh
ile many thought the per capita was too high, the
majority of the membership was now will to pay
what was necessary to make merger happen. Indeed,
277 105
Ibid., 4-5.
106
Ibid., 8.
107
Ibid., 6.
as Baker pointed out, NUPE members “ could well afford
to pay the shot”: wage rates were in general quite
good and they “ were not kidding anybody by saying they could not afford to pay an extra few cents. ”
105
Despite these objections, the joint executive meeti
ng resulted in a vote of confidence in the merger
committee and an acceptance that the two unions proc
eed with merger on the basis of the provisions
discussed above. Little, Rintoul, Buss and Black all re
iterated the importance to public sector workers of
concluding the amalgamation, despite the structural and political problems that would no doubt result. It was immediately the leadership ’ s duty to advocate amalgamation am
ong the membership, to make sure that all were
convinced of the necessitate for compromise. This would
require a great deal of effort, and perhaps ‘better
leadership ’ than had been offered in the by : little be
lieved that members “would be prepared to pay even
$ 1.40 for a impregnable unite organization, if they were
approached in the right way and made aware of the
benefits. ”
106
however, the task of selling the fusion woul
d not be easy, and important factions remained
discontented. The NUPSE Quebec representatives left
the January meeting dissatisfied with the results
and emerged as another authoritative regi
onalizing voice. Though relatively silent at the meeting, Guy
Beaudry of Quebec Hydro Local 300 emphasized the singularity of the Quebec context in which NUPSE had to compete against a very well-funded CNTU organizi
ng in the public sector with a large number of
highly skilled, knowledgeable and well-paid staff.
107
In a March 1963 letter to the NUPSE NEB, Quebec
Director André Thibaudeau explained how, due to this
intense competition, the new union’s per capita
would be insufficient to expand CUPE in Quebec. While
the majority of Quebec locals wanted the merger,
that there was no guarantee they would vote in fav
our at the September 1963 f
ounding convention, raising
the ghost of a split from the new
merged union. Quebec locals were also contemplating the creation of a
278 108
A. Thibeadeau, letter to NUPSE National Executive Board members, March 25, 1963: 2-4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 5, File 14 ] 109
R. Rintoul, Report of the National Director to the NUPE National
Executive Board, October 4, 1962: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc.
MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 7 ]. No rationale is provided for this reduction in Quebec ’ s represent
ation in any of the documents of
the
period. however, one speculates that NUPE may have insisted on having its greater numbers bette
r reflected on the NEB after
having yielded the presidency to NUPSE. strong Quebec provincial council, to be funded by thymine
he difference between NUPSE’s per capita ($1.50) and
CUPE ’ randomness proposed per caput of 85 cents. While this placement would deal with the trouble of underfunding, a provincial council would be “ a state
within the state: a double-headed monster (which is
actually the trouble with NUPE in British Columbia
).” In other words, CUPE would have another strong
regionalizing force within its midst. ultimately, Thibaudeau questioned the wisdom of solomon of allocating Quebec representation on a professional rata basis, given the clear-cut
problems of this membership and the tendency of their
representatives on the NEB to be “ mho
ubmerged” in the Anglophone majority.
108
Significantly, one of NUPSE’s
regional Vice-Presidents from Quebec had been dropped in July 1962.
109
Quebec ’ s guaranteed National Executive Board representation stood at one as a re
sult of this change, putting the Francophone member in
a relatively disadvantageous and linguistically sequester
position if Quebec did not also hold one of the GVP
positions. This consequence was not entirely surprising given the about complete lack of participation by Quebec leaders in the fusion process up to this point ; how
ever, it set the stage for future disputes over the
distribution of regional representation. Thibaudeau ’ mho letter had little immediate impression on a serve that was inexorably coming to a stopping point, but indicated t
hat the nationalizing thrust of the merger had not
eliminated the bases for regionalizing pressures, and
presaged some of the post-merger political issues
CUPE leaders would have to face. The leaders of the new union besides had to deal with
the persistent dissent from within NUPE’s ranks,
namely from British Columbia locals and the Toronto municipal Locals 43 and 79. Meetings with each were held before the fusion agreement was ultimately deoxycytidine monophosphate
oncluded, and a discussion paper responding to the main
questions and criticisms about fusion was distributed
by the NUPE executive. In February 1963, Black
279 110
N.A., “BC Division Conference Critic
al of Merger Terms”, Local 43,
The Observer
3 (2), May 1963: 8. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc.
MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 5 ] 111
J.Taylor, “NUPSE Shows its Hand: ‘Amalgamati
on Whether You Like it or Not’”, Local 43
, The Observer
3 (2), May 1963: 1;
stress in original. CUPE Fonds [ NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 5]
112
B. Stewart, “Around the City Hall”, Local 43
, The Observer
3 (2), May 1963: 6. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15,
File 5 ] and Rintoul spoke to 250 representatives from BC lo
cals about the proposed merger. Again, the delegates
were critical of the “ favoured st
atus treatment” of Locals 1000 and 180,
while their own self-servicing
structures would no long be funded by servicing grants.
110
evening more contentious was the meeting held with the Joint Executive Committees of Locals 43 and 79 in late March 1963, on the eve of signing the amalgamation agreement. In local 43 ‘s newsletter, a presence
-page opinion piece by the editor, Jack Taylor, reported
the joint committee ’ s indignance “ at the cavalier treatm
ent proposed for their locals” which “led to a very
bitter debate. ” Taylor ’ s analysis of the amalgamation agreement
was highly inflammatory: he claimed that “[l]ocal
autonomy would practically cease to exist ” because thyroxine
he National “would retain all rights to appoint field
officers. ” furthermore, he implied that they had been
‘betrayed’ by the NUPE leadership, as both Buss and
Rintoul had senior positions in the new union “ with appr
opriate salaries.” Perhaps most offensive to the
locals ’ leaderships was little ’ s attitude that “ [ a ] malgam
ation would come whether you like it or not”; that
crucial decisions could be made without Locals 43 and 79 was intelligibly uncomfortable, given their influence in NUPE. taylor declared : “ Locals 43 and 79 are
not
going to lump it.
We don’t have to and we
are not going to
.”
111
Elsewhere in the newsletter, Local 43’s business agent, Bob Stewart, encouraged
delegates to the approaching Ontario Division Conventi
on in May 1963 to “rally our forces and prepare our
plans ” for opposing the fusion terms
at the Convention in September.
112
The merger would thus be
concluded in the context of lingering dissatisfaction from local and regional bodies .
280 113
NUPE, “Canadian Union of Public Employees Merger Proposals”, 1963: 3.CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 1]
114
NUPE / NUPSE, “Merger Agr
eement”, March 30, 1963: 4.
IV.
Concluding the Merger: The 1963 CUPE Convention
The amalgamation agreement, finally signed on March 30, 1963 by Little and Rintoul, was a genuine compromise document which intelligibly generated tr
emendous debate within each of the unions. The
leadership had to make major efforts to ‘ sell ’ thymine
he merger agreement to t
he members and guarantee its
approval at the day-long conventions each coupling w
ould hold before the founding convention of CUPE in
September 1963. The fusion agreem
ent made clear that neither it
nor the constitution could be amended
at the convention : it was all or nothing. This st
ipulation reflected an unwillingness to throw open the terms
of fusion to hundreds of delegates – with all thei
r exceptional circumstances to be accommodated – when
it had taken seven years to get the two leadership groups to agree.
113
Anticipating the coming difficulties,
the fusion agreement exhorted all
to “renounce sectional interests or discrimination based on previous
commitment to either one of the merging organizations ” and
to “devote their efforts and activities to furthering
the interests of canadian public employees by strengthening the bonds of one within CUPE. ”
114
The 1963 NUPE Convention did not go quietly, however. Some continued their strenuous objection to the 25-cent increase over NUPE ’ s per capi
ta, and were simply unwilling to submit to any loss of
autonomy that the amalgamation might br
ing. Others worried about the trusteeship powers now vested in the
National Executive Board and their involve on locals ’ ab
ility to run their own affairs. Still others, who had
come to feel emotionally connected to NUPE, feared
the loss of their identity, particularly under a NUPSE
adherent ’ randomness leadership. As Grace Hartman recalled years
later, “[t]here was no great harmony in that last
convention. The decision to merge had to go to a ro
ll-call vote which was most unusual, but there was no
281 115
Crean, 98.
116
CUPE, 1963 Convention Proceedings: 2.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5, File 16]
117
S. Little, President’s Report, NUPSE, 1963 C
onvention, September 23, 1963: 1. CUPE F
onds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 5,
File 8 ] 118
The Public Employee
9 (3), Fall 1988: 5.
question about the concluding decision. It was the art of compromise. ”
115
Though NUPE approved the merger “by
a big majority ”, not everyone was evenly uncoerced to engage in that art of compromise.
116
For their part, NUPSE members were disbelieving
that the new union would be strong enough on the
basis of an 85-cent per caput, and worried that they w
ould no longer receive the same level of service from
the national union. NUPSE ’ s approval of the me
rger agreement, though unanim
ous, was therefore not
without its own reservations. As small put it in
his speech to NUPSE delegates, the NEB did “not look upon
the Merger Constitution and/or the documents relating thereto as being the ultimate. As must be understand in a Merger such as this, compromise must be the key-note. ”
117
For Little and the NUPSE NEB,
the amalgamation could only take place with the expecta
tion that they would eventually be able to transform
CUPE into the arrangement they wanted, an expectati
on they believed well-founded with Little at the helm.
In September 1963, then, CUPE was finally establis
hed, the result of seven years of often painful
and slow negotiations. The newfangled arrangement act
ed 78,317 members in 483 locals, with about three-
fifths from NUPE and two-fifths from NUPSE.
118
The potential of the union was enormous, in terms of both
the numbers of workers they could represent and t
he improvements they could make to public sector
wages and work life. however, not all were equa
lly enthusiastic about what CUPE would mean. The
ambivalent nature of the compromises made was electron volt
ident in the moments after adoption of the merger
agreement by the joint convention : amid the st
rains of “Solidarity Forever” sung spontaneously by
applauding delegates who had leapt to their feet, Overkott led the Local 43 delegating ’ s walk-out from the convention. The local anesthetic was not to return to CUPE
for another two years. Calgary Local 37, Lenihan’s former
local, submitted Late Resolution 92, which characteri
zed the powers of the new
NEB as “ unrestricted and
282 119
CUPE, 1963 Convention Proceedings: 2, 19.
authoritarian ” which “ could end up in the removal democra
tic rights of the local union memberships” and called
for the removal of these clauses before fusion takes space.
119
Of course, such a resolution was disallowed
by the amalgamation agreement itself, and, since it wa
s submitted late, was not even considered by the
convention. In the flush and excitation of making hawaii
story, it was easy to forget that such pockets of
discontent would not fade away easily. CUPE emerged out of a profoundly political procedure
which endeavoured to balance multiple conflicting
interests and visions of unionism. The especial structures which were created as a consequence of these compromises contained within them crucial contr
adictions whose effects would be expressed repeatedly
during the union ’ south consolidation. A key aspect of these contradictions was the way that a particular concept of union routine – focussed on expansion
and central and professionalized servicing of the
membership – was combined with identities and stru
ctures that reinforced localism and constrained the
implementation of a centralist vision. Most of the
conflicts which were to emerge over the next fifteen
years, and which are visible still visible today within
the national executive, the staff, and the position of
regional and local bodies, can be traced back to the fact
that neither the centralist nor decentralist vision
was hegemonic. The National Executive Board was to become an
important arena in which different union visions
and structures were continually disputed. T
he need for equality between NUPE and NUPSE meant that the
roles of and relationship between the National Presi
dent and National Secretary-Treasurer were muddy and
remained to be worked out. For those fearful of Li
ttle’s ultra-centralist approach, it was important to
consolidate the likely influence of
the Secretary-Treasurer as a s
ource of balance, even if lines of
assurance would be equivocal and overabundant with conflict as
a result. Similar dynamics would inform struggles
over the accurate character of the larger and more repr
esentative National Executive Board as opposed to the
283 National President and smaller National Executive Counc
il. Even where conflicts were rooted in personal
concerns over relative world power and determine, they would be well attached to broader conflicts over the power of the leadership
vis-à-vis
the membership.
National staff would besides be a independent web site of the
struggle over the degree of
centralism in the union. While the fusion agreement importantly added to the Na
tional’s staff complement, it did not provide the
fiscal means to realize the expectations attached to
the professionalization of the union. The relatively
low per head was to act as a constraint on the expansi
on of servicing. As well, staff were also divided by
factional disputes, which the equality of numbers from
each parent union only exacerbated. While issues of
personal dominance were no doubt at stake, there were al
so important differences over the appropriate role of
staff in the union, and their relationship to me
mbers and elected leaders. Equality between NUPE and
NUPSE meant that neither group c
ould become dominant, leading to a protracted struggle within the
National Office. ultimately, exacerbating the tensions amongst both t
he elected officials and appointed staff were the
decentralizing pressures from both regional and local forces, whose identities and institutional bases were left intact by the fusion agreement. regional bodies
like provincial divisions were reinforced by the
borrowing of geographic representation on the National Executive Board, but
voluntary affiliation meant that
they would remain systematically underfunded. furthermore, the institutionalization of a per caput rebate system, to be extended at the free will of the National
Executive Board, and the failure to eliminate the
business agent system due to fiscal limitations, meant
that the self-reinforcing cycle of autonomy would
be inherited by the fresh coupling from NUPE. The universe of peasant unions with different fiscal responsibilities to the national union besides sustained the
foundations for resentment and a ‘me-too’ mentality
amongst larger locals. furthermore, the fact that thyroxine
he rebate system could potentially be expanded to any local
284 served to transform per caput into a political
weapon which would repeatedly place CUPE’s financial health
and political oneness in question .
285 chapter 7 : The Limits and Contradictions of
CUPE Democracy I: Consolidating the Merger, 1963-
1967 What had been produced by the amalgamation of NUPE
and NUPSE in 1963? In many ways, it was a
one around the identical general theme of an expansive,
all-encompassing public sector unionism capable of
matching their ever-growing employers by combining a high standard of technical serve with grassroots pressure. however, the compromises needed to creat
e a union capable of carrying out such a vision made
for a profoundly contradictory organiza
tional structure. The merger
produced the ambivalent outcome of
placing an aggressively centralize leader at the head
of a decentralized structure in which much of the
concrete power – over finances and collective bargaining rhode island
ghts – remained at the local level. This structure
was underpinned by a relatively undisturbed culture of
local autonomy, a principle considered sacrosanct
not only by early NUPE locals but besides by the louisiana
rge NUPSE Local 1000. In order to make the merger
stick, a series of loopholes – in the kind of different
ial rates for provincial unions and the right to apply for
servicing rebates – had to be devised to satisfy those as so far unwilling to pay a higher price to develop the central capacities of the coupling. These escape clauses
placed serious financial and cultural limitations on
the extent to which Little ’ s centralizing vision could be implemented, and therefore, in his view, had to be overwhelm. however, divisions over the fusion terms served to mask the actual consensus which had emerged over the type of union desir
ed. Whether centralist or decentralist, nearly everyone wanted a
professionalized business union capable of providing a high floor of servicing to and on behalf of the membership. This is unsurprising given that, in t
he 1960s, unions with ranks of expert cadres were seen as
the most capable of dealing with their increasingly
complex employers. Public sector employers,
particularly at the municipal level, continued to adopt
more bureaucratized methods of dealing with their
workforces, putting ‘ amateur ’ coupling leadership in questi
on. Moreover, CUPE, as the new kid on the block
286 1
It is convention in CUPE documents and discourse to refer to the
head office of the union (and by extension its staff) as “the
National ” or “ the National Office ” ( with
capital letters). I will adopt that prac
tice here when referring to CUPE’s national
institutional apparatus. and hampered by an inferiority complex throw on it by
private sector unions who did not think that a union
of janitors had what it took to be a ‘ real union ’, wa
s particularly keen to consolidate a highly professional
servicing apparatus. While everyone wanted more service, there wa
s no agreement over how such servicing should
be implemented in CUPE. A host of issues had to be
confronted here. First was the definition of a
standard of servicing that everyone, in the interests of fairness and equality, could expect to receive. Some locals, given the higher wages and skill levels of their memberships, had been able to set up identical advanced self-servicing arrangements, to which the mem
bers and their leadership had become accustomed and
which defined the standard they immediately expected from
CUPE. Locals of lower-waged workers, who had been
unable to finance such servicing on their own, immediately relied on the National
1
and the redistributed financial
might of larger, wealthier locals to provide that south
upport. However, variations in local dues bases and the
gloomy per head set at fusion meant that CUPE could not afford to provide ‘ gold standard ’ avail to every local. Tensions soon emerged about whether the Nati
onal Office should provide only the lowest common
denominator of service, or whether they should besides
subsidize the higher levels of service demanded by the
larger autonomist locals. This definition of standar
d servicing was further complicated by the growing
diverseness of employee groups, industrial or occupat
ional contexts, and collective bargaining relationships
within the union ’ s ranks. CUPE had to determine how
to service groups with different needs and wants
while preserving a smell of equality amongst the mem
bership, particularly as inequality could have serious
implications for different membership groups ’ capac
ity to engage in the union’s democratic process. As
well, struggles emerged over which level of the union – the National Office or the locals – should define and direct that servicing. here the long-standing t
ensions between centralists and autonomists defined the
287 2
It is also convention in CUPE documents to capitalize the titl
es of union officers like National President, which I will adopt
here.
argue over whether service should be delivered
by locally-employed business agents or staff
representatives paid and allocated by the National. In early words, the modern union still had to sort out how much and what kind servicing should be delivered and by whom, which would inevitably be articula
ted in terms of the central-local tension and the
counterposition of the requirements
of effectiveness with that of democracy. These questions would have
to be addressed immediately after the fusion, as the
Union was hit with a wave of decentralizing pressure
from locals seeking rebates, which, if not reso
lved, would place serious financial constraints on
implementing the vision which motivated CUPE ’ sulfur creation. however, the political conflicts were not so simple
as national versus local, for this would presume
some oneness at the top. alternatively, the particular ra
solution of NUPE-NUPSE rivalries reached in the merger
procedure led to more quite than less factionalism, wh
ich came to plague the National Office. The merging
of two once break leadership groups resulted
in dysfunctional conflicts based on a complex stew of
personalities and individual power-seeking, commitment
to customary practices from the pre-existing
organizations, and deep ideological divisions. however, fa
ctions were also divided over the particular way
that a centralize service model should be implem
ented. Little pursued a more corporate version of
centralization, with the National President ’ south office clearly on peak and in command, the National Secretary- treasurer a mere bookkeeper, and the National Execut
ive Board a symbolic gesture to representative
democracy.
2
Others like Rintoul, though agreeing with the nec
essity of centralization for efficiency and
effectiveness, desired more democracy amongst the elect, with power shared by the senior leadership. Some members of the Executive Board preferred a moment
re regionalized set-up, in which the National paid for
programmes but the peasant divisions determined
how to implement them in ways suited to their
regionally particular needs. As well, though elect leader
s grew increasingly suspicious of a staff-led union
288 over the course of CUPE ’ s beginning four years, such
resistance did not signal a commitment to grass-roots
unionism either. Rather, staff were to be the mec
hanism through which central control could be maintained
by the elective leadership. This entail that elect
ed and appointed officials would also be locked in disputes
over precisely who was in charge. The factions of the elect leadership wanted to
consolidate power at the top, and moments of
irregular oneness were forged amongst the top officers, parti
cularly in the face of financial crisis in 1965. At
this moment, it was possible to win an increase to the per
capita to fuel the nationalization of local business
agents and the expansion of National services. Howe
ver, given the divisions among them about how a
centralized model should actually function, they c
ould never muster enough unity to prevent limits being
placed on this centralization. Autonomist locals we
re consistently successful at placing barriers to
centralization and to the unhampered use of executive prisoner of war
er. The largest of the locals still retained the
capacity to use the non-payment of their per caput as
a political tool to exact greater autonomy or more
services from the National, again blocking the comprehensive examination
lete centralization and rationalization of decision-
making about the allotment of resources. Hence,
even though there were centralizing trends, there was
never to be a clear post-merger victory for degree centigrade
entralizing forces in the union. However, an important
motion remained : was it enough to block cent
ralization in order to guarantee democracy?
Adding to the confusion was the way that both nat
ional and local leaderships had of reducing to the
simple question of money the very complex issues of how to implement the service model of unionism in an fabulously divers and growing constitution, even though
this would fuel the autonomist pressures which
placed limits on the union ’ second finances in the first plac
e. Convention debates about how much and what kind
of service was need were systematically displaced by
the simple equations of ‘higher per capita = strong
union ’ and ‘ higher per head = less local anesthetic autonomy ’. In
treating these debates this way, little room was left
to explore whether a union could be strong in a non-c
entralized way, or if it was possible to have more
289 centralized services in a way that preserved democratic control and accountability. In the immediate post- amalgamation years, CUPE consolidated a course in its political culture in which questions of structure and baron were displaced by debates about per caput and financi
ng. Rather than focussing more directly on the
merits of a particular proposal in terms of its im
pact on how the union should be organized internally, the
doubt of cost was always ascendant in these debates,
leading to serious confusion and lack of clarity in
CUPE about the nature, merits and
flaws of its own structure.
I.
“A Dozen Praying Mantises”: National Office Factionalism and Local Discontent, 1963-65
The newly union faced two problems immediately upon it
s formation: the intense factionalism which
plagued the National Office, and the strong wave of decentralizing pressures emanating from groups of early NUPE locals. Both situations were the direct
products of the political compromises struck in the
fusion process, compromises which were clearly
unstable even in the short-term. First, the need to
fashion a amalgamation of ‘ equals ’ entail that elected and
appointed positions in the National Office were evenly
allocated to representatives of the two parent unions. however, ‘ equality ’ did not translate into harmony. Partisans on both sides soon set to consolidating their positions and expanding their world power, which cursorily resulted in a deadlock as neither group was able to
establish clear dominance over the whole organization.
Despite the fact that both leadership groups favoured far centralization of the union, the infighting amongst them made it impossible to
move forward together on such an agenda.
second, in order to head off a far-flung revolt amongst NUPE ’ mho larger and more autonomist locals, per capita tax was set at a relatively first gear
level, and the Constitution provided the possibility of per
caput rebates to
all
locals, and not merely those with provincial structures. It was not long before locals
were testing this component of the Constitution. In lighter
of the centralizers’ disarray, autonomist forces in the
locals, districts councils and peasant divisions had much political distance in which to manoeuvre, and were
290 3
Susan Crean’s biography of Grace Hartman, for instance, makes t
he clash of personalities the particular focus of her treatment
of CUPE ’ s early years. able to bring some otherwise centralist NUPE leader
s to their aid in common opposition to the NUPSE
leadership. These forces, concentrated in british
Columbia and Alberta locals but also represented in
lake ontario by local 43, sought per head rebates
and threatened to undo the new union’s fragile financial
stability and political one. In other words, the
personal stakes and conflicts, political agendas, partisan
loyalties and structural features
of the union combined to create a cr
isis atmosphere during CUPE’s first
two years. The available solutions all seemed
to point in the direction of disintegration.
much of the attention paid to CUPE ’ s first ten
has centred on the difficulties experienced in the
union ’ s National Office.
3
Indeed, the seemingly endless cycle of
mistrust, paranoia, gossip and mutual
sabotage is fascinating, and possibly even titillating to therefore
me. Without a doubt, the consolidation of the new
merged structure was an intensely conf
lictual process, and a major aspect of the difficulties in the National
position concerned the kinship between the two full-
time national officers. However, this personal
battle took home in and was profoundly shaped by the
union’s deep structural contradictions. As such,
the common ground between Little and Rintoul in terms of
their vision of the structure and function of public
sector unionism was obscured by their contest and deoxythymidine monophosphate
heir pragmatic articulation with different forces in
the union. Despite the affirmative talk of cooperation at
the 1963 Merger Convention, Little and Rintoul each
desired to have meaning master over the devel
opment of the union, desires which were mutually
exclusive and which finally created “ intolerable condi
tions” in the National Office. This conflict was
attributed at the time and in holocene discussions to
differences in leadership and administrative styles.
however, underlying these differences, Little and Rintoul
actually had much in common in terms of their
vision of an effective and mighty union. As we have seen, both were centralizers in their respective unions, both were committed to the professionalizati
on of union activity and impatient with those who
291 4
Crean, 99.
5
Ibid.
6
Ibid., 115.
challenged or counterbalanced their power. The problem
was that they each desired personal control over
CUPE ; Little, as National President and therefore ‘ natura
lly’ identified as the leader, was unwilling to share and
Rintoul became increasingly resentful of his diminish condition. The Merger Agreement facilitated these conflicts, as it did not explicitly specify the post-merger distribution of ability and authority. The relationshi
p between the two top officers was clearly intended by
the amalgamation committees to be one of equality : both officers were to be paid the same sum of money, and each was to report directly to the NEB rather t
han one to the other. In practice, however, there was
minimal clarity around lines
of authority or status.
4
This vagueness was likely not troubling to Little, w
ho clearly saw the terms of the compromise as
sufficient to get the fresh administration rolling but ultimate
ly temporary. Ambiguity provided space for Little to
claim much ability to himself in line with his opinion
s on effective union structures and the kind of control to
which he had become accustomed in NUPSE. As Crean
described it, the National President “showed little
appetite for consultation or discussion with anyone early
than his Executive Assistant, Francis Eady … To
his way of think, the president was the CEO of
the corporation and the secr
etary-treasurer simply an
administrative policeman. He tended to act on his own and
Rintoul would learn of meetings when the bills came
in. ”
5
Little’s leadership style was very personalistic, centralized, and seemingly unconcerned with procedure
or consensus. He was increasingly possessive of “ heat content
is” union, which reinforced a focus on maintaining his
own personal exponent. He late admitted to the precedence he placed on his own primacy : “ I was prepared to workplace with whoever came along deoxyadenosine monophosphate long as I was at the top of the pile. ”
6
Little’s approach did not foster the
build up of newfangled loyalties either. He kept track of who opposed him, and held a stew .
292 7
Ibid., 99.
8
NUPE / NUPSE, “Merger Agreement”, March 30, 1963: 4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 4, File 1]
9
Crean, 100.
10
Ibid., 100, 104. It is interesting that in his autobiography, J
ohn MacMillan, the future National Director of Organization, ra
ther
unproblematically asserts that “ All these appointments balanc
ed things off to create a uni
ted CUPE” (MacMillan, 133).
Rintoul had different ideas about the relations
hip between the National President and National
Secretary Treasurer, or at least between
this
particular pair of leaders. “I never considered myself second
in dominate as national secretary-tr
easurer and I made that quite clearly and concisely understood. Little
and I were going in as equals so far as status and authority were concerned. ” Rintoul ’ randomness views were much more in line with the spirit of the Merger Agreem
ent, not least because it was the one thing preventing his
quick demotion to a mere administrator. In other words,
Rintoul wasn’t particularly interested in promoting
a different vision of the relationship between leaders and
members, in devolving power to the rest of the
NEB or to members more generally. rather, he was prim
arily wanting to share in the power of leadership,
specially as he was “ used to being in care of things at NUPE. ” Given their oppose personal interests, and despite their coarse commitment to a firm National
Office, “[i]t wasn’t long before the two men fell
to accusing each other openly of being obstructionist
and difficult, even paranoid, each blaming the other’s
staff at every turn. ”
7
Following the conduct of their two peak officers, the blend staff remained highly divided according to their allegiances to the early organizations, despite
the explicit injunction in the Merger Agreement to
put aside loyalties to the rear unions in favor of construction CUPE.
8
While the intention of the Merger
agreement was to balance office in the National Offi
ce by taking equal numbers of staff from each of the
parent unions, this scheme ’ south consequence was “
like putting a dozen praying mantises in a jar.”
9
A “Maginot
Line ” existed down the center of the position and sta
ffers operated in a “climate of gossip and character
assassination. ”
10
In general, the NUPSE side accused NUPE of incompetence, especially where financial
293 11
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, De
cember 12-14, 1963: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 11, File 11]
12
Ibid.; S. Little, National President’s
Report to the CUPE National Executive B
oard, November 21-22, 1964: 5. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 1 ] 13
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the CUPE National Executive Board, Marc
h 8-10, 1964: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG
28, I234, Vol. 11, File 12 ] ; and November 21-22, 1964 : 5.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 1]
14
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 6-7, 1965: 11.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4]
15
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, De
cember 12-14, 1963: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 11, File 12]
16
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 6-7, 1965: 11.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4]
matters were concerned, while the NUPE staff chromium
iticized the NUPSE lack of regard for democratic
procedure and regard for local anesthetic autonomy. extremely poor relations thus reigned between elec
ted officers and National staff, and particularly
with those staff originating from the other union.
Little was already advising the CUPE NEB of the
inadequate flush of communication between officers and
department heads at their first real meeting in
December 1963.
11
The leadership failed to establish regular
meetings between the National Officers and
Department Heads, and of the staff in general, and what meetings did occur merely aired quite than resolved grievances.
12
Little vaguely referred to problems with “
lines of communication” and adapting to the
new administrative procedures designed to cope with the needs of a larger constitution.
13
Rintoul,
however, described the dynamics in more concrete term
s: staffers from NUPSE were particularly resentful
of having to submit requests and expense reports to Ri
ntoul, were even “defiant in ignoring directives and
circulars ” coming from the National Secretary-Treasur
er’s office, and would go to Little when their requests
were denied.
14
Former NUPE staffers were similarly reluct
ant to be managed by Little. There were also
ambiguous references to staffers acting without the
approval of the two elected officers, and in effect
setting National policy, which Little
was particularly committed to stopping.
15
In other words, it was lines of
authority equally a lot as lines of communication that were at issue. While both Little and Rintoul expressed frustration
at the situation, with Rintoul reluctant to
discipline NUPSE partisans “ for concern of civil war ”,
16
and a shared desire for acceptance of the new office
hierarchy, their actual behavior was more contradictor
y. Their personal power interests led them to foster
294 17
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, April 2-3, 1966: 3-5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 9]
18
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
October 22-23, 1966: 6. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 12]
19
The Public Employee
9 (3), Fall 1988: 15.
the lengthiness of these factions in the National Office in the hopes of building a base strong adequate to contest exponent for the entire organization. Littl
e in particular used a double standard for judging the
transgressions of National staffers. A demonstration of Little ’ s own willingness to disr
egard the functional specializations of National
staff was his allotment to Francis Eady, preferably than
to Director of Organization Bill Buss, responsibility for
two major organizing campaigns at Hydro Quebec and the
CBC. After the nationalization of hydro-electric
generation by the Quebec government in 1962, the province sought the
establishment of three large
bargaining units for the stallion work force in 1966.
CUPE already represented some Quebec hydro workers,
who had previously been affiliated with NUPSE and had worked for one of the more than 80 electricity providers that had been merged. The CUPE NEB reje
cted a no-raiding pact with the CSN, who also
represented some hydro proletarian groups, and began, under E
ady’s coordination, a massive campaign to win
documentation of the stallion Hydro Quebec work force.
17
Although Eady’s bilingualism and historic connections
with the ( former NUPSE ) Quebec Region staff made him
a logical participant in the campaign, he reported
directly to Little preferably than Buss about the campaign.
In the end, CUPE won the three bargaining units –
now CUPE Locals 1500, 2000, and 957 – along with
5500 new members at a cost of $120,000.
18
Similarly,
when the CBC workers, who had attempted to join NUPSE in the early 1960s, made renewed efforts to join CUPE in 1966, Eady was put in cathexis of the campaign ’ randomness coordination.
19
These choices reflected Little and
Eady ’ randomness preference for massive campaigns and
also allowed Little to circumvent Buss.
little ’ second conflict with the early NUPE staffers t
ook a most extreme and pernicious form in his red-
baiting of Gil Levine, CUPE ’ s new Director of Research
. Little’s reports to the National Executive Board on
the activities of National Departments reveal the barel
y concealed tension in that relationship. While other
295 20
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the CUPE National Executive Board, June
4-5, 1964: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG
28, I234, Vol. 11, File 14 ] 21
S. Little, National President’s Report
to the CUPE National Executive Board,
November 21-22, 1964: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 1 ] 22
Crean, 100.
23
R. Rintoul, National Secretary-Treasurer
’s Report to the CUPE National Executiv
e Board, November 21, 1964: 11. CUPE
Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 1 ] 24
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
September 26, 1963: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 11, File 11]
departments were “ doing fine ” in Little ’ s assessment, the Research Department was systematically “ struggling under the increased load of the compound organizations. ”
20
Little often could not bring himself to
refer to the Director at all, as
he did when talking of other departments.
21
Behind this tense public face was
an ongoing search for evidence of Levine ’ second Communist ties, in the hopes of driving him out of the organization. Rumours of clothe and dagger meetings
with the RCMP and suspicions of surveillance
fostered even more distrust. little once took Rint
oul to a meeting at RCMP Headquarters in Ottawa,
where they ‘ revealed ’ to him Levine ’ s ‘ insurgent ’ activities and contended that he was still associated with the Communist Party. Rintoul challenged the soundne
ss of the allegations, and the RCMP officer admitted
that they could not bring what they had to court.
As far as Rintoul was concerned, the matter was closed,
but the incidental and the inkling of surveillance tu
rned an already “foul atmosphere toxic”. Moreover,
little and his loyalists would not allow the return to go away.
22
National Office factionalism raged aboard an
equally dangerous political problem emerging out
of the fusion compromise : the dissatisfaction of a silicon
gnificant number of former NUPE locals with the per
caput structure of the new union. This discontent
was expressed in a number a ways. The drama of Local
43 ‘s die from the 1963 founding convention was the visible
tip of a much larger iceberg: twenty-two locals
had in fact refused to join the new union.
23
These locals were concentrated in Western Canada, particularly
in British Columbia where regional and local forms of
servicing were long entrenched, and in the municipal
sector. local 21, Regina ’ s outside municipal workers,
immediately notified the NEB of their formal decision
to disaffiliate from CUPE.
24
Other locals were less definitive, opti
ng instead to withhold per capita tax as a
296 25
CUPE Locals 387, 389, 394, 409, 561, and 718, letter to CUPE
National Executive Board, October 29, 1963. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 11, File 11 ] 26
S. Little, “National President
’s Report to the CUPE National Executive Board on visit to Western and
Prairie Regions January
1964 ”, February 19, 1964 : 2-7. CUPE Fonds [ NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 11, File 14]
27
Ibid., 2.
means of negotiating lower fiscal responsibilities or higher
levels of servicing. In the case of a group of
municipal and educate board locals in the Greater Vanc
ouver area, this refusal to pay per capita was
accompanied by a courtly request that the NEB use it
s powers under Article 7.6 of the new constitution to
grant rebates in stead of servicing.
25
The basis of CUPE’s formation wa
south being tested right out of the gate. This challenge to CUPE ’ s one was so significant
that Little and Buss, now CUPE’s Director of
Organizing, spend ten-spot days in January 1964 investigati
ng the roots of the disc
ontent in Western Canada.
This trip was both a probability to assess the autonomists ’ complaints and an opportunity for Little to connect with the former NUPE membership in British Co
lumbia, Alberta, Saskatchewan and Manitoba. Their
meetings with local, district council and provincial divi
sion officials revealed two distinct but related bases to
the conflict. On the one hand, many locals were x
pressing grievances accumulated from their time in
NUPE : many of them wanted service, but had eit
her not received much from the NUPE structure or had
been dissatisfied with what was provided. This was
particularly true of British Columbia locals, who had
become quite unhappy with the serve provided by the public relations
ovincial division. These locals were particularly
trapped in the self-reinforcing cycle of autonomy : they remained committed to the staff they had hired to fill the servicing col, and they had fiddling religion in the capacity or willingness of the central coupling to provide the kinds of confirm they wanted.
26
They clung to this position despite the fact that their actions were
undermining some of the fiscal conditions which would have contributed towards better national services. The different arrangements of Locals 180
and 1000, the loss of grants under the new CUPE, and
the slowly yard at which national service was being
set up due to financial constraints all aggravated the
position.
27
On the other hand, some locals, particularly
in Regina, were committed to autonomy per se. In
297 28
Ibid., 8.
29
R. Rintoul, National Secretary-Treasurer
’s Report to the CUPE National Executiv
e Board, November 21, 1964: 11-12. CUPE
Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 2 ] 30
R. Rintoul, Financial Report, November 1964. CUPE Fonds
[NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 2]
31
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 9-10, 1964: 12.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 11, File 14]
32
Ibid., 11.
other words,
control
over servicing, and not just its availability, was at issue.
28
As such, simply increasing
awareness of the kinds of services now available through the national structure, which Little and Buss spent much time doing, would never satisfy everyone. The newly CUPE NEB was thus immediately confr
onted with a serious dilemma, and the political
and fiscal implications of a move in any directi
on were unfavourable. In his reports on the union’s
finances, Rintoul made clear that these locals ’ wit
hholding of dues had dealt CUPE “a financial blow which
seriously curtailed [ its ] activities ” and prevented
it from reaching the 85,
000 members anticipated and
budgeted upon.
29
These unexpected financial constraints had cont
ributed to CUPE’s deficit position, which
at mid-1964 stand at closely $ 91,000.
30
In other words, the “great plans” spoken of through the merger
process and at the founding convention had to be scal
ed back and postponed, and further deferral of these
promises risked spreading the discontented and claims for per caput rebates. It was distinctly important to get the hold-out locals into CUPE, but the versatile methods of doing therefore seemed baffling vitamin a well. not only would the rebates demanded monetary value $ 34,000, it was dawning on the NEB that any award made under Article 7.6 would unleas
h a deluge of applications from other locals which,
up to now, had been sitting on their particularist demands in the interests of oneness.
31
Grace Hartman, now
Ontario Division president of the united states and CUPE Regional Vice-Presi
dent, pointed out that self-servicing locals “would
not neglect deals at this time ”, and that even sm
all locals would band together to hire a business agent
and then seek concessions from the National Office. “ Breaking the trace at this stagecoach ”, warned Hartman, “ could mean the disintegration of our whole union. ”
32
Given the political impossibility of granting per capita
rebates, Regional Vice-President from Alberta Nap M
ilroy rightly demanded to know what Article 7.6
298 33
Ibid.
34
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, S
eptember 26, 1963: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 11, File 11]
35
S. Little, “National President
’s Report to the CUPE National Executive Board on visit to Western and
Prairie Regions, January
1964 ”, 10. 36
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 8-10, 1964: 12. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 11, File 14]
actually meant : why not jettison such a provision if
no local who applied for a rebate would ever actually
receive one ?
33
Little and Rintoul’s common response to Local 43’s exit from the union was now revealed as
disingenuous : both had argued that CUPE should not run a
fter them offering deals, as the Constitution
spelled out the procedure for appealing per capita tax.
34
however, that procedure was about meaningless under salute conditions. little ’ sulfur interpretation of the ancestor of the trouble
pointed to a different solution. For him, locals
merely desire services, whether they realized it or
not, and had to be convinced that the “more or less
centrally directed program which we are advocating ” tungsten
ould be capable of providing them. The local officers
were “ misguided ” and irrational in their inability to see why decreasing “ the duplication of effort by a a lot more align and uniform set about ” was in their
interests. This he blamed on NUPE’s legacy, since
“ it was in the past necessary [ for locals ] to group toget
her in almost any way that they could because there
was not a National Union or rear administration to which they could look. ”
35
This sideswipe at NUPE
revealed short ’ mho incomprehension of the inner dynami
cs of the other union and of the fact that suspicion
of central control condition itself was profoundly rooted in some quarte
rs. For Little, such concerns were merely “empire-
construct ”, a regress and selfish attitude to be proven ill-timed by providing the most effective national services potential. It didn ’ t hurt that such
developments would also build his own empire.
In the absence of any other feasible solutions,
the NEB thus voted at their March 1964 meeting not
to consider or grant any rebate appeals until after thymine
he 1965 Convention. Instead, the short-term strategy
was to undermine the footing of some discontented by making “ every effort to provide extra services where necessary and financially potential. ”
36
This risked exposing Article 7.6 as mere window dressing, and, given
299 37
Ibid.
38
S. Little, “National President
’s Report to the CUPE National Executive Board on visit to Western and
Prairie Regions January
1964 ”, 2-3. 39
Local 1000, “Precis of Dues Brief to CUPE”, January 1965: 1.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 3]
the unlike bases of discontented, might not satisfy all
of the claimant locals. Moreover, the financial means
were just not there to raise servicing to the po
litically required level. A longer-term solution would
therefore have to include revisiting one of the thousand
ger compromise’s key components, the 85-cent per
caput tax. Changing the per head tax would irritate not only
the autonomist locals who felt its current level
was already excessive. Such a scheme besides ri
sked provoking the two provincial unions, Locals 180 and
1000, who felt they were being wrongly held responsib
le for the union’s financial difficulties and internal
disunity. Bill Black, Local 180 business agent and immediately
CUPE General Vice-President, complained that the
provincial unions “ were being made into the whipping boys. ”
37
Indeed, Little’s report on his Western tour
indicate how “ disturbing ” the “ particular per head
arrangements” were to the BC and Alberta locals, who
attend only unfair advantages for the two provincial unions.
38
However, neither provincial union would accept
incrimination for the union ’ s deficits, nor would they count
enance an increase in the portion of per capita payable
to the National Office. In January 1965, local anesthetic 1000
attacked the autonomists’ use of their particular
situation to justify rebate demands with a brief to the N
EB. In it, the local reiterated a justification for its
discrete status as a provincial union in terms of
the geographic scope and multiplicity of occupations they
represented, reminded the leadership
not only of the lack of demands made by the local on the National,
but besides of the servicing aid they provi
ded the National on top of per capita, and emphasized its
resistance to any increase in per head for peasant unions.
39
Whatever the legitimacy of this perspective,
the fiscal and political power represented by
Locals 180 and 1000 meant that the solution to the
autonomist locals ’ problem would not come from eliminat
ing the deals with the provincial unions. The NEB
300 40
Pastorius was a member of the former
NUPE’s Windsor Municipal Workers Local 543,
and a General Vice-President since the
amalgamation convention. 41
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
March 9-10, 1964: 8-9. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 11, File 14]
would thus have to provide a coherent explanation for why special per caput arrangements would be left integral, but not extended to self-servicing locals. In the interim, other conflicts over the lo
cus of power were emerging between the National
Office and provincial divisions and locals, whic
h were clearly bound up with the intra-leadership
factionalism. NUPE loyalists on the NEB, many of whom
were also leaders of the provincial divisions, were
increasingly articulating their resistance to Little and his
followers Eady and Hikl in decentralist or regionalist
terms. Given that Little was unapologetically centralist
and easily identified with the national union, it fell to
those like Grace Hartman, B
ill Black, Gordon Pastorius,
40
and even Bob Rintoul to defend those levels of
the CUPE social organization whose autonomy and oscilloscope were being curtailed. Three issues revealed these dynamics. First, in early 1964, Hartman reported to the NEB the allegation that Little had overruled the right of the Pa
rry Sound Hospital workers’ local to decide on if and
when it would take fall upon action. little denied he
had attempted to interfere with the local’s autonomy;
preferably he had, with Rintoul ’ s agreement, merely attack
ed to get the local to delay strike action and submit
to conciliation at the request of the Ontario
Department of Labour, and blamed the misunderstanding on
“ bad communication ” with the Niagara Falls staff.
41
however, the mind that National Officers would intervene at all in local bargain was anathema to t
he former NUPE locals; Little’s actions did breach
previously understand conventions and raised the apparition of an ever-wider National charm on local affairs. second, the withdrawal of local 43 from CUPE praseodymium
ovoked a hard line response from most of the
NEB, including both Little and Rintoul, but Hartman argued that since the Toronto District Council and the Ontario Division had to live with the concrete outcomes of these decisions, they should have some say in
301 42
Ibid., 7.
43
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
June 4-5, 1964: 11-12. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 1]
44
B. Martin, letter to S. Little, January 29, 1965: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 16, File 13]
45
S. Little, letter to B. Martin, February 10, 1965: 2.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 16, File 13]
how the situation was managed. local anesthetic 43 had the c
apacity to harm the bargaining position of other
municipal locals in Toronto, and therefore particular local interests were besides at stake.
42
While Hartman was not
advocating sweeping borrowing of Local 43 ‘s decentralist
position, her comments pointed to the difficulty in
balancing national prerogatives and priorities with tho
e of the provincial divisions and raised the question
of which interests should come first. Since the Ontari
o Division was much more concerned with unity rather
than finances, they suggested that Local 43 ‘s retroactive
dues be waived if they would reaffiliate at the 85-
cent per caput level. however, Little was unvarnis
hed in his response to Local 43’s delegation to the NEB:
the Board would make decisions based on
National
problems and interests.
43
last, the Ontario Division besides came into vitamin c
onflict with NUPSE-led national departments over the
proportional province of peasant divisions in thyroxine
he areas of education and legislative briefs. Beginning in
early 1965, the Ontario Division executive began to stak
e out its territory and to criticize the quality of
servicing from the Legislative Department and the attitude
of its Director, Mario Hikl. In January, Ontario
Division Secretary Bruce Martin wrote to Little, information
rming him that “the Ontario Division shall decide on all
matters of policy relating to legislation and department of education in
Ontario, and any other matters not in conflict with
the National Constitution. ”
44
Little’s reply was, again, undisguised in
its centralism: while coordination with
the Division was surely desirable, they did not, in
his view, have the authority to make decisions over
education. For Little, such a read of the constitu
tion would lead to the “unthinkable”: that CUPE would
“ become a loosely constructed feder
ation of provincial divisions.”
45
The letter only fanned the flames, and
Hartman and Bill Baker, Regional Vice-President and Loc
al 1 leader, were soon complaining at the NEB
not merely of the quality of Legislative
Department briefs, but also of Hik
l’s (and Little’s) presumption that,
302 46
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 6-7, 1965: 2, 17-18. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4]
47
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
June 4-5, 1964: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 1]
48
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 6-7, 1965: 11.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4]
where the National and Division conflicted over the approac
h to take vis-à-vis provincial labour legislation,
the National ’ randomness platform should prevail.
46
The NEB began their preparations for the 1965 Conv
ention in the midst of these unresolved
conflicts over where the locus of restraint would rest in
the new CUPE. While some of the locals withholding
per caput had returned to CUPE with the addition of
staff and the setting up of a regional office in
Vancouver, the outside municipal workers ’ locals
in Vancouver, Regina and Toronto continued in their
refusal to relinquish autonomy.
47
Given the plus response of most hold-out locals to increased serve, little felt empowered in his pursuit of a centralist
response to decentralizing pressures. However, such
moves risked exacerbating the very problems they were aimed at resolving : a brawny dues increase to pay for a meaning expansion in the National Office staff – and control – could generate another wave of per caput strikes and fuel autonomist sentiment even furt
her. Rintoul was understati
ng the situation in early
1965 when he said to the NEB that “ there was a bunch of
work to be done yet in order to consolidate the
fusion. ”
48
II.
Holding It All Together: The 1965 Convention
CUPE ’ second 1965 Convention in Vancouver was frankincense a ma
jor test of whether the merger would stick,
and would have a meaning shock on the direction in which the marriage would develop. As the beginning opportunity to alter the terms of the amalgamation agreemen
t, the Convention would inevitably involve a replay of
the ten thousand of issues never amply resolved in the run-up to CUPE ’ s formation. For both centralizers and autonomists dissatisfied with the necessary compromises, this conventionality was a key opportunity to mould the union according to their own concerns. CUPE ’ s
formal unity encompassed a series of competing and
303 49
R. Rintoul, “Workpaper on Finances”, Marc
h 1965. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 3]; CUPE, National
Executive Board minutes, March 6-7, 1965 : 6-11. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4 ] 50
CUPE, National Executive Board,
Setting a Course
, April 1, 1965: 7. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File 4]
mutually exclusive interests, and finding a more
durable balance between autonomist locals, provincial
unions, the demands placed by increase on the servic
ing apparatus, and Little’s expansionist and centralist
vision of the union would be no comfortable tax. Which flat of the union would develop and exert control remained a contentious issue, but was supplanted by a focus on how to secure the fiscal means to provide an effective and centralized service machinery. thus, in March 1965, the NEB approved Convention proposals calling for a significant expansion in national service capacitance, which would be puerto rico
esented to the members the following month as
Setting a
Course
.
49
The stated objectives of the plan included stab
ilization of finances at a level which would
eliminate deficits and allow for expansion and the accumula
tion of reserves, as well as the provision of a
“ uniform standard of service in all areas. ”
50
Central to this scheme was therefore a significant per capita tax increase, from 85 cents to $ 1.50, a level higher than the highest ever proposed during the amalgamation negotiations, but equivalent to NUPSE ’ mho per head anterior
to the merger. This per capita would also be
uniformly applied, so that explicit character to
the special per capita level paid by Locals 180 and 1000
would no long appear in the Constitution. however,
such a move was not intended to eliminate the
eminence between provincial and local unions, whic
h was defended at length. Instead, the NEB would
negociate immediately with provincial unions to
determine the level of servicing and per capita;
Setting a Course
specified a web per caput of 60 cents for provincial
unions for the time being. The proposals also called for
all local business agents hired anterior to November 22
nd
,1964, to be taken onto National staff, a move long
favoured by Little and Eady but which had not found its
way into the Merger Agreement. The nationalization
of local staff would be part of a significant expansion
in the numbers of servicing representatives from 28 in
304 51
Ibid., 3, 5-6.
52
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, S
eptember 17-23, 1965: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC A
cc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 6].
The apparent cause given for holding a
closed session was the “activities of a gr
oup established in another hotel”, namely t
he
Metro Vancouver Coordinating Committee wh
ich, led by breakaway Local 15, was
attempting to undermine support for the hefty
per head increase. 53
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 6-7, 1965: 8.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4]
54
S. Little, President’s Address, CUPE, 1965 Convention Proceedings: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File 9]
1965 to 51. finally,
Setting a Course
would see a national monthly public
ation mailed to the home of every
CUPE penis.
51
It is far easier to chart the arguments put forward by the supporters of
Setting a Course
, not least
because the NEB voted to hold the convention debate
on the document in a session closed to the public
and the media.
52
As a result, details of the arguments for and against the proposal were never published in
CUPE ’ second 1965 Convention proceedings. rather, the pro-
centralization speeches of the National President
and National Secretary-Treasurer are
front and centre. While this speaks to the power of leaders to shape
their constitution ’ s historic record, the substanc
e and source of dissenting opinions can still be gleaned
from Convention resolutions which were offered as alternatives to
Setting a Course
.
The plan ’ second proponents, and not least little and Rintoul, emphasized that a strong union was by definition well funded, controlled and c
oordinated from the centre. Little and Rintoul were able to reach a
irregular one around their shared centralism ( heat content
inting at what might have been had they been able to
place these common concerns before considerations of
personal power in the long term). Little made his
exemplar of unionism clear to the NEB and the Convent
ion delegates: “Anything constructive … that was
provided in the Labour Movement came as a resultant role of triiodothyronine
he efforts of strong central bodies such as the Steel,
Auto, [ and ] Packinghouse ” workers ’ unions.
53
These unions had “faced up to the responsibility of
reasonably high dues and an adequate per head to the cardinal organization. ”
54
If CUPE failed to follow this
305 55
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, Marc
h 6-7, 1965: 8; CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4] S. Little,
President ’ s Address, CUPE, 1965 Convention Proceedings : 2. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File 9 ] 56
R. Rintoul, National Secretary-Treasurer
’s Report, CUPE, 1965 Convention Proceedi
ngs: 12. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 8, File 9 ] 57
CUPE, National Executive Board,
Setting a Course
, 3.
58
R. Rintoul, National Secretary-Treasur
er’s Report, CUPE, 1965 Convention Proceedings: 12. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 8, File 9 ] 59
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 6-7, 1965: 6.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4]
60
R. Rintoul, National Secretary-Treasur
er’s Report, CUPE 1965 Convention Proceedings: 12. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 8, File 9 ] model, not only would it remain “ a bunch of independents ”
, but it would also never “play a leading role in
the canadian Labour scenery ” as the unite force amongst all public employees.
55
For his part, Rintoul focussed on the more pragmat
ic and internal benefits of the plan. The union
had been forced to put off many “ worthwhile proposals ” due to lack of funds, and had neglected CUPE ’ second “ first objective ”, that is to organize public employees.
56
Furthermore, the nationalization of staff would permit
better coordination, specialization, a more equitable distribution of the cost and provision of service, and the “ elimination … of clash ” and demands fo
r rebates “arising from ‘double taxation’.”
57
Business agents
themselves would be better off on the National staff, for
they would “be able to use [their] abilities to greater
advantage and would acquire broader feel as a solution
of [their] direct contact with other locals and
with other field representatives. ”
58
Quebec Regional Vice-President Roger Lampron pointed to an even
more political benefit of the plan : it would remove
the basis for “empire building by some business
agents. ”
59
little, Rintoul and other centralists besides found
it necessary to replay the arguments about the
nature and condition of provincial unions which had c
onsumed so much of the merger discussions. Rintoul
reiterated not lone the basis of peasant unions ’ dispute from local unions with business agents, but besides argued that such a structure was superscript in terms of
coordination and efficiency. Indeed, rather than being
resentful, local anesthetic unions should be grateful to provincial
unions for the $83,000 paid in per capita – 10% of the
union ’ south revenues – for which they demanded no service from the National Office.
60
Little, however, pointed
306 61
S. Little, President’s Address, CUPE,
1965 Convention Proceedings: 1. CU
PE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File 9]
62
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 6-7, 1965: 7.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4]
63
Ibid., 6; CUPE, National Executive Board
Minutes, September 17-23, 1965: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12,
File 6 ] 64
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 6-7, 1965: 7.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4]
to more grandiose reasons to retain the classifiable st
atus of provincial unions. He linked CUPE’s ability to
make space for unions with different structures and
therefore servicing relationships with the National
office to its capacity to expand its jurisdiction
and encompass the entire Canadian public sector. Both
federal and provincial civil servants were “ awakeni
ng to the need for organization”, but because of their
need for regional or sectoral bargain, would not find a
home in CUPE if it failed to “adapt the structure of
[ the ] Union and the service that it offers to this changing membership. ”
61
As leader of Local 180, Black
agreed : CUPE had to make room for provincial unions
“since provincial bargaining in many sectors was
probable to be the average in the future. ”
62
Despite these emphatic justifications of the
plan from the national leadership, there remained
numerous reservations from several quarters. Some
, like Bill Black and leaders from the Alberta Division
and locals, were convinced that the removal of locally-employed business agents would spell the end of autonomy and “ grassroots leadership. ”
63
Instead of being accountable to locals, national staff would be in a
potent military position to act as agents of the National Offi
ce. Ontario Regional Vice-President Pastorius thus
warned that the National Executive Board “ should watch
for any attempt by a rep to dictate to a Division,
District Council or Local Union on any matter other
than enforcement of constitutional requirements.”
64
Others, like the BC and Alberta Divisions and the majori
ty of their locals, continued to deny the legitimacy
of the distinction made between local anesthetic and provincial
unions, viewed the set-up as “totally unfair”, and
demanded an unentitled undifferentiated per caput that would not
involve off-the-record negotiations with Locals
180 and 1000. If the per caput increase had to be lower, and frankincense constrain the expansion of the union in the interests of integrity, then so be it. If distinct
ions were to be made between locals, then some argued
307 65
CUPE, 1965 Convention Proceedings: 34 (Resolutions 15, 16, 17, 18 and 19). CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8,
File 9 ] 66
Ibid., 33-34.
67
Ibid., 35.
there should be a three-tiered per capita tax system
which would recognize the self-servicing local and
local business agents as legitimate union structures.
65
At the Convention, the complexities of these
positions were boiled down to an argument about the
flat of per head tax.
Setting a Course
was debated, and was clearly the rationale for the per capita
increase, but the document
itself was never voted upon.
66
Instead, the deliberations focussed on the level
of per caput and who was to pay it, not on what to do with
it. In that sense, any explicit contestation of the
centralized servicing model was submerged in a debat
e of how much money should go to the National
Office and frankincense who should be in charge of
that servicing. Moreover, given that
Setting a Course
was not
voted in as policy, the NEB was not held to any particular plan of spending and frankincense could exercise a great consider of delicacy. After closely eight hours of debate bedspread over
two days, and with a standing vote, the 1965
conventionality adopted the NEB ’ s Resolution 9, establis
hing a per capita tax of $1.50, and Resolution 10,
which would apply that per head uniformly. The
debate must have been vigorous and divisive, for Little
found it necessity to appeal to the delegates ’ committedness to the authenticity of established democratic procedure. He said “ that at this unplayful moment we
should all recognize that this was the parliament of our
union. Whether or not we agreed with the final
decisions, having been a party to the proceedings, we
should accept the democratic decision of our convention. ”
67
Clearly Little anticipated what was indeed to
come : a series of locals, particularly from Alberta
, refused to abide by the Convention’s decision and made
claims for per caput rebates. The uniform per capita tax increase was undoubtedly a
victory for centralizing forces. The majority
of delegates had signalled their support for nationally-dir
ected and provided servicing, and their rejection of
308 68
For example, at the 1969 Convention, Ed
Scott from Toronto School Board Local 134
asked Little from the floor: “I heard a
previous loudspeaker make a argument that K
ealey Cummings’ Local does not pay full per c
apita tax. I would like this explained as
I
did not know anything about this. Our local anesthetic
does pay full per capita tax and I think every local should. As this statement was
made, I would like an answer as to why. ” Little declines to
answer, and suggested that the i
ssue would be properly discussed
late in the Convention. ( CUPE, 1969 Conv
ention Proceedings: 33. CUPE Fonds [NAC A
cc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File 4])
69
CUPE, 1965 Convention Proceedings: 50.
the rehearse of “ special arrangements ”, although the size
of this majority is not known. However, the
approval of the new per caput structure did not m
ean the end of the provocativ
e “special deals” that so
many objected to. quite, it took the negotiation of
these terms out of purview of the Convention and the
scrutiny of the membership as a whole. This change w
ould have two important implications. First, it would
put the two provincial unions in a military position to negotiate
per capita tax levels directly with in the National
Union, in a room that other locals were unable to.
While all other locals would be bound by Convention
decisions, Locals 1000 and 180 would have more direct
influence over the amount of money they would
wage to the National. Second, removing the peasant
unions’ per capita from the Constitution functioned to
hide the differential placement made to a
ccommodate these locals, and gave the appearance of
sameness and hence equality. however, when these a
rrangements were revealed to newcomers, it would
always come as a electric shock and would well offend their feel of equality in the union.
68
As such, it would
constantly be potential for certain locals covetous of thes
e differential arrangements to whip up fresh resentment
and misgiving of the centre, as it seemed that the
powerful were able to get their needs met behind closed
doors. Despite the centralizing drive of
Setting a Course
, other resolutions constrained its implementation
or shaped the impression it could have, and tempered the antique
cise of control by the two top officers. First, a
resolution from the NEB which would have full
-time staff representatives and business agents be
considered CUPE members – and frankincense eligible for
elected office – was amended by the convention to
explicitly prevent such a possibility. Second, a reso
lution to increase the minimum level of local dues from
$ 2.50 to $ 3.00 – a key component in making the per degree centigrade
apita increase affordable for locals – was defeated.
69
309 70
Ibid., 46-51.
Third, the NEB ’ s powers of oversight
over the decisions of the Nati
onal President and National Secretary- treasurer were either expanded or explicitly laid out in
the Constitution, over the objections of both Little
and Rintoul ; both General and Regional Vice-Presidents were
now to be present at general meetings of the
National staff, and at staff meetings in their roentgen
egions,. Also, while the National-President and National
Secretary-Treasurer retained province for hiring st
aff, their decisions would be subject to the approval
of the NEB. ultimately, a National Defence Fund wa
s not set up, even though delegates were increasingly
calling for it.
70
The endorsement of the per head tax increase was therefore not a blank cheque to Little to carry out his centralizing vision. rather, the conventionality sought to balance the conditions recognized as necessity to permit the National Union to progress and fulfill it
s mandate with the maintenance of local control and
supervision over staff and National Officers. There would be increased fiscal resources and bureaucratization at the National flat, but there would
be some constraints on the power of staff. In other
words, the 1965 Convention produced another ambiguous
outcome which did not definitively alter the
libra of power in the union. The National Executive would have to manage the discontentment emanating out of western locals, particularly over the nationaliz
ation of their business agents. They would also have
to cope with Little and Eady ’ s continuing attempts to
centralize control in the National President’s office,
moves which could only intensify the factionalism in the National Office. III.
Exit Rintoul, Enter Hartman
Although the 1965 Convention had approved the
per capita increase called for in
Setting a Course
,
it was not immediately clear that the National O
ffice would actually receive the increased revenues
projected by the design. At the NEB ’ s inaugural post-conv
ention meeting in December
1965, Rintoul reported that
310 71
R. Rintoul, National Secretary-Treasurer’s
Report to the National Executive Board,
December 11, 1965: 3-4. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 6 ] 72
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, S
eptember 17-23, 1965: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 6]
73
S. Little, National President’s Report
to the CUPE National Executive Board,
December 11-12, 1965: 4. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 6 ] 22 % of the locals, representing 20 % of the penis
ship, had failed to make their October per capita
payment. Rintoul attributed some of this to
“normal arrears”, which had been exacerbated by the
convergence of a higher per capita tax and many locals ’
low dues levels. It would take some time for local
leaderships to win dues increases that would make metric ton
he new per capita affordable, particularly in the
absence of a higher, constitutionally-mandated minimal.
However, over half of these members were
concentrated in precisely twelve bombastic, self-servicing lo
cals, for whom non-payment was a political statement.
fiscal and political pressures continued to emanat
e from nine locals in Edmonton and Calgary, and
three locals in Hamilton, who, faced with the passing of
their business agents to National Office control, were
using their per caput as a means to negotiate their new servicing arrangements.
71
Some, like Calgary
municipal workers ’ local 38, were threatening to leave CUPE wholly.
72
Delicate negotiations with the Alberta locals about how to bring their busine
ss agents onto the national
staff had therefore begun in
October. These negotiations seem to have been satisfactory for
the majority of the hold-out locals, for Little
reported that “ most ” of their clientele agents had
come onto the National staff by December 1965.
73
however, Edmonton ’ s inside and away civic workers ’
Locals 52 and 30 continued to press for a return to
the old arrangement. Their joint marriage proposal to the NEB
in December 1965 attempted to justify retention of
their own occupation agents and revealed some of the liter
ogic underlying the autonomist position. For these
locals, the business agents were the means through which the membership maintained cheeseparing contact and designation with the local anesthetic leadership. That identit
y would be lost, it was feared, since the business agent
would be “ an employee of a huge massive organizati
on to which [the members] have no close personal
311 74
CUPE Local 52 and CUPE Local 30, “Joint
Proposal – Per Capita Tax and Business
Agents”, December 1965: 2. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 6 ] 75
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, De
cember 11-12, 1965: 7. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 7]
National Executive Committee minutes from
February 19-20, 1966 indicate that both
Edmonton and Calgary locals agreed to this
compromise and their business agents were on National staff by early on 1966. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 7 ] ties. ” however, and more materially,
Setting a Course
would mean a reduction in “the servicing to which
[ the members ] are now accustomed. ” ( According to t
he brief, this level was indeed high: the three business
agents employed by the two locals were said to be
performing so many duties that one wonders what the
elected executive actually did. ) The two locals we
re thus requesting a 33.3% rebate to continue to fund
their own commercial enterprise agents, while at the same fourth dimension importune
ing that “normal servicing provided to all locals …
be extended to Locals 52 and 30. ”
74
In other words, Edmonton munici
pal workers ’ leaders wanted a higher level of servicing than was the norm, but wanted the
National to pay for it while providing them with
extra services. Empowered by the 1965 Convention ’ s credence of
a uniform per capita and, by extension,
Setting a Course
, and keenly aware of the uproar that would
ensue if such a request were granted, the
beak voted to reject the Edmonton locals ’ proposal
. Ed Cooke, Manitoba Regional Vice-President and
member of the big Winnipeg municipal Local 500,
insisted that nationalization of staff did not
mechanically lead to the alienation and decline
in autonomy feared by Locals 30 and 52; his local’s
business agents had been taken onto the national staff, and both autonomy and close ties with the membership were still being maintained. At Grace Ha
rtman’s suggestion, however, the locals were to be
guaranteed in writing that they would have remark
over the assignment of business agents and the
appointment of successors.
75
Nationalization of staff therefore took pl
ace in the context of some restrictions
on the National Office ’ south manipulate. however, the
question remained whether only certain powerful locals
would be consulted on such matters. besides, this practi
ce indicated the union could be forced to deploy staff
in reply to political pressures, meeting the desir
es of the squeaky wheels rather than those locals that
312 76
S. Little, National President’s Report to the CUPE National Executive Board, April 2-
3, 1966: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 12, File 8 ] 77
S. Little, National President’s Report
to the CUPE National Executive Board,
December 11-12, 1965: 6. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 6 ] 78
Ibid., 4.
might truly need aid, and interfering with the im
plementation of more ‘rational’ expansions of
serve. frankincense, six months after the 1965 Convention, most autonomist locals had come on circuit board and were giving the National Office a luck to service their
memberships. By April of 1966, all local business
agents were region of CUPE ’ s complement
of national staff representatives.
76
Moreover, many of the locals
who had refused to participate in the amalgamation were now
coming back to the fold, perhaps realizing the illogic
of going it entirely. Discussions between the Nati
onal President and Toronto Local 43 had begun in late
1965, and Little recommended that the local be required to
pay per capita from the date of their reaffiliation,
that their business agent be taken onto the national staff, and that some clerical aid be provided.
77
thus, as of June 1966, Local 43 was part of CUPE
and had seemingly put aside its autonomist concerns
for the time being. exchangeable talks were taking place with the respective
British Columbia locals who had remained outside
of CUPE since the amalgamation. In this case, however
, the legacy of the local leadership’s ideological
commitments convinced little that he required “ a
certain amount of latitude in carrying on these
negotiations because of the complexity of
the problems and the personalities involved.”
78
By “personalities”,
short meant the full-time officers of TLC Local 28, Jack Phillips and Don Guise, who had both been members of the Communist Party and had, as we saw in
Chapter 3, with their local been kept out of the
mainstream of the parturiency movement since 1950. T
he local had been signalling to CUPE its desire to join,
as “ no effective solidarity was possible ” outside the
new union, but would not apply for membership only to
be rejected. little ’ south pragmatism and desire for expansion won the sidereal day, for he was able to put aside his
313 79
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the CUPE National Executive Board, June
28-29, 1966: 1-2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc.
MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 10 ] This is another
good indication of Little’
s vision of trade unionism.
80
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
October 22-23, 1966: 6. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 12]
81
CUPE, 1967 Convention Proceedings: 33-
35. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File 16]
82
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, De
cember 11-12, 1965: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 7]
anti-communism in order to secure the hark back of
Local 28 and the other Vancouver locals serviced by
Phillips and Guise. It was little ’ south opinion that after tw
enty years of ‘exile’, “the leadership have mellowed
well ” ; thus, he had obtained a commitment that, as CUPE staffers, Phillips and Guise would confine themselves to “ quiet and effective trade wind uni
on activities” and would not use CUPE “as a forum to
expand any policies of the alleged left-wi
ng, be they subversive or otherwise.”
79
On the basis of this
political bargain, TLC Local 28 became CUPE Local 1004
by October 1966, over the unofficial objections of
the CLC.
80
The 1965 per caput increase and the fall of southeast
veral large blocks of members to the CUPE fold
improved the union ’ s fiscal site well.
In four years, CUPE’s revenue more than doubled:
whereas the union had taken in $ 450,000 in its beginning
year, by 1967 it was collecting well over $1million
per annum.
81
This money allowed the union to move away from
the deficits of the first two years, and actually
begin to implement the strategic design envisioned in
Setting a Course
. However, with the financial crisis
forestalled, the footing of Little and Rintoul ’ s tempor
ary unity crumbled, and factionalism resurfaced with a
vengeance. With money and personnel to work with, conflicts returned over who would control these resources and the ends to which they would be dedicated.
In other words, consensus over centralization
dissolved in the face of the issue of who at the center
should be in effective control. The three main arenas
of conflict were between Little and Rintoul, Little and the NEB, and Little and the National staff from NUPE. The major fault line which organized conflicts in
the other areas remained that between Little and
Rintoul. The two top officers explained their problem
s to the NEB in procedural terms: there was ongoing
difficultly in establishing regular “ lines of conscientious objector
mmunication” and well-defined “areas of responsibility.”
82
An
314 83
R. Rintoul and S. Little, “Report to the CUPE National Executive Board on Improv
ement in Communication”, June 22, 1966: 1.
CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 9 ] 84
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 11-12, 1967: 13.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 1]; R.
Rintoul, “ To All Delegates to the Third Convention of CUPE ”, circular, n.d. : 7. CUPE Fonds
[NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File
13 ] 85
MacMillan, 139.
administrative solution, that of
specifying procedures, was repeatedly put
forward, implying that a lack of
clearness was leading to misunderstandings. To that end,
the National Officers met in June 1966 and, without
giving details, reported to the NEB that
they had “reached an understanding on procedures of
communication. ”
83
however, describing the problem and its solution in
such terms only masked what was really going
on and what was at stake for the two antagonists.
An agreement on “procedures” would imply a mutual
recognition of each early ’ sulfur legitimate control over a equality
ticular area of activity. Little later argued that the
“ old allegiances, backgrounds and suspicions ” – particu
larly of the NUPE crowd – got in the way of a
cooperative approach. however, Little did not acknow
ledge how his own actions fostered such suspicion.
Both Little and his supporters continued to operate
as though power was centralized in the National
President ’ sulfur Office. As a solution, any “ underst
anding” between Little and Rintoul was ephemeral because
little did not accept the authenticity of Rintoul ’ s spher
e of control. No doubt each officer had, as Cummings
put it, “ unlike ideas about how things should
be done at CUPE”, but Little’s idea – which involved
spending money without the National
Secretary-Treasurer’s knowl
edge or approval, and sending him the
bill afterwards, angstrom well as unilaterally hiring sta
ff – was a direct threat to Rintoul’s position.
84
The two
clashed over little ’ randomness
de facto
demoting of Rintoul, but also over br
oader “administrative structural changes
that Little wanted to implement. ”
85
These changes concerned the relative functions of the NEC and NEB,
and would imply a decrease in the setting of the NEB ’
s decision-making and the information they would
receive .
315 86
S. Little, National President’s Report
to the CUPE National Executive Board,
December 11-12, 1965: 9. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 6 ] ; Eady, handwritten note at
CUPE 1965 Convention. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.
8, File 5 ] 87
S. Little, National President’s Report to the CUPE National Executive Board, April 2-
3, 1966: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 12, File 8 ] 88
R. Rintoul and S. Little, “Report to National Executive Board on Improvement
in Communication”, 1.
The decision made by the 1965 Convention expanding deoxythymidine monophosphate
he NEB’s oversight role in both staff hiring
and management was deemed by both Little and Eady as praseodymium
ofoundly irrational. In their view, there would
now be significant “ problems arising from … ov
erlap between policy-making bodies and the full-time
administrative structure ”
which had to be eliminated.
86
According to Little, the constitutional amendment
which empowered the NEB to attend staff meetings had
resulted in a “sad experience [at] the staff meeting
immediately after Convention. ” Furthermore, the NEB ’ s
direct involvement in the staff hiring process made
it “ restrictive and chaotic. ”
87
Little continued to insist that the
National President and National Secretary-
treasurer retain the authority to make staff appointment
s, with the NEB to approve after the fact. By June
of 1966, Rintoul and Little proposed in their joint
report to the NEB a procedure which would allow
slightly more input than Little had in the first place env
isioned: Board members and Regional Directors would
receive a drumhead of each candidate, about whom t
hey would be able to submit comments; the National
President and National Secretary-
Treasurer would subsequently select and the NEB would ratify.
88
Rather
than having to deal with ‘ everyday ’ administrative
issues, the NEB would now be freed up to debate and
set the general policy steering of the union. again, the emphasis on rationality, clarity and einsteinium
fficient procedure covered over the push emanating
from the National President ’ s Office to reduce the NEB ’
s role to a body which legitimized executive officer
and NEC decisions via ratification. As a NUPE-dominated torso, the NEB was a lot less likely than the smaller NEC to be well dominated by Little. T
he Convention’s decisions, however, had supported those
on the NEB who saw the body ’ second function as a check on the circus tent officers, and particularly on Little ’ second tendency to unilateralism. Under Little ’ s presidency, mor
eover, the NEB’s policy-making function had remained quite
316 89
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 6-7, 1965: 10.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4]
90
R. Rintoul, National Secretary-Treasurer’s
Report on Administration, June 1966: 8. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.
12, File 9 ] 91
R. Rintoul and S. Little, “Report to National Executive Boar
d on Improvement in Communicati
on”, 1; R. Rintoul, “To All
Delegates to the Third Convention of CUPE ”, 9. underdevelop. Black, for example, argued that the
Executive Board had had “less policy put before [it]
for decision than at a labor council ”, let al
one the possibility of independently developing policy.
89
Finally,
the rigid and apparently rational part between
administration and policy advocated by Little and Eady
glossed over the way that administrative decisions
– like hiring – could have profound implications for the
way policies were developed and implemented. Reducing
the scope of the NEB’s administrative role would
be very utilitarian to Little in his ongoing baron struggle wisconsin
th Rintoul, as he could have much more control over
rent and consequently could select those in agr
eement with his centralist vision for the union.
The ‘ administrative ’ emergence of hiring was puerto rico
ofoundly political, not least because of the ongoing
conflicts between Little and NUPE-led National Departm
ents. Again, the gap between the description of
these problems and their actual contours and implicat
ions was profound. Both National Officers again
described the problem as one of “ misunderstandi
ng of procedures and bad communication” which,
according to Rintoul, rise because staff were not
given sufficient orientation and guidance once hired.
90
Little agreed that what was needed was “ better cobalt
mmunication between Regional Directors, National
Directors and National Officers ”, an unresolved problem ex-husband
acerbated by that fact t
hat regular staff meetings
had not been held since 1965.
91
such diagnoses again elided the core issues, namely
that ideas about the staff’s appropriate role in
the organization were unclear and confounding.
National and Regional staff continued to be deeply
engaged in the political conflict between Little and
Rintoul, and their behaviour and performance was
constantly evaluated through a factional lens. All
believed that staff should be neutral and apolitical –
unless they were working for the ‘ good ’ side. As a
result, staffers’ decisions about whom they would report
317 92
R. Rintoul, “To All Delegates to the Third Convention of CUPE”, 9.
93
Ibid., 7.
94
MacMillan, 138.
to were profoundly political. This was no surprise in
such a milieu: staff could not be expected to adopt the
“ proper procedures ” in an organization in which no degree centigrade
onsensus existed over what procedures to follow,
particularly over who should report to whom on which
issues. In this, the top officers were leading by
exercise : preferably than fostering communication across t
he old loyalties, they continued to circumvent each
other and coordinate and consult am
ongst their pre-CUPE associates.
92
In this context, and given the political implicati
ons of each hire, it is easy to understand why Little
wanted to centralize see over staff appointments aw
ay from the NEB and into the NEC, over which he
had more potential carry. In Rintoul ’ s scene, politicized and biassed decisions about staff congressman appointments were being made which had routinely vitamin e
xcluded Bill Buss, the Director of Organization and
hence the future supervisor of these employees.
93
however, nowhere were the stakes around staff hire clearer than in the process to select
a new National Director of Organization.
The appointment of newfangled national staff was particula
rly contentious since it could tip the balance in
the agency in prefer of one of the groups. Wi
thout question, each group worked to expand their numbers
and establish their laterality in the intra-office
conflicts. Buss’ sudden death in early 1966 opened up the
politically explosive return of his replacement. If ‘ bal
ance’ in the National Office was to be preserved as per
the Merger Agreement, Rintoul and the NUPE staffers
argued, the position should go to a NUPE person.
The elementary campaigner under consideration was lambert
ong-time NUPE activist, dynamic organizer and now
Atlantic Regional Director John “ Lofty ” MacM
illan. Although another NUPE adherent, Ontario Regional
Director Bill Acton, was known to want the job, “ the NUPE people were worry … that he would go over to the other side, to the Stan Little side, and then t
he balance of power would be out of ‘whack’ again.”
94
Little,
on the other hired hand, wanted the position to go to his powe
rful Executive Assistant, Francis Eady. Eady was
318 95
Crean, 128.
96
MacMillan, 138.
97
R. Rintoul, “To All Delegates to the Third Convention of CUPE”, 9.
98
Crean, 116.
99
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
October 22-23, 1966: 17. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 12]
100
Gilbert Levine, interview by author,
16 December 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
fiddling ’ sulfur connection to the increasingly mighty Quebec,
and, as we have seen, also on board with the kind
of organizing Little had always pursued : top-down assim
ilations of large units, or massive campaigns that
would bring large numbers of dues-paying members into
the fold in one fell swoop. Eady also believed
powerfully in the need to rationalize the Canadian labor
movement, which justified the continued pursuit of
provincial and federal government employees, as he ex
pressed in the CUPE brief he wrote for the CLC’s
1967 Commission on Restructuring.
95
MacMillan later reported that Buss’ death was seen by Little as “the
time to move ” to change the remainder in the National Office.
96
As a result of these conflicting aims, the
appointment took a fully year to make, which Rintoul a
lleged was the result of Little’s use of “every kind of
delaying tactic to see that this position would remain unfilled. ”
97
Given MacMillan’s reputation, “Little’s
reluctance to bring such a high-powered NUPE enthusiast into
national office” was certainly at the root of this
delay.
98
Though the NEB narrowly approved the NEC’s recommendation to hire MacMillan in October
1966, the decision was so polarizing that person moved
that MacMillan “be required to affirm his loyalty
to CUPE ” as a condition of his appointment.
99
While the motion was defeated, it is indicative of a
willingness to continue to fight even once a decision was made. These three conflicts – over the relative power
of Little and Rintoul, the responsibilities of the NEB,
and the appropriate function of staff – converged in an ex-wife
plosive way with Rintoul’s resignation in February
1967. While the resignation was formally and vaguely
attributed to “health reasons”, Rintoul’s lack of
control in the National Office and his ongoing margi
nalization by Little was literally making him sick.
100
With
the coupling ’ s most important conventionality – and its first elevated railway
ection for executive officers – a mere eight months
aside, the membership was being signalled that the amalgamation
was not holding at the top. Rintoul’s exit was
319 101
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, Ma
rch 11-12, 1967: 1-3, 13. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 1]
inevitably polarizing and usher in an unrestrained str
uggle between the two factions over the leadership
and therefore the future growth of CUPE. Rintoul ’ s decisiveness to leave thus provoked “ an
uproar”, particularly amongst the NEB who seemed
ill-informed about the details of the conflict. Board mem
bers were disoriented in the face of the NEC’s plan
for dealing with the crisis. The NEC recommended thymine
hat “the resignation be received but not acted upon.”
alternatively, Rintoul would take a combination of vacation time and paid leave of absence. In a gesture of cross-factional oneness, General Vice-President Keal
ey Cummings had nominated Grace Hartman as Acting
National Secretary-Treasurer, and thymine
he two recommendations were put forward jointly. It was hoped that
postponement of Rintoul ’ s ‘ actual ’ resignation and the presentation of a ready-made solution would allow the National leadership to avoid open discussion of events
in the National Office. However, the NEB was
disobliging, and repeatedly demanded information
rmation which would allow them to “vote intelligently” on the
motion. Ontario Regional Vice-President Bruce Martin in
sisted that it was “unfair” of the NEC “to put the
matter before the Board in this fashion. ” however,
“clearing up the stories and rumours” was precisely
what the NEC – and Little and Cummings in particular – tungsten
anted to avoid. Little’s distrust and suspicion of
the NEB as an irrepressible body was reflected in hello
s impatience in the face of repeated requests for
information, which he claimed would merely lead
to a “long rehash”. Cummings backed this position,
arguing that “ detail could hurt individuals and hurt the organization. ” The NEC had “ gone into a draw of detail ” the previous sidereal day, and intelligibly Little was conscious of
the damage such stories would do to his electoral
chances once they began circulating amongst local lambert
eaders and the general membership. However, the
NEB refused to approve the NEC ’ randomness solution without thus
me greater sense of the problem and who exactly
was responsible for it.
101
320 102
Ibid., 12-14.
103
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
June 24-25, 1967: 7. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 2]
104
R. Rintoul, “To All Delegates to the Third Convention of CUPE”.
105
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, July
29-30, 1967: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 3] S. Little,
“ Statement by the National President, Canadian Union of Public Employees, regarding the adverse
publicity resulting from a
text file distributed by the former National
Secretary-Treasurer”, S
eptember 1967. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46, File 11 ] 106
CUPE, 1967 Convention Proceedings: 10.
Rintoul, Little and Cummings therefore provided a very
general interpretation on the nature of the
conflicts, which emphasized the inability to share power
, to communicate and coordinate, and the resulting
bitterness between the National Officers and their staff.
This rendition of the problems failed to explore
whose behavior was at root blameworthy, leaving some
NEB members like Alex Josey unsatisfied. The Board
was frankincense evenly split on whether to approve the NE
C’s recommendation, and Little had to cast the tie-
breaking vote – in favor.
102
This was not the end of the crisis, however, as a motion by Cummings at the
Board ’ s June meet led to “ reconsideration of legal action regarding Rintoul ’ south resignation. ”
103
The NEB
received a far more detailed report of the problems at
their July special meeting, as Rintoul circulated a
14-page document detailing the meaning of Little ’ s ac
tions as he saw them, and the manner in which they
had sown discord amongst the National Officers and sta
ff. Rintoul claimed that Little had used the Union’s
staff and membership for personal political gain, gas constant
educed the role of the National Executive Board and
provided them with sanitized and distorted inform
ation, interfered with local union bargaining and the
operation of National Convention, made biassed and polonium
litical decisions in staff hirings, and spent funds
without discussion with the Na
tional Secretary-Treasurer.
104
Little rebutted these claims; however, there
remains no record of his response, for all the documents from one and a one-half days of deliberation were “ torn up and placed in newspaper containers for destruction. ”
105
At this converge, the Board decided to formally accept Rintoul ’ second resignation, making him a “ retire [ member ] on pension vitamin a far as CUPE was concerned. ”
106
321 107
Coffey, originally a member of Toronto Local 79, was br
ought on the NUPE staff as Rintoul’s assistant in August 1958.
108
Crean, 103-5.
In this heated and polarized context, the NEB was besides charged with a decision about the raw National Director of Public Relations. The consequence of this decision was to highlight the contradictory expectations of staff and the politicize criteria used to evaluate them. The day after Rintoul ’ s resignation announcement, the NEB was to vote on a replacement for Roy Laberge. The National Officers, unsurprisingly, had been unable to agree on a campaigner, reflecting their arrant deadlock and bounce the decision to the NEB. In this intensely factiona
lized climate, the NEB split as expected, and when Little
called the vote a tie, as chair he cast his vote in
favour of the NUPSE candidate, Norm Simon, a former
labor reporter for the
Toronto Telegram
. However, while preparing the minutes and reviewing the record
of the vote, Rintoul ’ s Executive Assistant Ben Coffey
107
discovered “ an apparent discrepancy ” in the run which would nullify Simon ’ s lease. He subsequently
contacted all the NEB members by telegram to
reconfirm their votes, and determi
ned that there was indeed an error in the count: the majority had been
against Simon. In Little ’ sulfur scene, an appoint staff
member had no right to challenge a decision by an
elected official ; more importantly, however, it wa
s particularly galling to be publicly called on such an
authoritative ‘ error ’. This attack to ensure the in
tegrity of the NEB’s decision-making earned Coffey an
eleven-day abeyance meted out by Little, who,
in the interregnum between Rintoul’s leaving and
Hartman ’ sulfur arrival, was in complete restraint. Si
mon was hired despite the problems raised with the
procedure.
108
The implications for democratic accountability of
the aftermath of Rintoul’s resignation were
profound. not alone did the resignation lead to more
factionalism and distrust, as well as a crackdown on
Coffey ; it besides produced a set of decisions which, over the long term, would restrict accountability and the run of information about executive discussions. Th
is increased central control over information was
symbolized by a change in the practices of minute-taking :
Little aggressively fought for a reduction in the
322 109
CUPE, National Executive Committee minutes, June 24, 1967: 1.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 2]
110
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
June 24-25, 1967: 7. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 2]
111
Crean, 104.
112
CUPE, National Executive Committee minutes, June 1-2, 1967: 3.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 2]
total of detail recorded in the minutes, arguing
that “too much discussion” was to be found there.
109
On
a gesticulate by Cummings and McCluskey, the NEC voted to
reduce minutes to a consensus, eliminating the
identification of who said what or who voted for what
unless explicitly requested. Also, executive minutes
were now to be vetted and approved by the National Offi
cers before being distributed to members of the
Council and Board. The impact of these decisions on transparency were immediately apparent. Views on the steering of the Union ’ s new hire policy were
completely inaccessible to non-participants: the NEC
was “ to study the hire policy with a see to amending
to the views expressed” – but those views were not
recorded in the minutes.
110
The actual destruction of the July
1967 meeting’s minutes brought this logic of
data control to its ultimate and most unaccountabl
e expression. The NEB’s decisions in this moment
of crisis, flush if intended to free up discussion at the
executive level, dramatic
ally shrank the amount and
quality of information available to the membersh
ip, should they have been able to even procure these
documents to begin with. In some ways, Hartman ’ s approach to the position of National Secretary-Treasurer was quite different from that of Rintoul.
Rather than engaging in a head-to-head pow
er struggle with Little, Hartman
focussed on establishing administrative clarit
y and openness and on breaking down the gatekeeping which
had worked to keep information out of the NEB ’ s hands. To this end, amongst her first acts upon taking office in May 1967 was to conduct a exhaustive review
of National Office documents and operations in an
attempt “ to determine, if possible, t
he cause and source of the problems.”
111
She signalled to the NEC in
June her purpose to place a such a gas constant
eport before the Board at its next meeting.
112
In it she challenged the Board to the reconfirm the duties of the National Secret
ary Treasurer, to direct the two national officers to
bring matters of policy upon which they could not agree
to the NEB for resolution, and to instruct National
323 113
Crean, 106.
114
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
June 24-25, 1967: 7. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 2]
115
CUPE, National Executive Committee minutes, June 24, 1967: 1. CU
PE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 2]; Crean,
106. Officers and Directors to keep the clerical staff out of their conflicts.
113
In her capacity as the organizer of
NEB meetings, Hartman circulated gain copies
of her June 1967 report to the RVPs, a move hotly
contested by Little, who, in line with his desire
to keep National Office dynamics under wraps, would have
had the NEC careful over the report first.
114
Though the NEC was successful in referring Hartman’s
report back to the National Officers for resolving power, as
it “concerned internal administrative matters”, Little’s
gatekeeping strategy was now made impossible for the time being, since Board members could not “ unread ” the report and the NEC could not i
gnore the recommendations contained therein.
115
This,
however, was only the preliminary to an afford battle for command of the union. IV.
Conclusion
Whatever oneness had been forged at the clear over
improving the union’s financial outlook in 1965 had
evaporated by 1967 in anticipation of an all-out elevation
ectoral struggle between NUPE and NUPSE loyalists over
who would control these resources. even though it
may have prevented a more thorough centralization of
the union, factionalism had farseeing been eroding the practice
of democracy, and as it was to play out in and
around the 1967 Convention, would have good negativ
e consequences for the democratic practices and
cultural expectations consolidated in the coupling. At the level of the National Executive, function of the linguistic process of rationality and efficient presidency served to mask struggles over who would possess baron
over important spheres of decision-making, as
well as over staff and other elect officers. The disk
ourse of efficiency justified practices restricting and
sometimes eliminating the flow of information amongs
t the Executive, not to mention the membership,
allowing for some to avoid accountability for the destroy
ive war of position going on in the National Office.
324 The political crisis over Rintoul ’ sulfur resignation in 1967 spawned decisions which shifted manipulate over the written record and significantly reduced
transparency at the Executive level.
furthermore, factionalism meant that the 1967 elec
toral contest would be a war over who would
control the present and future of the union, leading to
a willingness to do whatever it took to win. The
practice of managing conventions, in terms of
location, delegate numbers, convention committees and
debates on the floor, emerged in this context and rais
ed important questions about
whether the Convention
was in truth a space for grass-roots democratic c
ontrol over the union and its leadership. Little’s
characterization of challenges to his leadership as
disloyal mudslinging and destabilizing the organizational
integrity of the Union besides meant
that contested elections would be ex
perienced as a injury quite than as a legitimate serve of holding leaders accountable. finally, staff whistleblowing of some of these
questionable practices was delegitimated in terms of
protecting the union from unaccountable staffers. This
revealed the contradictory and hypocritical attitudes
developing towards the character of appointed officials.
Staff could be ‘political’ when it suited or served
leadership goals or operating on the ‘ gas constant
ight’ side of a factional dispute, but not when raising issues of
democratic procedure or when contesting
leadership decisions with members.
The union which emerged from this period of conso
lidation was therefore fu
ll of contradictions, making it difficult for CUPE to cope with the series of
challenges it faced from within and without. As the
state of matter at versatile levels grew larger, more complex
and more centralized, CUPE found it difficult to create
more centralized forms of representation which besides preserved democratic accountability. This was peculiarly because the type of centralization that was
on offer struck at the heart of previously existing and
localized centres of power without proposing methods
to balance greater coordination with democratic
representation. Given the polarization of options, specially as they were articulated by Little, there was short space to explore alternative ways to combine east
ffectiveness with democracy. As such, what passed for
325 democratic construction in the union was quickly becom
ing reduced to blocking leadership rather than
building a substantive alternative st
ructure that could be simultaneously uni
fying, effective, representative,
and participatory. The inability to overcome autonomist
sentiment would also always place severe financial
limits on the union, making it unmanageable to create the kinds of structures and resources that would be increasingly required to protect and improve
public sector workers’ rights and livelihoods.
326 chapter 8 : The Limits and Contradictions
of CUPE Democracy II: The 1967 and 1969 Conventions
For most of 1967, all eyes in the union were
focussed on the October Convention and CUPE’s first
election for its two National Officers
. Unsurprisingly, given what was
at stake for both individuals and the
administration, this would turn out to be the most cont
entious and bitterly fought election in CUPE’s history.
For those involved in the highest levels of leadersh
ip, this convention would determine not only their
personal power but besides their capacitance to shape the fu
ture course of the union’s development. The election
platforms of the two contenders for National Presiden
t, Stan Little and Bill Black, revealed that there was
distillery no consensus over whether the union should
focus on new organizing and growth or on internal
consolidation and accountability. Though much difficult
to separate out from the personal power stakes and
the longstanding hostility between NUPE
and NUPSE leaders, these different
positions on the importance
and challenges of growth, and whether a large union
automatically resulted in a strong union, figured
prominently in the campaign lit
erature and Convention debate, and pr
efigured later problems the union
would have to cope with. What actually consumed the delegates, however, was
the nature and implications of internal power
relations. The proportional powers of the NEB, NEC and Na
tional Officers, the politics of wielding administrative
world power, the sufficiency of adjective forms of democracy,
especially as practiced at Convention, the proper
function of staff in the political biography of the union,
and the enduring tensions between centralization and autonomy,
particularly over the presidency of a National Defence Fund, were identify questions raised during and after the 1967 Convention. The answers settled on here west
ould determine the future course of events in
authoritative ways. furthermore, these solutions were developed in the context of deep factionalism, which put extraordinary coerce on CUPE ’ s democratic values
and practices and revealed the protagonists’ different
notions of democracy. Factionalism made participants w
illing, to greater or lesser extents, to breach the
327 norms of accept democratic practice to fight field-grade officer
r their desired outcome. Both NUPE and NUPSE loyalists
attempted to use whatever advantage they could,
although Little’s hold over the union’s administrative
power gave him a set of tools to manipulate systemat
ically the structure of the Convention in ways
beneficial to his electoral fortunes. These resources,
combined with Eady’s political savvy, allowed the
NUPSE camp to influence the location of convention,
delegate allotments, and the make-up of Convention
committees, to direct staff about their allow c
onduct during Convention, and to hinder Black’s contact
with the membership through the union ’ s mailing list.
NUPE therefore had to rely much more heavily on
campaign and direct contact with the membership,
which had historically been their strength. However,
local anesthetic and home NUPE leaders were not above attempting to gain some kind of numerical advantage, peculiarly through unconstitutional expansion of local
delegations committed to vote for Black. Their
capacity to do so was, however, much more limited and circulate. The undemocratic impact of factionalism, and its
revelation at the close of the 1967 Convention,
was to send CUPE into a major home crisis of legiti
macy. Paradoxically, the resolution of this crisis was
to provide a greater sense of integrity amongst the leadership, albeit on the quite rickety footing of covering over a jell of unconstitutional decisions made by the
NEB. However, the long-term implications of this
‘ resolution ’ for the rehearse of democracy in CUPE were profound. Decision-making at the executive level was to undergo a meaning centralization such that
elected officials were increasingly shielded from
outside examination and accountability. The membership, and in especial local leaders, were ‘ confirmed ’ in their suspicions of the cardinal leadership and were ready to ‘ discipline ’ them in the boldness of real or perceived violations of basic democratic processes ( like vote
counting), even if that meant they would prevent the
expansion of the very services they said they
wanted. For their part, national leaders increasingly
understood the membership ’ second ‘ democratic anger ’ as
something to be managed or deflected rather than
respected .
328 1
R. Rintoul, “To All Delegates to the Third Convention of CUPE”,
circular, n.d.: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8,
File 13 ] 2
Committee for Stanley Little, “Your Voting
Guide”, November 1967. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46, File 11]
The change in leadership did, however, alter the active in the National Office and paved the direction for a renewed wave of centralization in the form
of both a National Defence Fund and a major programme
expanding per head and National services. however, the reduce factionalism at the top which permitted a more coherent approach around servicing besides wo
rked to exacerbate dormant tensions between
centralist and decentralist forces. In that sense, st
ruggles over servicing, the level of the union to
distribute them, and the question of democratic proc
ess continued to intertwine in complicated ways.
I.
Preparing for a Showdown
little and his followers began preparing for the Convention far in advance of the NUPE partisans, and their set about was both more methodical and s
ubtle. Rather than pursuing NUPE’s complete
excommunication from the national leadership, Little ’ s
goal was to entrench NUPSE dominance while coopting
some authoritative NUPE leaders who could
give the impression of power sharing. In this vein, Bob Rintoul
claims he was approached by Little to run on a joint slat
e and to offer his support to Little’s presidency, in
exchange for which Little would “ deliver the Quebec right to vote. ”
1
Not only did Rintoul reject such overtures, his
resignation made a joint campaigning with Little impossibl
e. Hartman was the logical alternative and was
perceived as easily managed by the quite retrograde and
patriarchal Little. Therefore, the NUPSE group’s
slate for National Officers and General Vice-Presidents included Hartman ’ south name, in minor letters, on their campaign literature with the be caveat : “ This candidate has not indicated her desire to associate herself with this team of officers, however,
her name is included to encourage teamwork and unity.”
2
little and Eady besides concentrated their efforts
on using their administrative power to shape the
convention in ways that would not be immediately six
sible. They began by setting the location of the 1967
329 3
Crean, 93.
4
CUPE, National Executive Board Minutes, De
cember 12-13, 1963: 7; CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.11, File 12];
Gilbert Levine, interview by writer,
16 December 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
5
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the NEB, September 29-October 1, 1967:
1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol.13, File 3 ] ; CUPE, National Executive Board Minutes, Sept
ember 29-October 1, 1967: 1-2.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol.13, File 5 ] convention in Montreal. The apparent bait of Montreal lie in its host of the World Expo that year. however, NUPSE ’ s historically bigger bearing in Q
uebec would also translate into a “large and reliable
base of support among the francophone members ” for Li
ttle, and a Montreal convention would maximize
their attendance.
3
This decision was made at the NEB in late 1963, which NUPE people later viewed as
attest of a long-run scheme to place Little in
a strong position to be re-elected. NUPE people showed
no awareness of the implications of this decision at the time – speak to a certain naiveté, possibly – and the movement was actually moved and seconded by Rintoul and Black.
4
This decision also casts a different
light on why organizing Quebec Hydro was of such impor
tance to Little and Eady: these units would be a
feather in Little ’ s cap, support his sight of a lar
ge and powerful CUPE, and provide a large bloc of loyal
delegates in the election. A series of ‘ administrative ’ decisions through the summer and drop of 1967 had a more immediate and obvious impingement on the Convention. At the CUPE NEB meeting in October 1967, Little recommended two proposals which would alter the Convention ’ s delegat
e composition. First, Little asked the Board to
allow the three Hydro Quebec Locals 957, 1500 and
2000 to seat their nineteen delegates at the
convention, despite the fact that all were in signific
ant arrears. Little argued that
the locals’ situation was
due to their successful however expensive rotating strike in May and June of 1967 ; since they had agreed to catch up on per head by paying for 1.5 months ever
y month, the locals should not be disenfranchised due
to their combativeness.
5
Little was thus asking the Board to waive the section of the Constitution which barred
delegates from locals in arrears for more than thr
ee months. BC Division President and General Vice-
President George Bone and General Vice-President
from Manitoba Ed Cooke, both NUPSE loyalists,
330 6
S. Little, National President’s Report to t
he NEB, December 7-8, 1967: 7. CUPE Fonds
[NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.13, File 6]
7
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the NEB, September 29-October 1, 1967:
1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol.13, File 3 ] ; G. Hartman, letter to J. Rodie, November 15,
1967: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13]
8
Crean, 107-8; CUPE, National Executive B
oard Minutes, September 29-October 1, 1967:
12. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol.13, File 5 ] ; G. Hartman, letter to J. Rodie, November
15, 1967: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13]
moved this proposal, which was passed,
according to Little, “without dissent.”
6
Little also recommended
that the delegations of the six locals with more than 3000 members – Locals 43, 79, 301, 500, 1000, and 1500 – be increased.
7
Little’s rationale was that, while the Constitution specified that locals with more than
3000 members were entitled to an supernumerary delegate for
every 750 members, each of these locals had a
“ major fraction ” of 750, and s
hould therefore be granted another del
egate. Since any constitutional
amendment would only take effect after the Conventi
on, Little believed the NEB could and should make an
interim decision on the matter. The NEB, again on a gesture from Bone and Cooke, granted these locals an extra delegate for each extra 750 members “ or major fortune thence ”, beyond their constitutionally defined allotment.
8
This change added six delegates to the convention, two from NUPE locals and four
from NUPSE ones. These decisions to alter delegate entitlements for the largest locals are particularly concern when examined in the context of the National Officers ’
response a month earlier to similar kinds of activity
occurring at the local flat. The National Office
was hearing reports that an
unspecified number of locals
were attempting to gather unused credentials from sma
ller locals who wouldn’t be sending delegates to the
convention, presumably in ordering to expand their delegat
ions and their ability to vote for their preferred
slate. little and Hartman issued a letter to all levels
of the elected leadership and staff advising that such
moves were “ unconstitutional and will be challenged by
the Credentials Committee at the Convention.”
Since delegate entitlements were designed to ensure
the representation of
small locals and prevent
domination by the larger locals, allowing locals “ metric ton
o supplement their representation by this method of
331 9
S. Little and G. Hartman, “Convention Ruling”, September 8, 1967: 1-2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File 13]
10
G. Hartman, letter to all National Executive Board Members, No
vember 9, 1967: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8,
File 13 ] ; CUPE, National Executive Board
Minutes, November 17-18, 1967: 2, 4. CU
PE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.13,
File 6 ] 11
CUPE, 1967 Convention Proceedings: 7. CUPE F
onds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File 16]; Committee for Stanley Little,
“ The Committee for Stanley Little ”, Novem
ber 1967. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46, File 11]; CUPE, National
Executive Board Minutes, November 17-18, 1967 : 2. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 6 ]. Jack Rodie was a penis of the Manitoba Hydro Worrker
s’ Local 998, while Les Jacobsen wa
s the president of CUPE Saskatchewan.
12
S. Little, letter to all CUPE National Executive Board Members,
November 10, 1967: 1-2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol.8, File 13 ] soliciting credentials from other local anesthetic Unions ” would “ hedge and abort this wholly concept. ”
9
These protestations seem quite disingenuous in light of
Little and the NEB’s plumping of the large locals’
delegations a bare calendar month late. The conflict which emerged amongst the Executiv
e Board over the appointment of Convention
committees besides signalled how authoritative these decisi
ons could be to the conduct of the Convention. On
the eve of the Convention, Grace
Hartman, Bill Black, General Vice
-President from the Maritimes Leo
McCluskey, and Bruce Martin objected to the proce
ss by which committee members were selected: all
were upset that they were not consulted by the Na
tional President before letters were sent out to his
choices for the Credentials, Constitution and Resolutions Committees.
10
However, process was not the
main issue : one could not fail to notice that Little had appointed Jack Rodie and Les Jacobsen, experienced and stated NUPSE and Little partisans, to
chair the Credentials and Constitution Committees
respectively, and that many of the appointed NUPE
people were inexperienced and from relatively less
powerful locals in the union.
11
Little protested that he had been forced to make these decisions quickly, that
Hartman had not made herself available for consultati
on, and that, in the end, no-one from the Executive
had voiced any objections before then.
12
Despite the fact that the letters
to the Executive notifying them of
these recommendations went out in the lapp mail as
those to the prospective Committee members, and
that no delegate list was supplied to them, Little in
sisted that Board members had had ample opportunity to
332 13
CUPE, National Executive Board Minutes, Nove
mber 17-18, 1967: 2, 4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.13, File 6];
S. Little, letter to National Executive Boar
d Members, November 10, 1967: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File
13 ] 14
S. Little, letter to CUPE National and Regional Directors, T
heir Assistants, and Staff Representatives, August 10, 1967: 1.
CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13 ] propose alternatives.
13
Even if this was true, it was clear that
Little and Eady had placed their supporters in
key positions with the power to shape both the
delegate make-up and the future rules of the game.
Little besides used his position as the employer of the
staff in an attempt to control their participation in
the elections in particular, and in the Convention
more generally. Knowing that staffers would be engaged
in the approaching leadership conflict and could have
a profound influence on many delegates, Little sent a
letter to all National and Regional Directors, their a
ssistants and staff representatives to “advise” them
about their appropriate function in the Convention. “ F
air play” demanded that staff not “become involved in
junior-grade politic [ potassium ] ing ”, but quite remain “ fair and imparti
al guides through this pre-Convention period of certain
uneasiness. ” however, for Little, disinterest did not meant
complete non-intervention, particularly in the face
of what he saw as “ unwarranted, undue and sometimes malicious attacks on the CUPE administration. ” Given that “ every smear or cruddy tactic is a reflec
tion on the whole organization”, Little directed the staff to
“ be on your guard and amply display your commitment to this arrangement. ”
14
This intervention indicated two
important things. First, Little possessed both the ab
ility and willingness to use his administrative power to
commune with and implicitly threaten staff so
as to shape their actions in the election and undermine
their ability to be critical of the condition quo. Second,
there was in Little’s mind no distinction between himself
and the administration ’ south integrity and future development. so
me staff were thus faced with the impossible
contradiction of attempting to be both loyal and neutra
l. Indeed, for Little, being “loyal” to CUPE meant
being loyal to him. The sight that Little and Eady were working so har
d to entrench with an electoral victory remained
the universe of a large and potent clientele union,
to be achieved through an emphasis on growth and
centralized, rational, and effective presidency. Li
ttle’s campaign material, issued by “The Committee for
333 15
Committee for Stanley Little, “The Committee for Stanley Little”.
16
Committee for Stanley Little, “Think Bi
g, Vote Little”, 1967. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46, File 11]
Stanley Little ”, stressed the achievements already made
in these areas, and attributed them either to Little
or to the NUPSE-led National Departments. Delegates
were exhorted to “look at the volume of education
programmes we ’ ve had and their high bore. Look at
the proficient and professional standards of the
briefs we ’ ve presented. Look at the sum of
favourable publicity CUPE gets.” The achievements of
Levine ’ s Research Department went blatant
ly unmentioned. Moreover, both CUPE’s growth by
32,000 members over the previous four
years, as well as the improvements in “the calibre of servicing to
the members ”, were attributed not to Buss as Director
of Organizing, but to Little’s “dynamic and aggressive
leadership. ”
15
The members were nowadays being offered more of the like. small highlighted his commitment to “ continued active emergence of CUPE ” through a “ design
of organizing the unorganized within the full realm of
our legal power ”, which would entail “ all-out
mammoth organizing campaigns” like at Hydro Quebec and
the CBC. however, the motto “ one strong union for
ALL public employees” gestured at Little and Eady’s
latent desire to go beyond CUPE ’ s current legal power and bring both provincial and federal employees into the congregation. furthermore, Little promised the delegates “ a personal commitment to continue to devote complete department of energy to CUPE based on the concept of modern me
thods combined with old-fashioned revolutionary
readiness. ”
16
The Committee for Stanley Little also distribut
ed a document entitled “Your Voting Guide”, which
indicated the five candidates for General Vice-Presi
dent on Little’s slate and also advocating this vision,
and listed twenty-two supporters, noteworthy among them General Vice-President Roger Lampron of Montreal municipal workers ’ local 301 and Guy Beaudry of
Quebec Hydro workers Local 1500, General Vice-
President Cummings of Local 1000, John King, the
Vice-President of Local 79,
Fred Plunkett, Secretary of
334 17
Committee for Stanley Little, “Your Voting Guide”, 1967. The G
eneral Vice-President candidates on Little’s slate were: George
Bone ( president of the BC Division ), Ed Cooke ( Local 500 ), Chas Macdougall ( local 8 Halifax ) and Cummings of local 1000. 18
Crean, 102.
19
B. Black, letter to all CUPE Members re: Election of National
Officers – CUPE Convention, November 4, 1967: 3. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13 ] ; B. Black, Press
Releases, November 6, 1967. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol.8, File 13 ] local 43, and Bone, Rodie and Jacobson, presidents of the BC, Manitoba and Saskatchewan Divisions respectively.
17
NUPE adherents like Rintoul, Black, Hartman and the NUPE national staffers had been actively preparing to challenge Little ’ s leadership since January
1967. However, their aims harkened back to their
pre-merger attitude towards NUPSE : NUPE intended to take both of the National Officers ’ positions, a goal they had obviously become more convinced of given the difficulties encountered in working with Little. This “ NUPE take all ” orientation course was reflected in their
slate: deliberations were being held about which slate
could most efficaciously challenge the NUPSE loyalis
ts, not about which NUPSE people they might seek out
to work with. The crisis precipitated by Rintou
l’s resignation only strengthened NUPE’s resolve to seek a
fundamental switch in leadership, and Hartman ’ s ascens
ion to the Secretary-Tr
easurer’s position did not
pacify the growing discontent amongst former NUPE members, leaders and staff with Little ’ s leadership. furthermore, with Rintoul ’ s health taking him out of the
running, a slate of Hartman in her current position and
Bill Black for National President was settled upon.
18
however, these plans were arrived at quite
late in the game: Black’s candidacy was only
announced publicly in early November, with a mere
three weeks to go before Convention, and no NUPE
slate of General Vice-Presidents was on offer.
19
Clearly, the NUPE side had been in some disarray, and
had been unable to engage in the kind taxonomic and long-run plan which typified the Little camp. furthermore, Little was unwilling to provide Black with
a mailing list of convention delegates to enable his
crusade, apparently in the name of comeliness : “ in
order that campaign letters not be sent in case there
335 20
S. Little, letter to B. Black, November 10, 1967: 2.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13]
21
B. Black, “Bill Black’s Program for Progr
ess”, pamphlet, November 1967; CUPE Fonds
[NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46, File
11 ] ; CUPE Local One, “ CUPE in Search of Leadership ”,
Local One News
10 (7), October 1967: 1; CUPE Local 878, “That
elusive Quality ” in
The Custodian
, 1967; CUPE Local 43,
The Observer
, October 1967: 5. All newsletters CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13 ]. These newsletters were collected by Francis Eady and deposited with his files in the Nation
al
Archives. 22
B. Black, “Bill Black’s Program for Progress”.
23
B. Black, Press Release, November 6, 1967: 2, CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13]; B. Black, “Bill Black’s
program for Progress ”, booklet, Nove
mber 1967. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46, File 11]
24
“CUPE in Search of Leadership”,
Local One News
10 (7), October 1967: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File
13 ] 25
B. Black, “Bill Black’s Program for Progress”.
are other candidates as well ”, Little was “ not puerto rico
epared to direct that such a list be forwarded.”
20
Black
therefore had to attempt to reach the membership
via news stories, membership meetings, and local
newsletters. Black ’ s campaign was based on a bespeak review of
the leadership that Little had provided thus
far, portrayed as bumbling, dissentious, undemocratic,
and threatening to local autonomy. One of Black’s
independent themes in the NEB debates – that the
Convention and the Board had been reduced to “the rubber
stamp of the President ” merely “ listening to reports
of what the Chairman has done” – permeated both his
crusade literature and the articles of
support published in local newsletters.
21
Worse yet was the fate of
the membership, who were at gamble of becoming “ cogs
in an organizational union machine” as the eventual
result of Little ’ s near-obsession with numeric x
pansion of the union. While Black undoubtedly supported
newfangled organizing, as evidenced in his remarkable success
in the BC hospital jurisdiction, he did not believe
that such growth automatically conferred upon
the union the capacity to serve new members well.
22
Black
feared that Little ’ s growth program would result
in centralized decision-making, in which “the rank and
file extremity loses direct control over decisions
which affect him” and becomes merely “a source of
increase income. ”
23
Local One echoed the theme that “ intensity is
not measured by numbers alone, as some
people would have you believe. ”
24
In other words, the Black campaign wanted to build “a QUALITY union,
not merely a QUANTITY union. ”
25
336 26
Ibid., italics in original.
27
“Bill Black Supporters”, convention circular
, November 1967. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46, File 11]; B. Black,
Press Release, November 6, 1967. 28
“Bill Black Supporters”.
29
Crean, 107.
30
S. Little, letter to B. Black, November 2, 1967: 1.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13]
Black seemed to be offering a different type of fifty
eadership, promising to provide “strong, fair and
democratic leadership ” with decisions “ made in
the interests of CUPE, and not based on misguided
loyalties to any of the former unions. ” Local
leaders and members would be encouraged “to think, make
decisions, and act for themselves, without
interference
.”
26
Moreover, Black’s supporters pitched him as “a
constructive Union builder, who has demonstrated his
ability to get people working together in a team”; as
the first president of the BC Federation of Labour
after the merger of the TLC and CCL, Black was being
promoted as person with the experience
to complete the merger and unite CUPE.
27
Electing Black would
therefore be both unite and democratize, and woul
d permit the genuine consummation of the merger.
This message had a widespread attract, for Black ’ sulfur list of declare supporters, including Hartman, Leo McCluskey ( General Vice-President from the Mariti
mes), Alex Josey (Regional
Vice-President Alberta),
Bruce Martin and Bill Baker ( Regional Vice-President
Ontario), Wallace Higgins and Bill Overkott, the
presidents of both Local 79 and 43 respectively
,
was twice ampere long as Little ’ south.
28
The late disclosure of Black ’ s campaigning provoked
an explosive reaction from Little. One story has
it that Black ’ s campaigning was only discovered by Li
ttle’s partisans when CUPE Public Relations Director
Norm Simon ran into local anesthetic 79 staff congressman Pa
t O’Keeffe at a Toronto printing shop copying Black
political campaign materials.
29
Additionally, Little received separate r
eports from an Ottawa-area CUPE member
about a touch Black held with local anesthetic union officers in early October.
30
Offended at not having been
informed in person, believing that a clandestine ca
mpaign was underway, and undoubtedly realizing the real
threat to his position, Little fired off a hastily-worded
telegram to Black accusing
him of attempting “to take
the presidency … by underhand and nastacious tactics ”
and deeming his criticisms as “merely political
337 31
S. Little, telegram to B. Black, October 21, 1967.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 17, File 3]
32
B. Black, letter to All CUPE Members Re: Election of National
Officers – CUPE Convention, November 4, 1967: 1. CUPE
Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13 ] ; B. Black, tel
egram to S. Little, October 24, 1967. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 17, File 3 ] mudslinging. ”
31
Little’s inability to accept being challenged and criticized in public, and the negative
implications such reactions would have on the union ’ s dem
ocratic culture, merely confirmed for Black that a
“ contest for [ the ] National Presidency would be most
timely.” Black emphasized that he had for some
months been conducting exploratory discussions with “ s
everal of [CUPE’s] most active members”, and,
despite Little ’ s chemical reaction, that “ members of this
organization will not be dissuaded from contesting national
elections because of personal threats or implied threats. ”
32
Both sides proceeded to Convention in this
climate of hostility and reciprocal contemn. II.
CUPE’s ‘Test of Fire’: The 1967 Convention and its Aftermath
The Convention opened with its usual rituals
and greetings from Montreal-area and Quebec
political and labor motion dignitaries. however, it wasn ’ t long before the fight was engaged. little used his presidential address and single reserve on the C
onvention’s attention to frame the union’s issues,
make an undisputed election address, and preemptive bid and
undercut his critics. Little trumpeted that the
membership and servicing targets for 1969 laid out in
Setting a Course
had already been exceeded,
echoing his campaign message. He was, however, careful to
take the sting out of Black’s criticisms that he
was growth-obsessed, wanting to be “ the foremost to
concede that mere numbers are not enough and that we
must continue to improve the efficiency of our organiza
tion, particularly in the areas involving service.”
ultimately, Little made a confounding statement
about the way delegates should understand the internal
conflicts they had no doubt listen about. While claiming
that “the buck stops here” with the President, he
338 33
CUPE, 1967 Convention Proceedings: 3, 5. CU
PE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File 16]. Note that one of the
problems raised by Black that Little
didn’t
deal with was accountability.
34
Ibid., 7.
argued that if he was creditworthy for all problems, he
should also be credited with all successes. In this
confusing manner, Little was refusing to shoulder responsibility for CUPE ’ randomness problems.
33
The fireworks began over a normally everyday praseodymium
ocedural matter, the presentation of the
Credentials Committee ’ s report, which actually signall
ed attempts to regulate access to the Convention
floor. The Committee was asked whether all of the
local unions represented there were in good standing
according to Constitution. Little replied that “ in the
eyes of the Executive Board, yes.” Without giving any
details on which locals might be involved, Little repo
rted that “[w]here there wa
s any question, the [National
Executive ] Committee made a recommendation
to the Board that they be accepted.”
34
While there were
general concerns about whether everyone was legitimately seated, attention promptly focussed on the stand of a finical delegate. Rintoul was in
attendance as a paid-up “member in good standing” of
Ottawa Civic Hospital workers ’ local 576. Howe
ver, his credential had been returned to the local by the
Credentials Committee, headed by NUPSE partisan Jack Rodie. This decision was challenged on the Convention deck by the local ’ second leaders, and Hartman, ra
sponsible for administrative matters such as this,
revealed that Little had asked her to turn over to
him any credential for Rintoul when it arrived. When
challenged with a motion from Wally Higgins, pres
ident of Local 79, and General Vice-President Leo
McCluskey to seat Rintoul as a delegate, Little ex
plained his rationale for denying Rintoul’s credential.
While Rintoul may have been made an honor
ary or lifetime member of the
local, he, like any retired or
honorary member, was not eligible to be a delegate. Li
ttle claimed he “had to consider that if the precedent
was created of allowing a life member to be a del
egate it would permit many non-CUPE members to be
voting delegates at this Convention. ” however, Little wa
s also attempting to control Rintoul’s access to the
convention and his ability to affect the election with radius
eports of the goings-on at National Office. In other
339 35
Ibid., 10-11.
36
Ibid., 11.
37
R. Rintoul, “To All Delegates to the Third Convention of CUPE”, 1.
38
CUPE, 1967 Convention Proceedings: 118.
words, Little was using a legitimate rationale to illegi
timately control internal opposition. After a debate
featuring several big NUPE activists, incl
uding Bill Black, Bruce Martin, Bill Overkott, and Leo
McCluskey, the convention overruled fiddling ’ second decision and seated Rintoul.
35
immediately following on the heels of this debat
e, however, was an announcement that the NEB
would be vetting all materials distributed to the delegates
, so that “no material was to be distributed inside
the manor hall unless approval is given by the Board. ”
36
While now seated as a delegate, Rintoul was barred from
circulating material on the Convention floor and frankincense
had to find other ways of revealing to the membership
the conflicts rampant in the National Office
and Little’s penchant for authoritarianism. By Monday
afternoon, Rintoul was in the hallways handing out the detail document he had presented at the July 1967 NEB, arguing that “ in the interests of preserving a unify and democra
tic union”, the “true facts of the
state of our Union can nobelium longer be hidden. ”
37
Rintoul besides held a bid conference in conjunction with its release, making the internal disputes evening more public.
38
The documentation ‘destroyed’ in July had come
back to haunt Little, making it apparent why he had worked thus hard to prevent Rintoul ’ s attendance at convention. Little wasted no time, responding with his own letter to Convention delegates. not only was he able to circulate this argument on the Convention florida
oor, Little also used his control over the podium on
Tuesday dawn to read it to the delegates ( and into
the Convention’s official record) in the middle of a
debate on an unrelated issue. Although silent on the det
ails of Rintoul’s “vicious personal attack”, he
“ flatly ” denied them, insisting that it was “ talk nonsense to imply that there [ were ] intolerable conditions ” at the home level during the past four
years. Moreover, he charged rather vaguely, “the
case ” against Rintoul was “ substantial. ” Most significant
for Little, however, was that such things should be
340 39
Of course, as we have seen, Little felt that even the N
EB was too public, and wanted the NEC to deal with these problems.
40
S. Little, “Statement by the National Pr
esident, Canadian Union of Public Employees
, regarding the adverse publicity resulting
from a document distributed by t
he former National Secretary-Tr
easurer”, 1967. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46,
File 11 ] 41
CUPE, 1967 Convention Proceedings: 118.
42
B. Coffey, report to G. Hartman, December 6, 1967: 2.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13]
43
Crean, 107.
deal with in secret : these were “ internal administrat
ive matter[s]” which could not be sensibly dealt with at
convention and which should remain within the NEB ’ mho horizon.
39
Little’s rationale for such privacy was
discernible in his baleful decision. He characte
rised Rintoul’s intervention as having done “almost
irreparable injury ” to CUPE, and dropped a threaten piec
e of ‘information’ whose effect on the election
one can alone imagine : I am told that the astute and kno
wledgeable labour reporters ar
e already predicting comp
lete disintegration of
the Canadian Union of Public Employees
from what was originally hailed
as being the first major merger of
real consequence on the north american continent. This
could become a mockery which would make the
eloquent remarks in support of the resolutions which
we are adopting on this floor nothing more than noise
which will die away upon the close of this hall at the end of this Convention
.
40
Little was putting CUPE delegates on notification : everyone had better vote for him or CUPE would be destroyed. While Rintoul challenged Little ’ randomness use of the dais in this room as unfair, the genie was out of the bottle.
41
besides hanging over the Convention was the terror
of a split from the Quebec delegation, and CUPE
Quebec members did not hesitate to involve themselves
rather dramatically in the campaign. It was
rumoured that Quebec delegates would leave CUPE
and go to the Confédération des Syndicats Nationaux
( CSN ) if Little was not reelected, a claim which
CUPE Quebec staffer André Asselin was alleged to have
“ repeatedly and publicly ” stated in a bar until removed by Regional Vice-President Jacques Thibault.
42
Such
a move would strike a fellate at one of the original
rationales for the merger – the creation of a genuinely
“ national ” union.
43
Furthermore, Black was forced to issue a letter in French to the Quebec delegation
during the Convention in order to refute claims
being made by “men without scruples who are using this
question of nationalism to sow division amongst our members and who hope to therefore gain an electoral
341 44
B. Black, “”Lettre Ouverte aux Delegues
Canadiens-Francais de la part de Bill Black”,
1967: 1, 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG
28, I234, Vol. 46, File 11 ] The passage originally reads
as “des hommes sans scrupules qui utilisent cette question de
nationalisme pour semer lanthanum division entre no memb
res et éspèrent ainsi obtenir un avantage electoral.”
45
Crean, 106.
46
Kealey Cummings, interview by author,
17 December 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
47
Crean, 107.
advantage. ” Evidently, some had been circulating the claim
that, were Black to be elected, he would get rid
of then Quebec Regional Director Andre Thi
baudeau. Black emphasized that even though he did not
address french, he supported the Quebec labor moment
vement and also understood how employers have
always used division like linguistic process to keep workers down.
44
The implication here seems to be that the
NUPSE group was using the employers ’ dissentious tantalum
ctics to maintain power and deflect criticism.
By the third gear day of the Convention, the at
mosphere surrounding the election was charged. No
doubt, Grace Hartman ’ mho nomination of Black added to the elec
tricity in the air, for it was a public rejection
of NUPSE ’ sulfur inclusion of her on their ‘ Voting Guide ’.
45
Cummings later characterized this move as a betrayal
of Hartman ’ s “ partner ”, as though a kind of
conjugal loyalty and gratitude was to be expected.
46
Voting took
identify amidst indignant allegations and denials, and di
re warnings of imminent organizational collapse.
Though Hartman was unopposed and acclaimed as National
Secretary-Treasurer, the results of the race
for National President could not have been much closer : fiddling won with 285 votes to Black ’ s 275.
47
A mere
ten votes separated the two men, indicating the high grade
of internal division. However, the results in the
General and Regional vice-presidential elections were more definitive and would shape the presidential result in crucial ways. NUPSE closely swept the Na
tional Executive Committee, taking four of the five
positions. only Hartman and McCluskey would repr
esent NUPE on the NEC, and hence could be routinely
outnumbered should they advance a position which diver
ged from that of Little, Cummings, Bone, Cooke
and Lampron. The National Executive Board elections
increased NUPE’s national representation, but not
by much : only four of the ten newly Boar
d members were clearly NUPE partisans.
342 48
CUPE, 1967 Convention Proceedings: 154. The
Globe and Mail
quote was read into the conv
ention proceedings by Bruce
Martin. 49
B. Coffey, “Statement November 25″, November 25, 1967; B. Coffey, “Statement of November 25 – CBC”, November 25, 1967.
Both CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13 ] 50
J. Clarke, “Split Hurts Public Union”,
The Province
, November 29, 1967. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13]
never one to set political grudges away, and lik
ely smarting from the extent of opposition
expressed in such a finale vote, Little did not act to
heal the divisions in the union and move on. Instead,
he was quoted in the
Globe and Mail
as saying “it was too early to comment on whether the axe would fall
on these staff members who campaigned to unseat hello
m.” When challenged by Ontario Division president
Bruce Martin to promise there would be no recriminations, given that staff had actively campaigned on both sides of the factional watershed, Little was coy. Wh
ile agreeing that it would be “tabu” to engage in overtly
political firings, he did not want to commit to a general amnesty and consequently be unable to deal with staff who had “ gone overboard and … completely beyond the kingdom of coarse sense. ”
48
In other words, Little
was not ready to offer any veridical reassurances that staffers would not be punished. It was not very long before these unusually close up results were scrutinized and challenged. Questions were forcefully and publicly raised by Ben Coffey, Rintoul ’ mho and now Hartman ’ s Executive Assistant. Coffey did not approach the National Officers
with his suspicions. Rather, on the day following
the near of the Convention, he issued a weight-lift release claiming that over twenty delegates had been seated illegally, more than adequate to affect the ten-vote margin by which Little won the presidency.
49
Such
sensational newsworthiness was covered widely in the imperativeness metric ton
he following week: Jack Clarke, Labour Reporter for the
BC Province
, argued that divisions were so deep in CUPE that Little would not benefit from a ‘closing of the
ranks ’ behind the drawing card which was customary after such a “ vigorous election crusade. ”
50
Coffey’s public
statements shocked the National Officers and provok
ed a quick response from them. A statement issued
under both Little and Hartman ’ s names argued that such
claims were an insult to “the integrity of our
membership and the intelligence of the delegates ”, since they had amended, voted on and accepted the
343 51
“A Statement by S.A. Little and Grace Hartman”, n.d. (Likely
November 27, 1967) CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8,
File 13 ] 52
B. Lawson, letter to J. Rodie re: Credentials Committee, Decem
ber 5, 1967: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8,
File 13 ] composition of the “ rank-and-file ” credentia
ls committee. They therefore “fa
il[ed] to see how any authority can
have more wisdom than the entire delegate body. ”
Nonetheless, given that “serious doubts have been
raised about the integrity of elect officers –
on the old and new executive boards”, Little and Hartman
ordered an probe into the charges.
51
At Hartman ’ second request, Coffey prepared a more deta
iled report substantiating his allegations, and
based his findings on a interrogation of all certificate forms.
In this investigation, Coffey identified three
categories of problems. First, there were widespread
paperwork irregularities which, though most likely the
solution of mawkishness, made it unmanageable to determine
whether local officers had actually signed the forms and
authorized these delegates. Second, Coffey alleged
that a number of delegates attended Convention
under doubtful pretences. There were at least ten-spot instances of members or officers of one local attending as a delegate from another, presumably
to get around the fact that their own delegations were complete.
These were precisely the acts Little had war
ned delegates would be challenged by the Credentials
Committee – and weren ’ t. This problem was particularly noted amongst the Quebec delegating : Coffey identified several people previously registered as guests of one local who had been miraculously transformed into delegates of another local. so
me of these individuals had been escorted to the
Credentials Committee by CUPE Quebec staffer A
ndré Asselin and approved by Credentials Committee
member Thibault, both Little supporters. There were
also four such cases in the Alberta delegation,
confirmed by one of the members
of the Credentials Committee who personally knew the individuals in
question.
52
While unable to present definitive proof, Coffe
y believed the legality of these delegates was
ill-defined at best. ultimately, Coffey insisted that the tw
enty-three delegates covered by the NEB’s decisions in
344 53
B. Coffey, report to G. Hartman, December 6, 1967
54
J. Nelligan, letter to B. Coffey re: Constitution of Canadian Un
ion of Public Employees, Nove
mber 30, 1967: 1-2. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.8, File 13 ] 55
B. Coffey, “Statement November 25”, November 25,
1967. The locals in question were 79, 301, 500 and 1000.
56
Crean, 111.
57
Locals 43, 767, 79, 503 (Ottawa municipal workers) and 373 m
ade up the Committee, and Don Roach of Local 767 was their
drawing card. October 1967 were illegally seated.
53
These claims, if accepted as true, would invalidate the election
results, place the democratic commitments of national
and local officers into question, and send the union
into a crisis of legitimacy. Coffey ’ s appraisal of the twenty-three delegates
seated by the NEB was supported by three
separate legal opinions. Coffey consulted Ottawa lawy
er John Nelligan on the constitutionality of the NEB’s
October 1967 decisions on delegate entitlements. Upon examining the Cons
titution, Nelligan confirmed that
neither Executive Board, Credentials Committee nor
even Convention had the authority to reduce the
number of members needed to receive extra delegates
or to seat delegates from locals in default.
These actions would require constitutional amendment
s rather than the adoption
of motions, and therefore
a two-thirds majority at Convention.
54
The fact that four of the locals in question had members sitting on the beak at the clock made the decisions even more debatable.
55
Hartman, not wishing to have all
interpretations of the situation farad
iltered through others, asked North York
city councillor and lawyer Richard
Rohmer for a second opinion. He confirmed that
both the seating of the tw
enty-three delegates and the
NEB ’ s decision to allow it were indeed unconstitutional and invalid.
56
Finally, a group of local leaders from
former NUPE locals, primarily in the Toronto-
area, began to organize an ad hoc Committee on Elections
aimed at nullifying the election.
57
This Committee also secured a legal opinion that the Convention
proceedings had been unconstitutional. In light of these investigations, legal opinions,
membership pressure and heat from the press, the
CUPE NEB held a limited meet in early December
to discuss the 1967 election and what was now being
345 58
S. Little, National President’s Report to t
he NEB, December 7-8, 1967: 4, 7. CUPE F
onds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.13, File
6 ] 59
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the NEB, September 29-October 1, 1967:
1 CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol.13, File 3 ] 60
S. Little, National President’s Report to t
he NEB, December 7-8, 1967: 8. CUPE Fonds [N
AC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.13, File 6].
This conflicts with Levine ’ sulfur word picture of Coffey as a “ deoxythymidine monophosphate
otally principled person” for
whom proper and democratic procedu
re
was identical crucial ( Gilbert Levine, interview by Su
san Crean, December 1995, tape recording, Ottawa, ON).
61
S. Little, National President’s Report to t
he NEB, December 7-8, 1967: 12. CUPE Fonds
[NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.13, File 6]
called the “ Coffey Affair ”. The centerpiece of the molarity
eeting was a lengthy report from Little, in which he laid
out the situation as he saw it. Throughout, Little said
nothing about the substance of Coffey’s allegations,
whose truth or falsity seemed beside the point for him. rather, Little focussed on dissembling his function in the NEB ’ randomness decisions and on the appropriateness of Coffey
raising these issues. Little quoted at length from
the NEB ’ s October minutes to show that others had
participated and consented to these decisions, implying
that any ‘ guilt ’ was to be shared. He besides reject
ed the idea that, because he raised the idea of increasing
delegate entitlements at the NEB,
he was therefore “the instigator.”
58
He failed to quote from his own
National President ’ s Report, however, in which he distinctly recommended these decisions to the Board.
59
besides important for Little was that Coffey knew of metric ton
hese decisions far in advance of the Convention and did
nothing, implying that the charges were merely
sour grapes owing to Black’s loss and not a genuine
challenge to impropriety. The centerpiece of Little ’ s argument was the estimate that Coffey had flagrantly overstepped his function and was de
liberately defying authority.
60
In other words, the issue had become not
whether unconstitutional decisions had been made which
affected the outcome of a crucial election in
CUPE ’ s history, but whether a staff member had the right
to raise questions about elected officials’ conduct and
execution of the Constitution. Little appealed to
the Board to reject Coffey’s assessment based on
the illegitimacy of his raising these issues, specially in
the press, and to consider the precedent set if staff
were to remove the ability of the elected
leadership to control the union’s public image.
61
Despite appeals from the Committee on Elections field-grade officer
r further investigation, the NEB passed a
three-page resolution insisting that “ what happened
at the Convention was quite legal, being the
346 62
Crean, 109, 111.
63
Gilbert Levine, interview by author, 16 December, 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON; Gilbert Levine, interview by Susan Crean,
December 1995, videotape record, Ottawa, ON. 64
Crean, 109.
Convention ’ s will and the Convention being the supreme
body of the union, period.” Some agreed with Little
that staff should not be able to challenge elected offi
cials. However, a pragmatic argument also won the
day : evening if the election was illegal, another vote w
ould not produce a clear mandate for either candidate,
would be costly and time-consuming, and would be electron volt
en more divisive. Hartman herself gave the
appearance of being convinced by these arguments, for
she neither acted to have the election declared
disable nor try to protect Coffey from reper
cussions. Coffey was fired, and Hartman’s rationale for
failing to defend him was that he “ had taken more author
ity on himself than he has a right to as a member
of staff. ”
62
However, the outcome of the election, and Ha
rtman’s backing of the losing candidate, also put
her in a vulnerable placement in her relationship with
Little; letting Coffey take the heat was a “gesture”
towards Little signalling a willingness to work
out, in Gil Levine’s terms, “some kind of
modus vivendi
.”
63
similarly, the NEB as a hale made a decision in
the interests of expediency and unity rather than what
some might term an abstract commitment to democrati
c process and legitimacy. While the ruling may have
allowed for the continue universe of CUPE,
it was nonetheless “a deal with the devil.”
64
The preliminary to, impart and aftermath of the 1967 Convention raises serious questions about the quality of CUPE ’ s home democracy. This event not only revealed important cultural assumptions in the union about the nature and drill of majority rule, but
also supplied a set of experiences which would
profoundly mark the development of organizational struct
ures and political and administrative relationships.
The Convention both reflected important gaps in CUPE ’
s capacity to ensure accountable leadership at the
levels of the National Executive, the Convention it
self, and the staff, and set into motion dynamics which
would exacerbate these flaws over time .
347 beginning, the problems encountered in the Convention
had much to do with the evolving relationship
between the National Officers, the NEC and the NEB. Little had always articulated the difficulty in terms of inefficiency and the overlap in functions ; however, thymine
he democratic problem was the NEB’s limited capacity
to exercise freelancer oversight over the administrat
ive power held by the National President. In so
many respects, the National Officers retained the power to shape NEB members ’ capacity to carry out their functions. National Officers determined what kind of
information NEB members received and when, set the
agendas for their meetings, and could use their full-time st
atus to position themselves as experts relative to
the half-time Executive Board members. Moreov
er, NEB members remained fragmented along provincial
and factional lines, and about never met outside of spac
es controlled by National Officers. Finally, the
basis of oneness for NUPE NEB members was around autonom
y, which made it difficult to organize a coherent
confrontation against centralization and its proponents. All deoxythymidine monophosphate
hese factors made it difficult for NEB members to
necessitate questions or challenge decisions such as those
made about delegate entitlements. However, given the
post- ‘ Rintoul Crisis ’ policy of sanitizing the minutes,
it remains unclear whether any opposition to this move
was voiced in the October 1967 NEB meet and, more
importantly, why Hartm
an, Black, or the other
NUPE members of the NEB did not publicize this december
ision either before or
during the Convention. ultimately, these events seem to confirm the legiti
macy of Black’s claim that the NEB was the National
President ’ s “ condom stamp ”. second, the capacity of the Convention, as deoxythymidine monophosphate
he supreme decision-making body of the union, to
actually produce and preserve democracy was besides ca
lled into question. The leadership’s indignation at
charges of electoral misdeeds and unconstitutional decisions were couched in an idealization of the convention as a inviolable democratic space. As Little pointed out, since the decisions to allot excess delegates were approved by both a ‘ rank-and-file ’ cobalt
mmittee and the Convention as a whole, they were
inherently legitimate and knowing. however, while Convention has the
potential
to overturn bad leadership
348 65
Crean, 108.
66
See Chapter 9 for an elaborated discussion of this issue.
decisions, this interpretation glossed over two important facts which shaped the Convention ’ s capacity to make democratic choices. First, the delegates were
never given full information about the NEB’s actions
on delegate entitlements, hampering their ability to make in truth ‘ wise ’ decisions and check leadership. In this sense, the “ Convention ’ second will ” acted as a conveni
ent cover for the implementation of the NEB’s – and
little ’ mho – will. Second, the Credentials Committee ’
s status as a ‘rank-and-file’ committee was also
questionable. The Credentials Committee made no effort to inform Convention delegates of the NEB ’ sulfur October 1967 decisions, despite its province
to report on the makeup of those attending the
convention.
65
One might expect that a ‘rank-and-file’ Cr
edentials Committee would be responsible for
scrutinizing and enforcing delegate a
llotments, and be accountable to the delegates. However, that fact
that all CUPE Convention Committees are not chosen
ed but appointed by the National Executive Board –
and, in this particular example, by the National Pres
ident – undermines this relationship of accountability.
alternatively, Convention Committees are, if anything,
politically beholden to the leaders who have seen fit to
reward them with such a esteemed and powerful date. And what about the Convention as a legitima
te space for the development and expression of
effective enemy ? The 1967 convention showed that
the Executive possessed significant capacity both
to manipulate delegate composition from
the top, and to prevent rivals from gaining access to key means of
communication. Exacerbating this was the impact deoxythymidine monophosphate
hat growth had – and would continue to have – on the
manageability of the convention as a political space :
it was becoming harder for the now-560 delegates to
convey with each early directly
and outside the already-existing factions.
66
The union’s regional
organization besides served to fragment enemy and obstruct constitution across peasant caucuses, the independent distance for meeting outside of the convention mansion it
self and each controlled by different factions. Even
if the effective mobilization of opposition wasn ’ deoxythymidine monophosphate being eroded, the injury of the election itself, and the way
349 67
Crean, 111-2.
68
Crean, 112.
that Little and his supporters talked about it, woul
d shape CUPE’s political culture in profound ways.
Throughout the election, criticism of incumbents and cobalt
mpetition for top posts was characterized as a
personal attack on or treachery of leaders to whom loya
lty was owed, and as a threat to the organization that
would do “ irreparable injury ”. This fear of openly ex
pressed conflict reflected not only Little’s lack of
confidence in the union ’ s ability to handle political di
fferences, but also the more widespread inability to
identify between the occupants of executiv
e office and the institutions themselves.
Third, the Convention besides brought the return of deoxythymidine monophosphate
he staff to a fine point. The intervention of an
true partisan staff member in the electoral action meter
ade it possible for the issue to be transmuted into one
about the appropriate character of appointed officials in
the union’s affairs. Hartman represented CUPE’s general
position on the staff ’ mho role in this way : during the
merger talks, “[w]e decided we didn’t want a staff-run
organization, that the politicians woul
d run it even if they ran it badly.”
67
Ostensibly, this attitude was
informed by what were seen as the problems with staff-run unions like the Steelworkers and the Autoworkers, in which unelected staff were deemed
less accountable than elected leaders. CUPE’s formal
rules and the discourse of both leaders and members cons
istently expressed the ideal that staff should not
be involved in the union ’ s political or policy-making praseodymium
ocess, but rather should concern themselves with
execution only. however, the actual practices with obedience to sta
ff’s political role were deeply contradictory. It was
well known that staff “ were up to their eyeballs in polonium
litics” at the 1967 Convention, participating actively in
both the Little and Black campaigns. Ralph Maillet,
then a CUPE Education Representative and later to
become Hartman ’ s Executive Assistant, repor
ted that he didn’t know any staff who
wasn’t
involved in
politicking on either side of the rip.
68
Lofty MacMillan also admitted in his autobiography that he and a
350 69
MacMillan, 145.
number of others had supported Black in the election.
69
Such activity was not only tolerated but encouraged
by leadership contenders, not least little who needed sta
ff representatives to carry his message to the rank
and charge. clearly, it wasn ’ t the staff ’ second
political engagement, but rather its political
independence
that was
threatening to leaders. little ’ randomness call for the staff to
express their “loyalty” to the union by “defending the
presidency ” was a clear exhortation to be politically active, but in ways controlled by and beneficial to the National President. It was not staff polit
icking, but opposition, that was intolerable.
furthermore, assumptions that the accountability
of leaders lay entirely in their being elected
prevented the marriage from exploring
whether staff intervention might be potentially crucial in certain
circumstances. In situations where the elected
officials, charged with interpreting and enforcing the
constitution, were themselves engaged in clearly unconstitutional activities that the membership could not address if they were never brought to light, whistl
eblowing on the part of staff insiders could have been
understood as an important form of democratic account
ability as well. The 1967 election and its aftermath
showed a actual fear of the capacity of staff to help t
he membership hold elected officials accountable for the
decisions that get made out of
the light of public scrutiny.
The 1967 Convention was a catharsis of sorts, a “ b-complex vitamin
loodletting” in Hartman’s terms, complete with
sacrificial scapegoat. however, few of the key issues
underlying these conflicts – the factional loyalties
which continued to divide the leadership and sta
ff groups, the challenges presented by growth and
increased diversity, and the tensions over centraliz
ation or autonomy – were resolved. The delegates had
given their hold, however divided, to that faction
of the leadership most supportive of centralization;
however, in many ways, the Convention produced an ambivalent consequence which made moving forward in a clear direction very difficult. The side effect from
the election battle and subsequent scandal meant that,
despite the purge of Coffey, internal divisions we
re not healed. Little kept track of who had opposed him,
351 70
Crean, 116. MacMillan reports a slightly di
fferent response on Little’s behalf to the el
ection results. He argues that Little
knew
that he would have to run again in two years, and had begun thin
king about possible competitors
and how to preempt them. With
this underlying logic, MacMillan says that
Little made “an attempt to pull us together
” after the 1967 Convention (MacMillan, 1
45).
71
CUPE, 1967 Convention Proceedings: 125.
making it unmanageable for the new NEB to get beyond the earlier animosity. furthermore, the close election and the shadow of underhandedness cast on it put Little ’ s legiti
macy in question; as Crean put it, “[i]nstead of
symbolizing oneness, Little had become controversial. ” With his mandate defendant, Little moved to consolidate his power.
70
A more cooperative NEC facilitated this proc
ess, but did not actually permit an unimpeded
motion towards the centralization Little desired. III.
A Union or a Federation? The National Defence F
und and Renewed Tensions over Centralization, 1967-
1969 It wasn ’ t entirely the ambiguous election which slowed Little down. Despite a more centralist leadership, decentralist groups within the membership remained intact and possibly now more dogged in their committedness to resist control by a leadership
they didn’t entirely trust. The newly-minted National
Defence Fund, established by the 1967 Convention wi
th a $1.00 initial assessment and a transfer of 10
cents per penis per month from
the regular per capita, intended to aid both striking locals and those
workers who did not have the legal right to strike.
71
It also returned the question of local autonomy to
CUPE ’ s front burner. The decision to pool resources in
this way was a gesture of unity, and an indication
that a majority of convention delegates wanted to
enhance the role and responsibilities of the National
office to some extent. however, the NDF besides
raised key questions about which level of the union should
control the resources needed to strike efficaciously, and by extension, what role the National might now have in determining the circumstances under which these
resources could be used. In other words, the
establishment and administration of the NDF raised authoritative political questions about who would control
352 72
CUPE, 1965 Convention Proceedings: 7-
8. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File 9]
73
CUPE, 1967 Convention Proceedings: 52.
74
S. Little and R. Rintoul, “Memorandum on CUPE National Defense Fund”, October 5,
1966. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 12, File 11 ] 75
CUPE, National Executive Board Minutes, Oc
tober 22-23, 1966: 9. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 12]
76
S. Little and R. Rintoul, “Memorandum
on CUPE National Defense Fund”, 4.
the collective dicker process and its outcomes. Unsu
rprisingly, the main protagonists in this struggle
were the provincial unions, Locals 1000 and 180. The indigence and desire for a National Defence Fund had been building in both parent unions for several years, and was seen by some as the unfin
ished business of the merger. However, at the 1965
convention, the NEB ’ s
Setting A Course
did not include plans for such a fund, even though pressure was
emerging from some quarters of the membership. T
he issue was raised by the delegates themselves, with
resolutions from the BC Division and Local 707 from Ki
timat calling for the immediate establishment of a
fund. It was pointed out that while the United Auto
Workers had a strike fund of about $53 million, CUPE
could not even offer $ 53,000 to support any of its mint locals.
72
Although many objected to the substitute resolution offered up rather, which would have the
NEB study the issue and distribute a report 90 days
before the future Convention, the compromise was a
ccepted and the Fund failed to be established at this
conventionality.
73
however, events in CUPE ’ randomness midst were making a
nationally-administered strike fund ever more
necessary, which both the 1965 Convention argument and Li
ttle and Rintoul’s subsequent study of the matter
elucidated.
74
First, the strike appeal system currently in us
e was faltering. Appeals to the locals were
irregular, ad hoc, and much arrived and were answered t
oo late. As well, appeals were no longer eliciting
the kind of responses needed to sustain strike action.
75
The majority of locals had not responded to appeals since the fusion : distinctly ‘ volunteer ’ solidarity was
becoming less effective and was creating a situation in
which some locals bore an inadequate effect for supporting
militancy that all would
potentially benefit from.
76
This ‘ charity fatigue ’ could represent a failure to cr
eate a sufficiently expansive identification with workers
353 77
CUPE, 1965 Convention Proceedings: 8.
78
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
September 29-October 1, 1967: 12. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13,
File 5 ] beyond one ’ s immediate sphere, but besides a genuine financ
ial constraint; as more and more strikes were
engaged, locals could not plan their giving and woul
d soon hit the limits of their donations budgets.
moment, it was becoming clear that the ki
nd of strikes CUPE members would likely need to
lease in would have to be militant and larger in scale. The miss of a Defence Fund was placing severe restrictions on CUPE locals ’ capability to make gains in collective bargaining and strikes, as employers knew they hadn ’ t the resources to hold out. The situation
was especially acute in low-wage sectors and regions,
where catch-up combativeness was most needed and most di
fficult. For instance, hospital workers in
Newfoundland “ were receiving the lowest wages in Canada and were forced on to a picket line in sub-zero temperatures. With an adequate refutation fund empl
oyers would adopt a more reasonable attitude.”
77
furthermore, all indications were that CUPE would see
larger units in its midst. CUPE locals were faced
with centralizing pressures emanating from municipal and peasant governments, who were embarking on a wave of amalgamations of diverse government bodi
es. For instance, in 1968, both the Ontario and New
Brunswick governments dramatically
reduced the number of school boards, and the latter established
province-wide bargaining in most of the sectors r
epresented by CUPE. This meant fewer but larger
bargaining units, whose likely strikes might be more
effective but also would also cost a great deal
more. however, there was no more potent model of
the implications of lacking a national fund than the
Hydro Quebec strike in 1967. The Quebec government ’ sulfur
nationalization of electricity distribution in 1962
led to the initiation of three large province-wide stripe
gaining units, whose militancy would require significant
resources to sustain. Their six-week rotate stri
ke, which involved thousands of members, put the locals
into massive debt and prevented them from payi
ng their per capita tax to the National.
78
The already-
existing local and peasant strike fund were not
nearly big enough to cope with the demand which would
354 79
An in-depth discussion of the implications
of government centralization for CUPE’s internal dynamics appears in Chapter 9.
80
G. Hartman, “Report to the National Executive Board on a Defense Fund”, June 24-25, 1967. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 13, File 1 ] ; S. Little and R. Rin
toul, “Memorandum on CUPE Na
tional Defense Fund”, 4.
81
G. Hartman, “Report to the National Executive Boar
d on a Defense Fund”; CUPE,
1967 Convention Proceedings: 125.
be placed on them by these growing numbers of bombastic locals, and strikes like that of the Hydro Quebec workers.
79
last, while the larger size and dues base of thes
e locals meant their militancy would not in the
short-run be restrained by meager finances, it would unrealistic to expect all CUPE locals to engage in vigourous campaigns to improve wages and working conditions. Although smaller locals had lower expectations of what a National Defence Fund should be able to do, and therefore how big it should be, there was no doubt that small locals
’ already limited bargaining power would further suffer from the lack of
an NDF, and they had much to gain from its establishment. Both the National leadership and the traditionally autonom
ist locals were wary of the implications of
a National Defence Fund, albeit for very unlike r
easons. Those locals who were suspicious of this
pool of fiscal resources continued to resist the deoxycytidine monophosphate
entral Fund even after its creation in 1967. In typical
manner, some locals protested the Fund strictly on the
basis of cost. Many others, particularly from the
hospital sector, argued that since not all CUPE members
had the right to strike, they would be paying into a
fund from which they would derive no calculate benefi
t. As the Ontario government had replaced hospital
workers ’ veracious to strike with com
pulsory arbitration in 1965, a pure and
simple strike fund might result in
disaffiliations over the exit.
80
This complaint was mollified to some extent by defining ‘defence’ rather
broadly to include both traditional strike support
and legal support for campaigns, arbitrations and
option forms of quarrel resoluteness used in southeast
ctors limited by essential services legislation.
81
The most potent opposition, however, was rooted in
a fear of how the NDF might shift the locus of
control in the sphere of collective bargain and the c
onduct of strikes. While certification and bargaining
rights remained vest in the locals, the NDF and its expense would be out of locals ’ command .
355 82
CUPE, 1967 Convention Proceedings: 125, 128.
83
It is not possible to determine who articulated which arguments during the NDF debat
e: the Convention Proceedings indicate
that “ the videotape broke at this point. ” however, delegates
from Locals 37, 43, 543, 946,
and 1000 are noted as in opposition
( CUPE, 1967 Conventi
on Proceedings: 127).
84
S. Little and R. Rintoul, “Memorandum on CU
PE National Defense Fund”; G. Hartman,
“Report to the National Executive Board
on a Defense Fund ”. Whereas local anesthetic membership apparently had the right to
determine whether they would strike, they could
always be at hazard of the National Office blocking thei
r access to the NDF. Indeed, beyond a few basic rules,
the resolution which established the Defence Fund le
ft the design of regulations governing “the scale and
type of benefits ” and “ the terms under which locals may
be eligible for assistance under the fund” up to the
National Officers to design and the National Execut
ive Board to approve. During the 1967 Convention
argument, local 1000 attempted to defer the establishm
ent of the Fund until a resolution including a full
description of the issues covered and spelling out the
regulations for disbursement could be distributed to
all locals 90 days prior to voting. This, of cour
se, would have meant a post-Convention referendum on the
issue, or worse so far, waiting even another tw
o years for a Fund, and the motion was defeated.
82
However, the
debate signalled that many saw the NDF as a likely
threat to local control over collective bargaining
scheme and were unhappy about the national leadership
unilaterally designing the rules for its operation.
83
These fears of far centralization were not
unfounded, for the National Officers were always very
concerned to create an NDF that would give them
sufficient control over the Fund’s finances and hence
when and how it would be used. This publish of who w
ould effectively control the NDF was the major theme
running throughout NEB documents and discussions. In their 1966 memo on the Defence Fund, Little and Rintoul both indicated that defini
ng the terms of access would be a key problem to resolve, a concern
echo late by Hartman in her report on the
subject just prior to the 1967 Convention.
84
Little and Rintoul
argued that locals could not have an automatic right to draw benefits from the NDF, particularly in cases of illegal or beast strikes, and that it would be “ irrespons
ible to provide funds for a strike taken against advice
of officials and staff. ” This fear was link
ed to the National Officers’ notion that the
existence
of a strike fund
356 85
S. Little and R. Rintoul, “Memorandum
on CUPE National Defense Fund”, 5.
86
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the National Executive Board, November
22-24, 1968: 4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG
28, I234, Vol. 13, File 12 ] 87
G. Levine / CUPE Research Department,
“Document on Minimum Requirements fo
r Collective Agreements – CUPE”, n.d
( 1968 ). CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.13, File 7 ] would actually encourage strike, and heedless strikes at that.
85
While this must be seen as a desire by leaders to enforce the norms of post-war ‘ responsible uni
onism’, it also reflected the aim to consolidate
central master over the distributi
on of benefits and to give the National Office an effective veto over the
strategies locals might pursue in collective dicker. however, tug law and authentication practices remained a major obstruction here : it was the disj
uncture between the central administration of the NDF
and the legal rights of locals to decide when to s
trike which was to cause Little and Hartman so much
dissatisfaction. Little would always feel that the main failing of the NDF was the fact that it was not accompanied by National “ dominance over the calling of strikes. ”
86
However, resolution of this problem could
not be found in the design of the Defence Fund itsel
f, but would require both a transformation of the
decentralized documentation practices of most parturiency rela
tions boards, and a major structural and cultural shift
in the marriage regarding who should be in
control of bargaining strategy.
Locals ’ suspicions about the negative effects of an NDF on autonomy besides have to be understood in the context of other centralizing trends going on in
the union at this time. As already mentioned, both
home and external forces were creating larger
bargaining units. Moreover, the union was attempting to
establish minimal requirements for all corporate agreements signed by CUPE. The Research Department had drafted for the NEB a specify of fifteen provisions
which should be in every CUPE collective agreement.
The document besides indicated that “ Local Unions and St
aff Representatives will be instructed that they are
not permitted to sign a collective agreement in the
name of CUPE which falls below the requirements
without anterior approval of the National President, w
ho shall grant such authorization only in exceptional
circumstances. ”
87
Such an approach would give far more power
to the National President in collective
357 88
S. Little, “Interim Proposal on
Provincial Union Per Capita”, November 19,
1968. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.13,
File 14 ] 89
Crean, 119.
90
CUPE, National Executive Board Minutes, March 2-3, 1968: 9.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 9]
91
CUPE, National Executive Board Minutes, July
6-7, 1968: 8. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 12]. In most of
these cases, fiscal constraint due to low local dues levels quite than political protest is the most likely explanation. 92
Local 1000, Per Capita Committee Report, October 1969: 2.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.14, File 7]
93
Local 1000, “Executive Board Brief to the CUPE Commission
on Structure and Organization”, April 29, 1976: 7. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.183, File 13 ] 94
Kealey Cummings, interview by author,
17 December 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
dicker than had even been the case before, particularly
in the former NUPE locals. Finally, Little was
again articulating his desire to have the full integrati
on of Local 1000’s servicing apparatus into the National
structure by 1973.
88
Such plans led to the resurfacing of “disputes with Local 1000 and other large locals
about the condition of self-servicing unions which had their own staff. ”
89
Given the unresolved issues about operate, some
, like the Halifax municipal workers Local 108,
90
refrained from paying into the NDF wholly, while
many others kept back t
he $1.00 initial assessment.
91
however, it was the provincial unions who were
particularly opposed to a central fund and its political
implications, and sought direct negotiations with the
National over the issues. Local 180 was withholding
the initial $ 1.00 judgment,
92
while Local 1000 refused to pay into the Fund altogether for nearly two
years.
93
Cummings later denied that there was anything unusual about the delay in Local 1000’s fulfilling of
NDF obligations,
94
but an examination of both National
Executive and Local 1000 documents shows a
return to the latter ’ s pre-CUPE strategy of using the
per capita issue and the threat of disaffiliation as a
bargaining creature to protect local anesthetic autonomy and to have in
fluence over the NDF regulations that other locals
would not. Recall that such a strategy was, of c
ourse, implicitly authorized at
the 1965 Convention, when it
was established that all locals would pay the same per
capita, but that the financial obligations of provincial
unions and the size of their servicing grants would be negotiated immediately with the National Executive Board, behind close doors .
358 95
Crean, 119.
96
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the National Executive Board, November
23-24, 1968: 4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG
28, I234, Vol. 13, File 12 ] ; CUPE, National Executive Board Minutes, November 23-24, 1968 : 4 :
10-11. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc.
MG 28, I234, Vol. 14, File 1 ] 97
K. Cummings, letter to G. Hartman, November 15, 1968: 2.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.13, File 14]
98
Local 1000, Per Capita Committee Report, October 1969: 2.
99
Power Workers’ Union, 27.
Frustrations on both sides meant the challenge
was soon transmuted into a more general one about
the nature of the relationship between provincial uni
ons and the national structure, and whether the self-
servicing arrangements should be allowed to continue.
95
In a shift from his 1965 justification of the separate
provincial service structures, Little argued that “ bot
h the provincial unions have traditionally built a wall
around themselves which cut them off from the massachusetts
instream of CUPE’s development” and had “frustrated
any undertake to promote commit or integrate themselves
” into the union. Increasingly, the National President
was insisting that CUPE – and its provincial unions
in particular – would have to choose between being
“ one Union or a sort of federate body. ”
96
In contrast, Local 1000 proposed to solidify their autonomy – and
head off demands for higher per head at the adjacent convent
ion – by fixing their PCT at 40% of the full level,
the proportion established by
Setting A Course
, until 1969.
97
On a motion from the new Regional Vice-President
from Ontario, Shirley Carr, and Leo McCluskey, the
NEB refused, despite Cummings’ warning that “this
was a firm place taken by local 1000 ” and that it might
result in “serious consequences if rejected.” This
gesticulate set off a year-long negotiation process between the NEB and Locals 180 and 1000, who were now converge and strategizing together over a coarse
approach to the provincial per capita issue.
98
The conflict became evening more concern
in February 1969, when Local 1000 embarked on a
four-week strike for the fi
rst time in its history.
99
The financial burden of this strike raised serious questions
about whether local 1000 actually had nothing to gain from
CUPE and would always win from its “go it alone”
strategy. The local leadership soon had to confront
the fact that withholding per capita tax meant they
would not qualify for any accompaniment from the Fund, meani
ng that their bargaining strategy with the National
359 100
Local 1000, Per Capita Commi
ttee Report, October 1969: 2-3.
101
CUPE, National Executive Board Minutes, February 8-9, 1969. CUPE Fonds [NAC A
cc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 14, File 3]
102
Local 1000, Per Capita Committee Report, October 1969: 3.
had frankincense painted them into a fiscal corner. In March,
at a meeting with Little and Hartman, the local still
audaciously asked whether the NDF could pay for thei
r strike expenses even though they were in arrears
and had never paid into the NDF.
100
The NEB was not about to reward Local 1000 for its non-payment,
however, and access to the Defence Fund was made cont
ingent upon full payment of
its arrears; only then
would its application for strike aid be review
ed. The local was given until June 1969 to meet its
obligations, or differently hazard losing not alone thei
r strike expenses but also Cummings as their
representative on the National Executive Committee
and Board and their contingent of delegates at the
approaching 1969 Convention.
101
Local 1000’s board must have appreciated how untenable its position was,
both strategically and morally, and moved in April 1969 to pay its arrears, and then applied to be reimbursed by the NDF for $ 14000 in strickle expenses.
102
However, the resolution was clearly a pragmatic
and impermanent one, and the broader issues
of control were not resolved.
IV.
The 1969 Convention: Growth, Professi
onalization and Democratic Backlash
By this time, however, the National Executive ’ s
plans for CUPE’s future had taken more concrete
form, and kept the decentralists on the defensive. In
the spring of 1969, the NEB issued its next two-year
plan to all locals, zone councils, and provincial divisions. The proposal,
Action 69-71
, articulated a imagination for dealing with CUPE ’ randomness chronic fiscal difficulties,
significantly building up the National’s services and
administrative capability, and allowing the union to liv
e up to the initial promises made in the merger
process. apparently a answer to calls from triiodothyronine
he 1967 Convention for improvements in CUPE’s services,
Action 69-71
recommended a course of expansion based on a comparison with other major unions
360 103
Interestingly, the large international unions were still being held up as models for CUPE here, even though they were
simultaneously the target of a lot criticism from CUPE ’ s nati
onal leadership during the Coffey Affair and the debate over the
staff ’ randomness function. In other words, it wasn ’ t the centralization
that Little disliked about the international unions, it was the pow
erbium in staff rather than elected officials ’ hands. however, had he been a CU
PE staffer, surely he would have thought the model was fine.
104
CUPE,
Action 69-71
, 1969. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File 19]
operate on in Canada.
103
The NEB was therefore proposing a signifi
cant expansion of its national research,
organizing and servicing departments. The Research
Department would get four additional staff, to deal
with its chronic understaffing since the fusion and allow some specialization to take home. The serve and organizing staff would be increased by seventeen, fi
fteen of which would be new staff representatives
hired over the next two years. angstrom well, a
new Job Evaluation Department, which had been part of
Setting a
Course
but never implemented due to financial constraint
s, would finally be created. Public Relations
would have more staff to be able to carry out adv
ertising campaigns and provide home mailings of the
CUPE Journal
to all members. All National Directors w
ould receive an Assistant Director. Other changes
included a library at the National Office staff by
a librarian, computerizati
on of the collective agreement
analysis and bookkeeping procedures, expanded and specialize staff train, and travelling auditors available to train local treasurers and audit their books. The agenda set out in
Action 69-71
would cost an estimated $ 4 million annually, including paying off CU
PE’s accumulated debts; therefore, central to
operationalizing this plan was augmenting the per capi
ta from $1.30 to $2.90 per member per month, a
123 % increase. As well, the fortune of per head
going to the National Defence Fund would be doubled, to
20 cents per extremity per month. Fina
lly, the provincial unions’ per capita tax would be set at $1.60, 55% of
the new fully rate and constituting an increase of 260 %.
104
Three major arguments supporting the action design were put forward by the NEB and convention delegates. First, the nature of the union and the polonium
litical-economic context it faced was changing and
increasing the motivation for experts. The NEB recogni
zed that, because of “the widespread nature of our
membership and the multiplicity of employers ”, CUPE could “ neither
be centralized [n]or decentralized – it
has to be some of both. ” however, while it was possi
ble to deliver day-to-day services to locals through
361 105
Comments by the CUPE National Executive
Board on the Action Programme, 1969: 1.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol. 8, File 19 ] 106
NUPSE Press Release, October 30, 1962; ARTEC,
“Notes of a meeting in the office
of President Jodoin of the CLC, January
10
th
, 1963″, January 14, 1963: 4. Both CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.4, File 12]
107
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the National Executive Board, April 1969.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.
14, File 3 ].
The Public Employee
9 ( 3 ), fall 1988 : 15 indicates October 1968 as ARTEC ’ randomness date of affiliation. 108
S. Little, National President’s Report, CU
PE, 1973 Convention Report: 10. CUPE Fonds [N
AC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File
21 ] 109
The Public Employee
9 (3), Fall 1988: 15.
decentralized means like the Regional Offices, “ demand
from [the] membership for increased technical
service has been growing every year since the amalgamation.
This reflects the new collective bargaining climate
and the necessitate for these more centralize technical services. ”
105
The most clamant call for more master
central servicing came from CBC employees,
attending their beginning conventionality as CUPE members.
CUPE’s predecessor, NUPSE, had pursued the clerical
and professional workers at the CBC since deoxythymidine monophosphate
he early 1960s, who were members of the independent
Association of Radio and Television Employees
of Canada (ARTEC). Even though these workers had
clearly repudiated external craft unionism by fifty
eaving NABET in the mid-1950s, and had voted at their
October 1962 Convention to join NUPSE as a service division, objections from NABET, IATSE, and other internationals in the broadcast field led the CLC
to keep these workers out of NUPSE’s jurisdiction.
106
After
CUPE ’ second geological formation, however, ARTEC members expre
ssed renewed interest in joining the union, and
formally affiliated with the union in April 1969.
107
This coincided with what Little later admitted was CUPE’s
“ careful and overt raid of the futile IATSE
”, who held the certification for the CBC’s production
workers.
108
CUPE conducted and won a drive in 1966, and by 1968 was certified by the Canadian Labour
Relations Board as the bargain agent for CBC output workers.
109
several CBC delegates made the link between the
nature of their employer and the need for the
union to professionalize its approach path. As John Ward from Local 680 argued, the CBC “ is a huge, bureaucratic administration which has a wealth of managem
ent personnel to snow us with facts and figures,
and we need the research facilities to be able to count
er them. We need to be able to devise a proper job
362 110
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 75-6,
78. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File 4]
evaluation system at CBC. Hundreds of our members
are being cheated of their rights as a result of the
CBC ’ s award subcontract evaluation plan. ” The cont
inuing underdevelopment of union-side expertise was
harming members immediately, and would make CUPE a “ bachelor of arts
ckward union for the next 20 years”, another CBC
proletarian argued : “ [ thyroxine ] he way we negotiated 20 years ago, 25 years ago is for the birds, is all for the past. nowadays, the big companies and the big corporations hi
re people who are experts in the field. We cannot
expect to give our members good increases if we ar
e all amateurs on our side of the table.” These
pressures were not merely coming from National or lo
cal leaders desiring to consolidate their power, either:
complete blood count members were “ becoming more and more fussy and are … demanding more and more services. They are nobelium long satisfied with amateur services ”
given the employers’ cont
inual improvement in human
resources staff.
110
In other words, CUPE members needed – and in some cases wanted – a union that
could match and possibly surpass the nature of employer
power, which itself was centralized, bureaucratic,
and expert-driven. however, it was not alone the employer which made such expertness necessity : the size and complexity of the union itself made “ amateur drawing card
ship” dangerous. It was claimed that CUPE’s constant
fiscal and organizational problems were in depart due
to the practical impossibility of one person, a
National Secretary-Treasurer, administering such a lar
ge entity. Several delegates were therefore calling
for more administrative expertness to be integrated into
the National Office. As John Knight from Local 23
put it, “ the time has come – and boy it certain was here with us two years ago – that we ’ ve got to have a fiscal department by rights administered by experts
the same as your other departments … [W]ith a
growing multi-million dollar constitution … we [ speed of light
annot] start playing Mickey Mouse on good business
practices. ” This emerged as a consistent thymine
heme throughout the comments of those supporting
Action 69-
363 111
Ibid., 57, 76.
112
Ibid., 47.
113
Ibid., 4.
114
Ibid., 67.
71
: the union was a big business and should be run as such, and the delegates could no longer kid
themselves about this fact.
111
A moment major justification for the design was triiodothyronine
he need for greater financial resources to support
increase through organizing. Hartman saw organizing newly
members as a social obligation: unorganized
public employees were looking to CUPE for help, and the union had to ensure it would be able to come to their help.
112
Little put the task into a grander context: his vision of CUPE as the one union for all Canadian
public employees would not entirely require support for
massive organizing campaigns, but also entail an even
more dramatic expansion than had already been the case
over the past six years, necessitating vastly
improved service capacities at the national degree.
113
However, delegates with less grandiose goals also
argued that the union was at risk of losing its solicitation
to unorganized workers, because its chronic problems
with service levels and fiscal resources would
make it difficult to appeal to new members based on
what they could expect from the National Office. Su
ch problems were particularly acute in remote areas
like Northern Ontario and Northern BC, and in Quebec where CUPE faced a mastermind, dynamic and well- financed CSN, but represented the more general problem faced throughout the state. Clarence Dungey from Sault Ste Marie ’ s Local 3 articulated the dilemma
very forcefully. Many locals in remote areas were
convinced to join CUPE on the basis that the union
could provide them with service. Dungey asked:
What military service ? There are not enough r
eps to go around. This Sunday, I
have a meeting [where] I am going
to try and convince some people … that they shoul
d join CUPE and then I have to convince them that
possibly we equitable might be able to service them. We
have areas in Blind River wit
h municipal employees who
happen to be under a labourers ’ Union.
Now, how ridiculous can you ge
t! The only reason I do not object is
because I can not look at them in the center and say : ‘ I can
certainly say to you that I can give to you a rep to
service you ’. And if I did say it, I would have to look
them in the eye and say: ‘I am going to give you a rep
who is putting in 80 hours a week and is
driving 35,000 miles a year. He is
really going to be able to service
you ’. How can I do it ?
114
364 115
Ibid., 84.
116
These criticisms were still being made despite the concrete
progress that had been made in reduc
ing the local-to-staff ratio
between 1965 and 1967 ( see postpone 1 in chapter
9), which perhaps reflected that new staff was not being equally distributed
geographically or sectorally. 117
Ibid., 49, 84.
A delegate from Kitimat Local 707 echoed these concerns : CUPE was losing members to unions like the International Union of Operating Engineers and T
he United Brotherhood of Car
penters “ plainly because we did not have organizers from CUPE to go and do the job. ”
115
In other words, at some point the financial
constraints would impede CUPE ’ s growth and capacitance to
organize its entire jurisdiction, since other unions
would fill a void wherever they could. Successful organizing and potent serve were consequently intertwined, and crucial to CUPE ’ s survival.
116
last, as we have already seen in the discussion of the National Defence Fund, CUPE needed more money in rate to be the kind of belligerent uni
on capable of winning full collective bargaining rights for
populace sector workers and making material gains for them a well. Hartman argued that, particularly in the subject of hospital workers,
Action 69-71
would help “develop a more dynamic, militant organization” which
would be capable of fighting aggressively both at deoxythymidine monophosphate
he bargaining table and against restrictive legislation.
such fiscal support would, for another delegate, be the merely room to make gains in the face of “ management who spares no expense to thwart all [ the workers ’ ] demands. ”
117
Given the plan ’ s practical vehemence on the National Office, and dogged resistance to much smaller per head increases in the past, the
1969 Convention inevitably involved a showdown between
centralizers and autonomists. In the lead-up to the Convention, diverse groups were now expressing their opposition to the plan. Locals 180 and 1000 informed the NEB in July 1969 that they could not support Action 69-71
, given the lack of consultation about the $1.60 per capita level set for provincial unions; their
accept required a denotative undertake,
written into the plan itself, that
they would get to negotiate directly
365 118
Local 1000, Per Capita Committee Report, October 1969: 4.
119
CUPE, National Executive Committee Minutes, June 20, 1969: 1.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 14, File 5]
120
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 63.
121
Crean, 123.
122
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 60, 61.
with the NEB the application of the program to them.
118
Opposition was also concentrated in the
Manitoba Division,
119
unusual given its NUPSE past and its tendency to go along with changes that would
strengthen the union at the national leve
l. However, the size of locals was a factor here: with a higher
assiduity of smaller units, CUPE Manitoba warned t
he NEB that the per capita increases would leave
very little leave for the locals and might impede thyroxine
heir participation in the broader labour movement.
120
many of the large and traditionally autonomist muni
cipal locals – 1, 43, 79, and 500 – also lined up
against the design. even though they were more able to a
fford the increases, they objected to the attempts to
turn CUPE into a “ centralized union like Steel. ”
121
A challenger for the National Presidency – Wallace
Higgins, president of Local 79 – emerged from their mids
t to articulate their criticisms. Higgins issued a
four-page review of
Action 69-71
, which he presented on the Convention floor, containing three major
themes besides echoed by other delegates. First, many
of the proposals were deemed to be “empire building”,
presumably on the part of Little, and “ of little use to
our members without fantastic costs.” Here the
stress was on distinguishing between those services
that would actually help the members, and other
that would only aid them indirectly by making the staff ’ s occupation easier. The latter were defined as “ frills ” which could be dispensed with. Higgins argued that the chromium
eation of the Job Evaluation Department, the addition
of personnel to the Legislative and Public Relations D
epartments, and the establishment of library services
at the National Office would “ not [ be ] a direct servic
e for the members” but rather for the benefit of Officers
and staff, and therefore a frill that the coupling could not afford.
122
A second base and refer objection was the monetary value of praseodymium
oposals relative to their benefit. Travelling
auditors were besides costly for the benefit they might
produce. The idea of home mailings of a national union
366 123
Ibid., 60-68.
124
W. Higgins, “Policy Statement on
Action 69-71
“, 1969: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46, File 14]
125
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 60.
newspaper, however, was the lightning perch drawing about universal reject. The
CUPE Journal
contained
honest-to-god news by the time it arrived in local union offices, and was largely unread by the membership in any event. Some predicted that even with home
mailings, “probably only 10% would read” the
Journal
. The
cost of postage and of maintaining an up-to-date mailing
list would make the venture far too rich for CUPE’s
blood. For many, this kind of proposal represented t
he NEB’s (or perhaps Little’s) “delusions of grandeur”
and a “ ostentatious ” desire to be more than CUPE was.
As Jim Neil from Local 555 in Winnipeg put it, “[t]his
is not a big affluent external, and we should not try to become one in one pace. ”
123
In that context,
CUPE could not afford to pay for things that
would not have a big pay-off for the money spent.
however, the crux of the matter for Higgins wa
s that CUPE was not and never would be sufficiently
like the international unions being held up as a template to
justify such centralization. While centralization
made sense for steelworkers and autoworkers because they were concentrated in detail industries and geographic areas, CUPE “ has Locals or potential Locals in
every community. Because of this difference
alone, centralization is dim-witted for them, but impossible for us. ”
124
Higgins argued that “in order to cope with
the hundreds of employers that we bargain with and
the thousands of classifications and skills that we
serve … CUPE must have potent, slightly autonomous local anesthetic Unions, District Councils, and Provincial Divisions. ”
125
Diversity would always make centralization im
practical and ineffective, as it required more
flexibility than was thought possible by a central organi
zation. According to this analysis, CUPE would be
much better off focussing on regionalization. Another major reservoir of protest came from a ra
latively new – yet growing – section of the CUPE
membership : hospital workers. Prior to the Convent
ion, and perhaps consumed with the problems of the
peasant union locals, hospital workers ’ discont
ent per se hadn’t appeared on the NEB’s radar. Attempts
367 126
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes July 6-7, 1968: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 12]
127
CUPE, 1967 Convention Proceedings: 120-1.
in Ontario to set up a hospital council in 1968 possibly signalled some discontentment with the service they were receiving,
126
but the NEB’s discussions of this move did not explore that possibility. Nor had hospital
workers expressed their interests in a coherent and
organized way at any previous convention, in part
because indeed many of them had been merely recently organized into the union. As a leave, hospital workers made a sudden and dramatic entrance onto the CUPE st
age at this Convention, introducing a different
set about to the per head tax debate and a very diffe
rent conception of how fairness and equality should
be sympathize and practiced within the coupling. hospital locals ’ delegates did not object importantly to the means of
Action 69-71
, nor to the
idea of a per head tax increase in and of itself. Ra
ther, they objected to an increase in the context of a
structurally unfair tax system based on flat rate
s rather than a percentage of one’s income. In other
words, CUPE had long used a regressive form of tantalum
xation that presumed a uniformity amongst members in
terms of their bring conditions, their dicker world power
relative to their employers, and their resulting
incomes and standards of animation. however, the in
flux of hospital workers – along with school board
employees and greater numbers of part-timers – meant
that such assumptions were no longer valid and
sustained a per head arrangement unfair to a meaning
portion of the membership. Others had previously
raised the topic of a differential gear rate for half-time
workers at the 1967 convention by putting forward a
resolution to have members working less than 24 hours per
week pay 50% of the regular per capita tax
rate. This proposal was rejected on the basis that it would introduce a form of second-class union citizenship, and would interfere with equality in a union
already sensitive about differential per capita rates
for finical groups.
127
Now a renewed debate on the issue had more force, since, according to Hartman,
hospital workers constituted 30 % of CUPE ’ s membersh
ip. This growing constituency within the union
pointed to the contradictions of “ going on commemorate as advocating the Carter Commission Report [ which
368 128
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 49, 65, 54.
129
The arguments for and against percent
age-based per capita are explor
ed more fully in Chapter 9.
130
Ibid., 59.
131
Ibid., 73.
sought progressive tax income at the federal level ] while the union itself was using “ the most capitalist outline always devised in taxation ” that was designed to “ keep
the poor poor, and the wealthy wealthy.” With the
lowest wages in CUPE, and most without the right to
strike, some hospital workers felt that “the national
office is doing nothing to help hospital workers ” and were convinced “ that they will not do anything in the future. ”
128
While others were not so cynical, hospital worker
s made it clear that they would resist increases
angstrom long as the union did not have a percentage-based per
capita system that would redistribute wealth and
parcel the price of unionism in a more equitable way.
129
Given the quarrelsomeness of both the substance
of the proposals and their price tag, three days
debate over per caput ensued. hera issues of
content and process intertwined in complicated and
dramatic ways. Aware that a detached and full air
of the proposal would be required before the delegates
would sign on, the NEB led the Convention into a Co
mmittee of the Whole for two hours, during which no
motions or directives could be issued.
130
This operation besides allowed the Executive to assess the extent of support or resistance, and to plan what if any modifications to
Action 69-71
they might make. However, the
first round off of debate attend delegate after delegate lining up to decry the design, emphasizing excessive price and misplaced priorities. In a display of democratic responsiveness but besides
political pragmatism, the NEB came back the
next dawn with a substitute resolution which reduced the per head demanded to $ 2.60, would see it phased in over two years, and would place vehemence on spend in the areas of organizing, servicing and inquiry.
131
Some of the most contentious
items, like the home mailing of the
CUPE Journal
, were
jettisoned. Debate only heated up after this move, however. Proponents of the plan rallied and in some cases berated the delegates for their childish short-
sightedness, tight-fistedness which parallelled that of
369 132
Ibid., 74, 79.
133
Kealey Cummings, interview by author,
17 December 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
134
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 86-7.
135
Kealey Cummings, interview by author,
17 December 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON.
management, and unwillingness to make sacrifices like
earlier generations of unionists. Some opponents
became tied more entrenched, deeming the NEB ’ s subs
titute resolution an attempt to manipulate the
delegates. John Miller from Toronto Hydro Local 1 chromium
ied that “we have been the victims of the biggest
snow-job in a long while ” ; in this channel of think, the NEB had wasted an integral day of the convention presenting a program far greater
than they thought they would actua
lly get from the delegates, in order
to make them glad with a reasonably dilute even still meaning per head increase.
132
In this agonistic context, the question was call
ed on the new motion. Little declared a standing
vote won by the necessity two-thirds majority, and
was promptly challenged. Cummings took the chair,
and conducted another standing right to vote with “ the doors … nailed close, never mind tiled ”, which the staff, reporting to Prairie Regional Director Bud Hender
son and Director of Organization Lofty MacMillan,
manually counted.
133
The outcome apparently confirmed Little’s
original ruling: 492 in favour, 220 against.
again, the results were immediately questioned,
but on more serious grounds: the number of votes
exceeded the issue of read delegates by 35. little,
with the elections for National Officers coming
up late that sidereal day, knew that more
was at stake than the approval of
Action 69-71.
He hypothesized that
more delegates had arrived since the last Credentials
Committee report, and that, when they issued their
final examination report before the elections, he hoped “ it will conf
irm that [the vote] was very much in order.”
134
Cummings, however, by and by said he could see the problem immediately, knew the result would be perceived as bastard ( even if it had passed in reality ), and
argued in the Executive Board meeting that a new vote
had to be taken evening though the two-thirds majority for the increase might not be forthcoming.
135
These hopes were soon to be dashed. The Credent
ials Committee confirmed that while there
were more delegates present than previously indi
cated, there was still a 31-person discrepancy in the
370 136
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 110.
137
Ibid., 116, 124.
vote.
136
The Convention agreed to vote a third time, this ti
me by secret ballot, after the elections. Surely
small must have been fearful of what impact the per
ceived manipulation of the decision-making process
might have on the Presidential subspecies, peculiarly giv
en the not-too-distant memory of the 1967 Convention
debacle. however, Little won the day handily, with 459
votes to Higgins’ 148. Moreover, Hartman was also
reelected to her point over challenger Hugh Lennon,
from Toronto Board of Education Local 134, who
admitted he ran because of his belief that “ no position, w
hether it be at the national
level or otherwise, should
go by undisputed. ”
137
The delegates had seen fit to give the leadership a pass, despite the substantive
disagreements and procedural problems. The delegates ’ discipline came in another shape : the loss of the one-third vote on
Action 69-71
by a mere
five votes. This resultant role forced the foster reduction of the per caput increase to 90 cents. furthermore, the first half of the change was to take effect only in
March 1970 and the second half a year later, leaving the
National the lapp level of income for six months
after the Convention. The increase to the National
Defence Fund was besides to be delayed for six months, although this was supplemented by $ 1 appraisal for each of December, January and February. The C
onvention was intent on making the leadership work
overtime for this atrophied husk of their original
proposal, and, on a motion from Bill Overkott of Local 43,
forced them to conduct an highly time-consuming coil call right to vote. Though the design finally passed, the NEB was incensed – and let the delegates know it
– not only because their intentions had been questioned
in preferably cardinal ways, but besides because they
would now have to manage the union’s growth, activity,
and members ’ even high expectations on a importantly reduced budget. Shirley Carr, Regional Vice- President from Ontario, was particularly ferocious and did
not hesitate to tear a strip off the delegates. Surely
371 138
Ibid., 138, 140-41, 143-48.
139
Crean, 124.
140
“The Little record … is a BIG record!”, pamphlet, CUPE, 1969 Conv
ention. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46, File
14 ] 141
Crean, 124.
142
Gilbert Levine, interview by Susan Crean,
December 1995, tape recording, Ottawa, ON.
many feared whether CUPE would be able to enter thyroxine
he 1970s capable of facing what Little predicted would
be its “ baptism of ardor. ”
138
V.
Conclusion
The 1969 Convention was a major turn point for CUPE, in some ways “ where the fusion truly took identify. little and Hartman were elected handily, as if they were a team. ”
139
Indeed, Little’s 1969
campaign literature featured
a picture of the two together at a pr
evious convention, hands clasped, their
other hands raised in victory.
140
As well, Crean argues, “there was
no question that the convention had
succeeded in formulating an ambitious plan for the fu
ture – something unimaginable two years before.”
141
The second coming of newfangled personalities had made it possible
to move beyond the stand-off between Little, Rintoul
and their respective followers ; surely, Hartman wa
s seen by many as a compromiser, and her relative
inexperience with fiscal matters gave Little an advantage he hadn ’ thyroxine had with Rintoul.
142
As well, the joint
necessity of having to make such a decentralized or
ganization function and provide a significant amount of
serve fostered a common committedness to the National triiodothyronine
hat overshadowed former loyalties. A substantial
expansion of National services, including a National Defence Fund, was the result. however, greater one at the deoxythymidine monophosphate
op, though certainly crucial for the union to make progress, did not
mean all the cracks had been sealed up. Each convention in this time period was taken up with a drawn-out and cranky debates over growth, whose baffling
effects could no longer be ignored. These problems
translated into a debate over expansion of services,
and the finances required to fund the growing union’s
activities. While delegates continually pressed for solutions to the union ’ s fiscal problems, the
372 143
CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 44.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File 15]
144
Ibid., 43-44.
insufficient number of staff representatives to serv
ice local unions, underfunded research facilities, and the
ever-expanding want to organize the unorganized, they were
reluctant to provide the National Office with
the resources to solve these problems.
143
Underlying everything was the
delegates ’ incredulity that the centralization of services systematically proposed by
the National Executive was either necessary or
desirable solution, particularly in light of the
questionable procedures in evidence at both the 1967 and
1969 Conventions. As such, even though much more unite by the end of the 1960s, CUPE was not actually able to overcome its self-reinforci
ng cycle of autonomy, making it difficult to construct a solid financial basis
for central structures and reconfirming therefore
me quarters’ discontent with the National.
This menstruation was besides characterized by a conf
luence of anti-centralist sentiment and democratic
backfire against the leadership. Leaders were haunted by
the mistrust left over from the 1967 leadership
struggle, and punished for perceived attempts to m
anipulate the decision-making process at the 1969
convention. This suspicion of the cardinal leadership ’ sulfur intentions led to a major scaling down of
Action 69-
71
. The “ambitious plan” was circumscribed from
the outset by the delegates’ refusal to approve the
original per head proposal and their insistence that
service to members rather than the National Office had
to be the precedence. In October 1969, the NEB ’ second firs
t order of business was to discuss how to trim down
Action 69-71
to fit with the reduced per capita increase approved by the Convention. Home mailings of the
CUPE Journal
, the 5% reserve fund, union label promoti
on, full-time auditor and Public Employee Week
were promptly eliminated.
144
This paradoxical outcome – that
members desired and demanded increased
services but were unwilling to pay for them out of
fear of a too-powerful National Office – was to be
repeated at convention after convention over the adjacent thirty years. The impression that ‘ democracy ’ was vested in locals ’ capacity to say no to leaders was fu
rther entrenched, and the questions about whether the
substance and procedures of the National Executiv
e and Convention were sufficiently accountable or
373 participatory was left unexamined and unreformed. Th
is was to become particularly problematic as
CUPE ’ s persistent growth continued to alter the terr
ain on which effective democratic representation and
participation could take position. ultimately, the union was ineffective to stabilize the poise between its peasant unions and autonomist locals. peasant unions ’ ‘ justly ’ to negotiate immediately
with the National leadership over its obligations to the
rest on the union was entrenched in 1965, but in such a washington
y as to make this process invisible to the wider
union. This fostered simmer resentment amongs
t traditional autonomy seekers and created pressures
for ‘ particular deals ’ to be eliminated to bombastic locals or
eliminated altogether. The political pressure for
rebates was besides to affect decisions about how thymine
he union should best respond to the needs of its growing
membership. furthermore, even with the right to direct
ly deliberate with the National over its per capita,
Locals 180 and 1000 remained discontented, resisted any
greater obligations on their part, and as such
refused any further consolidation into the union.
The 1969 Convention debate resulted in Local 180’s
disaffiliation, a serious fiscal blow to the ever-struggling union. Thus, even though the union had consolidated its structures, it was unclear whether
it would enter the next period equipped to take on the
challenges of growth, home demographic changes, and greater combativeness, all the while attempting to preserve some likeness of democracy .
374 1
See Table 1; Data in this table is compiled from the R
eports of the National President
and National Secretary-Treasurer
submitted to each CUPE
Convention between 1965-1973.
2
S. Little, National President’s Report, CU
PE, 1973 Convention Reports: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File 26]
chapter 9 : Can the Union Make Us Str
ong? The Contradictions of Growth, 1969-1975
Whether by purpose or not, CUPE ’ second emergence during its beginning ten years was phenomenal. Whereas in October 1963, proper after the amalgamation, the fresh marriage
had just over 75,000 members, by October 1973 this
number had grown to 182,000, representing a 140 %
increase over CUPE’s initial membership.
1
Put
another direction, every calendar month closely 1000 people
were joining CUPE during this period.
2
Notable additions to
the membership in this period included the three Hydro Quebec locals, the CBC ’ s clerical, professional and production workers, and a constant menstruate of hospita
l workers. The union was also expanding in the
university sector and, as constantly, attempting to attrac
t Ontario civil servants. Although CUPE also withstood
some major disaffiliations in this period, including
all the BC hospital workers in Local 180 in 1969, new
members and a steadily inflow of locals that had remai
ned out of the union at merger kept growth rates
impressive. In this regard, CUPE was successfully
fulfilling a major component of its initial mandate.
postpone 1 : CUPE Membership and Field Staff Growth, 1963-1973 Month / Year
Membership
% Increase
% Cumulative Increase
# Locals
# Field Reps
# Locals / Rep
October 1963
75,726 June 1965
90,371
19
19
552
24
23 June 1967
111,951
24
48
600
58
10 June 1969
138,705
24
83
N.A.
60
N.A
June 1971
156,375
13
107
823
77
11 June 1973
181,798
16
140
987
78
13 While such numbers distinctly pointed to CUPE ’ s successful appeal, they besides signalled a series of major dilemma. Growth came with a hefty pric
e tag, both financial and polit
ical, and had contradictory
implications for a decentralized arrangement predicat
ed on the servicing model. Specifically, growth
375 created as many problems as it solved and CUPE was unable to deal with these difficulties without provoking significant inner political unrest
amongst both longstanding and new members. From 1969
onwards, the challenges of growth, combined with
the entrenched decentralizati
on in the union, created a
series of crises that made it difficult for
the union to be both a democratic and effective union.
Growth continued to drive a series of internal
tensions which had remained unresolved from before
the fusion. There was continuing consider over west
hat balance should be struck between new organizing and
servicing the already existing membership, in term
s of both financing and other resources. CUPE faced
constantly growing pressures for more staff, particula
rly given its pursuit of the servicing model. However,
given the chronic underfunding of the nat
ional level of the union, staff were consistently unable to carry out
this character to the standards expected by a growing membership, and neglected out of necessity the organization of new groups. As such, CUPE found it diffi
cult to fulfil the servicing and organizing role it had
set out for itself as a key motivation for the fusion. CUPE besides had to deal with the question of how to integrate new groups into the existing CUPE structure. The kinds of workers now being intr
oduced into the union tended to face more centralized
employers, and were less well served by revolutionary declination
entralization and local autonomy. As well, these new
members tended to be women engaged in ailing paid work in hospitals who were much less able to suffer financially impregnable local union structures on thei
r own. New groups therefore introduced a series of
centralize pressures through their calls for provinci
al or national bargaining structures, requiring the union
to consider how it might need to change its struct
ure to serve the needs of a changing membership.
furthermore, new groups challenged CUPE ’ sulfur identity and ther
efore its priorities in new ways, and brought to
the bow the necessitate to rethink the basis of one,
such that it was, on which the union had been founded.
however, given the continue entrenchment of gr
oups invested in autonomy, CUPE found itself unable to
develop raw structures effective adequate to meet these fresh needs .
376 Growth besides renewed debate about relations of control, democratic or differently, at respective levels of the union. Growth challenged CUPE to figure out how to balance administrative efficiency and coordination with democratic participation and grassroot
s control. However, while members began to feel
alienated from their ever-growing union, the drawing card
ship’s tendency was to examine relationships and
structures at the top, and to seek administrative solu
tions that would centralize control, rather than develop
and enhance structures that might increase the connections between unlike levels of the marriage. Size besides meant an increasing insulation of the National
leadership from forms of accountability, like delegate
control over Convention consider and contested elec
tions. Most leaders considered this a positive
exploitation, for it released them from the particulari
st concerns of different groups and allowed them to
consider national interests. however, it besides meant that the National Officers were constantly at risk of losing touch with legitimate needs in respective regions
and sectors. In the context of decentralization and the
growing difficulty of sustaining coalitions across locals
to fight for alternatives, the height of democratic
expression in the union continued to be saying no to
the leadership, or exiting the organization.
ultimately, in the grimace of a beckon of working-
class militancy in the early 1970s, CUPE faced the
doubt of whether its decentralized model of unionism
would be sufficient to support its members in their
conflicts with employers and governments. While
CUPE had set up a central strike fund in 1967, the
disjunction between local control over collective
bargaining and central responsibility for strike benefits
mean that the union was chronically in deficit, ther
eby reinforcing the sense that the National could not
effectively serve members ’ needs. I.
Servicing Union or Organizing Union?
As we have seen, the beginning major finish of the 1963 fusion was to provide a high level of professional service to members. While l
eaders and members may have differed on what kind of
377 3
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 63-
4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File 4].
4
CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 22.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File 15]
5
Richard Bird, “The Growth of the Public Sector in Canada.” In
Public Employment and Com
pensation in Canada: Myths and
Realities
, ed. D.K. Foot (Scarborough, ON: Butterworths and
Co.,1978), 41; CUPE, 1965 Convention Proceedings: 21. CUPE
Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 8, File 9 ] service was a priority, they created a union whic
h provided both technical services like collective
bargaining research, union education, and legislative brie
fs, as well as day-to-day assistance to locals in
their dealings with management, and particularly with grievances, arbitration, and the negotiation of collective agreements. overall, deoxythymidine monophosphate
he trend in the union was to professionalize this servicing as much as
possible, flush when the field representative had been
drawn from the CUPE membership. While there
were arguments about how much serve should be expected, how much it should cost, where in the social organization such experts should be located and to
whom they should be accountable, both leaders and
members were quite enamoured with what ‘ expertness
’ could do for workers’ bargaining effectiveness and
standard of life and both disdained the am
ateurism characteristic of previous forms of servicing. In the
coupling ’ s early growth, it was thus very rare to
see this servicing model questioned. Only Bill Baker
from Local 1 went on record in this period to articula
te the problematic implicati
ons of fostering membership dependence upon the National and its representatives.
3
Otherwise, the idea that it was the union’s
province to provide dear technical, professi
onal servicing was hegemonic, and was a key rationale
used to organize new locals.
4
As a leave, the handiness and quality of serve was a major political issue in CUPE from the beginning. The irregular major goal of amalgamation was to create
a large, dynamic union capable of organizing the
exponentially growing numbers of unorganized public empl
oyees. There were several motivations for
pursuing growth. First, the count of unorganized
workers in CUPE’s jurisdiction was constantly
expanding. For exemplify, in the ten years before CUPE ’ s constitution, the count of municipal workers about doubled.
5
Similarly, general public employment was gr
owing at a rate of 3.3% in the 1960s, with
378 6
Bird, 27.
peasant employment growing at
a phenomenal rate of 8.2% per year.
6
In the context of a rapidly growing
public sector, there was about no choice but for
CUPE to organize its burgeoning jurisdiction in order to
conserve and increase union concentration levels and their
consequent bargaining power. Second, there was also
a actual desire and feel of duty to provide a
ll public sector workers with access to the kind of
unionism that was believed would actually protect thei
r interests. This goal also explains in part why
CUPE ’ sulfur leaders systematically pushed at the boundaries of
their jurisdiction, particularly with respect to
provincial civil servants and populace workers represented by external unions. ‘ One big union ’ in the canadian populace sector would help workers not fair by rationalizing the jurisdiction, reducing fragmentation and waste of resources, and increasing coordinati
on and bargaining power. It would also draw people
away from the civil service associations which we
re seen as company unions, and the internationals which
kept more canadian dues in the US than they
put back into servicing Canadian memberships.
Third, CUPE ’ sulfur expansion would serve the instrument
al power of its leaders by resulting in greater
leverage within the broader canadian labor move
ment. CUPE had the potential to outstrip the
membership levels of external private selenium
ctor unions, whose industries’ expansion had slowed and
whose focus had turned to consolidation and servic
ing already existing memberships rather than
aggressive pursuit of expansion. In other password
s, the size of the CUPE bloc in the Canadian Labour
Congress would finally require an analogous level
of influence for CUPE’s leaders. Finally, more
members meant more money in the class of per hundred
apita tax, which would hopefully permit the further
expansion of National services. indeed, in some peri
ods, as in the aftermath of the 1969 Convention, the
union was able to accomplish through increase an incr
ease in revenue and therefore National programming
that would otherwise have been impossible given Conv
ention delegates’ consistent predilection for fiscal
379 7
CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 21.
8
CUPE, 1965 Convention Proceedings: 21.
9
Ibid., 20.
restraint.
7
As a result, there was a consensus at the top
and in other sections of the membership that the
union “ should be organizing quite vigorously. ”
8
However, a second assumption implied by these motivations
was that evening while current membership interests might
be best met in the short term by allocating all the
resources to servicing, in the long term this would
be an insufficient strategy. As a result, the membership
had to be convinced that growth was in triiodothyronine
heir interests and that they had to fund it.
II.
“Expecting the Per Capita to Perform Miracles”:
The Dilemmas of Balancing Organizing and Servicing
Both service and organizing fell under the auspice
s of the Organization Department. While this
structure may have made some common sense, given that
the people who organized a new unit would also have to
service it, the practice besides introduced some impor
tant contradictions. Ev
en though the CUPE membership
agreed in a general way with the need to organize newly
members, their day-to-day needs would always
come inaugural. Since the same staff were assigned to
perform both servicing and organizing, a conflict existed
around how much time and energy to devote to each functi
on. Naturally, servicing would win in this tug of
war, since already-existing dues-paying members coul
d always pull harder than not
-yet certified potential
members. As a leave, from the beginning, the majori
ty of the work performed by the evidently misnamed
Organization Department was servicing. consequently,
new organizing initially only received “less than ten
percentage of [ the Department ’ s ] effort ” which could onl
y “be accomplished when as the servicing requirements
allow. ”
9
While there was recognition of this dilemma in the national leadership, who attempted to deal with
it by hiring impermanent organizers dedicated to the tantalum
sk, these efforts were limited in scale and impermanent.
In CUPE ’ s first decade, there plainly was not adequate money
at the national level to sustain specialization in
380 10
It was only in 1972, at a conference amongst the Director of Or
ganization, Regional Directors and Assistant Regional Directors
on Organizing Potential, that a complete word picture of the number
s of workers likely to join CUPE was compiled, and the needs to
achieve their membership clearly articula
ted – by the staff. In order to organize
the over 80,000 potential members nationally
,
the staff was insisting that “ a share of the CUPE Budget
be allotted to organizing”, and were unanimous in deeming the
lease of full-time, permanent organizers
“one of the most urgent matters” faci
ng the union (J. MacMillan / Department of
Organization, “ Organizing Potential ”, May 9, 1972 : 1-2. CU
PE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 7]).
field staff.
10
The fundamental contradiction betw
een organizing and servicing also played out at the level of the
coupling as a whole, particularly in the leadership ’ s lim
ited capacity to ensure that servicing would keep pace
with a growing membership. These contradicti
ons sustained the self-perpetuating cycle of autonomy-
seeking set up in the NUPE social organization, out of which the coupling was never able to extricate itself. While centralizers at the national level were occasionally su
ccessful in extracting from locals increased resources
and hence expanding services, they were never able to
alter the underlying logic of local autonomy which
insured the chronic underdevelopment of home service capacity. As we ’ ve already seen, defining and distributi
ng servicing amongst a static membership was
already unmanageable in CUPE, given the diverseness of the membership and competing notions of comeliness and equality. This dilemma was best represented by
the always latent, sometimes open conflict between
peasant unions and big local unions, who felt deoxythymidine monophosphate
heir servicing needs were no different and therefore
deserved alike fiscal easing and world power to negotiate their own needs immediately with the National. Because such accommodation was systematically rejected by the
NEB, large locals sustained a sense of bitterness at
the idea that the provincial unions received a higher
quality of service than the rest of the union.
furthermore, bombastic locals and minor locals besides c
onflicted over the kinds of service that should be
prioritized. The larger, more lay down locals
emphasized the development of technical services, since
they were able to pay for full moon clock time staff through t
heir locals dues, while smaller, poorer, newer and less
experienced locals wanted greater daily hel
p running their internal affairs and dealing with
increasingly advanced employers. The central sarcasm of CUPE is that the latter, who needed directly
381 11
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 66.
servicing from the National the most, were the least able
to afford its full cost, while the former, with the
most resources, were the least uncoerced to pay. It was
thus next to impossible to establish a “standard” of
servicing that everyone could expect and feel happy
with. Indeed, the union’s debates always avoided
explicit discussions of precisely what was needed. As Da
ve Werlin from Vancouver municipal workers Local
1004 pointed away at 1969 Convention, “ the question truly is
what do we … consider to be the needs of this
Union and, having determined that, how much is it going
to cost and at what level can we fix the services
that are going to be provided by this Union around a progr
am that is going to win for the workers … the kind
of working conditions and the standard of
living that they ought to have.”
11
However, no such discussion
was ever clearly had, and no substantiv
e consensus reached by the delegates.
continuous growth made it even more difficult
to establish and deliver a consistent standard of
service. While every newfangled group of members expanded
the dues base, there would always be a lag before
the costs of an organizing campaign would be ra
couped, and, depending upon the workers, there was no
guarantee that the money and staff fourth dimension spent on or
ganizing would always be recovered through dues. In
some instances, the price of establishing newfangled lo
cals went beyond initial organizing costs, and included
having to strike for a first base collective agreement, which locals had to bear themselves before the institution of the National Defence Fund in 1967.
The Hydro Quebec locals, in particular, demonstrated
the lag that frequently existed between the time a local is
organized and the moment that full per capita is being
paid to the National. In the interim, greater selenium
rvicing responsibilities were difficult to finance.
furthermore, given the reliance on the serve model and hence on national staff in the context of austere fiscal restraints, every extra local megabyte
eant greater demands on staff representatives already
stretched paper-thin. From the beginning, it was unclutter deoxythymidine monophosphate
hat staffers were having to provide services beyond
what was both reasonable and goodly. For the first fluorine
our years, most reps had to service an average of 23
382 12
MacMillan, 135-38.
13
CUPE, National Executive Committee minutes
, February 26, 1971: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 2]
14
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the National Executive Board, June 1971: 3.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.
15, File 2 ] 15
R. Lampron, letter to S. Little “Re: Crisis in Quebec R
egional Office” November 17, 1969; J. Brule, Y. Forest and A.
Thibaudeau, “ Report on the Situation in Q
uebec Region”, November 26, 1969. Both
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol.
14, File 7 ] 16
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 67-8.
locals, some in outback areas and across big distances. In separate, super-human demands on staff were sustained by a acculturation amongst the rep themselves of
machismo and heroic self-sacrifice in the service of
workers and the labor movement. A casing in point is the discernible pride that Lofty MacMillan expressed when describing the three cars he totalled travelli
ng the treacherous, snow-covered back roads of New
Brunswick organizing hospital workers night and day.
12
However, these demands on the staff would
finally hit a limit in multiple ways, harming both deoxythymidine monophosphate
he union as well as the reps themselves. Insufficient
staff numbers meant that servicing systematically
overshadowed organizing and made it next to impossible to
invention and carry out an organizing plan or respond to threatened disaffiliations.
13
Chronic overwork was
besides beginning to create health issues for reps : cons
tant stress was leading to higher incidence of illness,
alcoholism, long-run disability, and in
some cases premature death of staffers.
14
Such arduous working
conditions created problems with staff memory, par
ticularly in the Quebec Region, where other unions
were will to pay staff more and provide more humane working conditions.
15
Even though the National
successfully reduced by half the average service load of
field staff in the union’s first four years, this
improvement masked crucial regional
variations, in which some reps continued to service upwards of 26
locals spread across big distances. Clarence Dungey
, from Sault Ste Marie’s Local 3 and later an NEB
member, pointedly condemned the membership ’ second unr
ealistic and contradictory demands, which he felt
would finally take a good toll on the union ’ s employees : “ I fully expect some day to see one of my reps kill himself … because I say to my people : I want 40 hours a week but the people that work for me, I want them to work 1000 hours a week. ”
16
383 17
CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 6.
18
Local 1 attempted to get a rebate on a regular basis: in
September 1967, in December
1970, and again in December 1971;
Locals 15 and 43 cherished rebates as the price of their affiliati
on to the new CUPE in 1963; Locals 30 and 52 in Edmonton wanted
a 33 % rebate in December 1965. 19
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 65.
The inability of the union to ensure that servicing kept pace with growth worked to delegitimize National Office appeals for higher per caput and rhode island
sked undermining support amongst the membership for
far organizing campaigns. As service was not growing fast adequate, flush in the awaken of per caput increases in 1965 and 1969, existing locals were increasingly unwilling to give up more money to the kernel. rather, larger locals increasingly wanted to
keep a larger portion of dues at home. Little labelled
this attitude as “ the british pound of flesh syndrome ” in which
locals would make very detailed accountings of the
total of per head paid out versus the am
ount of servicing received from the National.
17
The alternative
being sought would see the locals supplement national serv
icing in technical areas with their own staff for
daily documentation, financed through per head rebates
under Section 7 (6) of the CUPE Constitution.
initially, the autonomists attempted to get rebates on
case-by-case basis, sometimes hiring staff precisely
to put blackmail on the National.
18
Indeed, local business agents continued to play a key role in fostering
autonomist sentiments and creating a material basis
for demanding rebates. When their requests were
systematically rejected by the National Executive, t
hese locals backed Convention resolutions seeking to
establish the principle of rebates to locals with metric ton
heir own staff, at the same proportion as that received by
the provincial unions. In these attempts, they us
ed the ‘evidence’ of the National’s chronic financial
problems, and the apparent health of Locals 1000 and 180,
to support the idea that the membership would
be better served by staff hired by their own locals, ev
en though their restraint was partly responsible for that
crisis in the first place.
19
When both of these strategies failed,
autonomists fell back to a negative strategy
of preventing per caput increases, therefore perpetuating
the cycle of limited national services, chronic financial
crisis, and local discontent .
384 20
The Public Employee
9 (3): 8; CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 31.
21
B. Black, “Interim Report re: the Appoi
ntment of a National Hospital Division
Coordinator”, September 1967: 3. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, F
ile 4]; CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 49.
22
B. Black, “Interim Report re: the Appointment
of a National Hospital Division Coordinator”, 4.
23
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 80-1.
24
White, 41
Limits on serve besides made coping with increase
difficult in another way: new locals, who had been
appealed to on the basis of being serviced by CUPE,
grew discontented when their expectations were not
constantly met. The majority of workers being organized in this menstruation were women and hospital workers, often one and the like, and more probably than in other
sectors to be part-time. These components of
CUPE ’ randomness membership grew quickly over a very shor
t timespan. While in 1968 30% of CUPE’s membership
consisted of women, a bare three years
later, in 1971, that proportion had hit 50%.
20
Similarly, fully 25% of
the marriage consisted of hospital workers in 1967, and 30 % in 1969.
21
In a study carried out for the National
Executive Board in 1967, Bill Black predicted that If triiodothyronine
he jurisdiction was fully organized, it was possible to
contemplate a CUPE dwell of 50 % hospital sour
ers in the near future, and this was likely based on
cautious estimates.
22
The particular characteristics of these workers and their sector had a direct
impact both on their relations with their em
ployers as well as with the broader union.
These newfangled members were much more probable to be
low-wage workers with little prior experience of
unionism and therefore more probable to be dependant on the National.
23
Hospital administrations had long relied upon the female ‘ ethic of care ’ to forestall collective action and combativeness and maintain hospital workplace as a low-wage ghetto for women.
24
Although the wave of unionization in this period proved employers
incorrect, these low-waged workers were besides creating ra
latively poor locals. When faced with demands to
pay more per caput tax, as in 1969, these new members felt unable to do sol, evening though they had the most to gain from extend National service and
organizing compared to members in other, more
densely organized sectors. Lucy Nicholson, from
St. Catharines hospital workers Local 1097 and later
president of the united states of the Ontario Division, articulated the postulate
ion of most hospital workers in this way: while she
385 25
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 72.
26
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
February 21-22, 1970: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 14, File 12]
27
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, De
cember 11-12, 1965: 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 7]
accepted the motivation for an increased per head, and agr
eed that more reps were needed, particularly by
new locals of hospital workers, they just couldn ’ t a
fford to be the ones to pay for it. She pointed out that
hospital workers did not have the same kind of bargai
ning power as other kinds of workers, both because
of the relatively amateurish nature of their work ampere well as
the legal restrictions placed on their right to strike in
many provinces. “ We are not a ship-building marriage,
and we are not a craft union of any description. You
can not expect us to pay the same sum of money
as other people do.” To drive the point home,
Nicholson went on to read out from the give stub of
a male hospital worker, showing that he took home
$ 135 every two weeks to support two children.
25
Such dynamics also interfered with the union’s growth, in
that it became more difficult to appeal to fresh low-w
aged groups with the promise of low-cost good service.
expansion frankincense meant ceaseless pressures to increase per
capita to pay for more staff, but also introduced
limits to that expansion because of deoxythymidine monophosphate
he kinds of workers now joining CUPE.
Assessing legitimate serve needs, and where
to concentrate the union’s energies, staff and
resources – among already existing members, in the loca
tions of greatest future potential, or in response to
those large locals demanding rebates, withholding per caput and threatening disaffiliation – was therefore a politically contentious action.
26
Rational rather than politically reactive decision-making was further
impeded by factionalism amongst leadership and staff.
For instance, at the end of 1966, Cummings and
Hartman were insisting that the union demeanor a dens
ity study to determine where to put new reps and
where to post jobs.
27
However, this was a mere month before Buss’ death, after which there would be a
year-long delay in finding a new Director of Organiza
tion, creating both a serious gap in CUPE services and
an incapacity to engage in longer-term planning rather
than ad hoc reaction to the current situation.
MacMillan ’ sulfur description of his beginning day as Director of
Organization illustrates just how completely factional
386 28
MacMillan, 140.
29
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 2-3, 1968: 1.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 9]
30
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 65, 82.
politics had eclipsed the considerations of functionalit
y, even where the central activity of organizing and
servicing locals was concerned : “ When I went into my
office, there wasn’t a picture on the wall or anything.
There had been cipher there in that position for a solid yttrium
ear. There were no statistics to tell you who was
organized and who wasn ’ thymine. There was nothing.
Just a piece of scrap paper and a pen on the desk.”
28
Three years into CUPE ’ s universe, the National Dire
ctor of Organizing had to start over from scratch and
sort through the multiple and competing demands pl
aced on the field staff now under his supervision.
The inflow of more ill paid workers raised the issue of how the coupling ’ s gross should be raised in the most equitable way and kept the need
for an alternative per capita system based on a
percentage rather than a flat pace on the agenda for the following 15 years.
29
It also introduced a new and
complicated dynamic into the local autonomy cycle. Hospital and early low-wage workers resisted the goodly per head increase demanded at the 1969 Convention,
since it made more sense that those “who are
making the money pay the blast in proportion to what
they are earning”; in other words, they were
advocating use of the principle “ from each according
to their ability, to each according to their need.”
however, they were joined in this resistance by large autonomist locals who were motivated by no such principle, but rather the equation “ to each according
to the ability to pay, from each whatever might be left
over. ” The goals of these two groups coalesced in
the medium term to block per capita increases, but
some were insightful adequate at the time to point out
the opportunism of the large locals who could well
afford a per caput increase. Douglas Lavalee, a hospital worker from Saskatchewan, argued that bombastic locals ’ ostensible concern for lower engage workers was very precisely a way to cover their resistance to a per capita tax addition with a morally satisfactory logic.
The result was “to deny us a programme where the
hospital workers can advance. ”
30
This points to the need to disentangle the different reasons why groups in
387 31
Ibid., 68, 139.
32
Ibid., 70, 139.
CUPE have hindered per head increases, and distingui
sh between the political solutions acceptable to
unlike constituencies. The dispute at the 1969 convention showed that speed of light
entralist National leaders were in fact slow to
spot and understand the relevance of the emergenc
e of this new constituency and their different
qualms with the per caput tax. alternatively, the Nati
onal Executive continued to frame the debate in the same
previous terms, polarized between ‘ narrow ’ autonomists and ‘ forward-thinking ’ centralizers, masking both legitimate concerns about inequalities ampere well as a
potentially permanent and fair solution to the union’s
chronic fiscal problems. Centraliz
ers put themselves the side of progress; those resistant to an increase
were advocating stagnation and were inconsistent, having themselves asked for a future plan for CUPE in 1967, and now preventing the very thing that woul
d allow for the improvements they were demanding.
31
One delegate put it starkly, demanding
of the Convention: “Do you want a 25¢ union? Do you want a two-
bit union ? Or what do you want ? Or do you want a uni
on that is going to progress and get the things you
want … And I think that despite all the fantastic speec
hes in the world, either you are going to progress
ahead, or you are going to drop binding, or you are going
to dissolve.” For others the culprit was crass, self-
concerned, and short-sighted materialism, which invited comparisons with tight-fisted managements.
32
Les
Blackburn, from local 133, most myst
ified the debate by completely eliminating the distinctions within the
anti-increase coalition by assuming he was talki
ng only to the autonomist locals who had been at the
vanguard of resisting a higher per caput in the fusion procedure. For him, the “ people crying in their beer ” were the same ones saying at the founding convention that they could not afford it. And we came away
from Winnipeg with less money that we needed to start off
with and, from each consecutive convention from her
e on in, we have asked for more money and got about
half of what we asked for until now … And it does not change the fact that they hush do need the sum of money that they asked for in the inaugural plaza. And if
we do not get that money here at this convention, we will
still be in the red at the next convention and you will still
be crying in your beer. Somebody had said that this
is a baby union. You are correct. And a lot of you ar
e acting like babies. Do you want a union or don’t you
388 33
Ibid., 74.
34
Ibid., 80.
35
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, No
vember 29-30, 1969: 2. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 14, File 8];
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings : 80. want a union ?
33
While this kind of grandiosity may have been deserved by
some of the larger autonomist locals, it was to be
expected that proponents of percentage per caput
system would feel both misunderstood and somewhat
resentful. even though the pressure to adopt a percentage-based
per capita tax was strong in 1969, the full
adoption of such a system was not to come for
another 20 years. Even though Local 134 member Hugh
Lennon believed that the delegates could have forced t
he NEB to implement the proposal in 1969, Little
clearly said no to percentage per head tax, that “ we can not do it now. ”
34
Instead, the NEB proposed that it
study the ramifications and examine opposing opinions
before moving forward. Three resolutions on
share per capita were referred to the NEB for study, one of them from the NEB itself.
35
The incoming
Board was instructed to come back to the future Convent
ion with a resolution on a new structure for the per
head organization. A class later, the NEB issued its
Policy Statement on Percentage Per Capita Tax
, which indicated a
bewilderingly ambivalent approach. The NEB accepted thymine
hat the union should be moving in this direction, as
the current method of raising finances was inequitable. however, the new system would have to be designed so as to ensure it would produce the lapp am
ount of revenue as at present. The National Office
could not tied begin to establish a rate that would
have such a result. It was claimed that the knowledge
they required, the income levels of their members, was not centrally held at the national horizontal surface. As a solution, a share per caput system would have to be built through a gradual action ; for the time being all the National could do was to encourage existing locals to adopt a share system. New locals would adopt a share due system so they would create the barium
is for changing over in the future, but the NEB
389 36
CUPE, National Executive Committee minutes, June 25, 1971.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 3]
37
CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 106.
would not be recommending a change to this system at the 1971 Convention.
36
however, the discussion at the 1971 Convention revealed a less technical reason for why the union would not be moving forward with a share system.
Hartman pointed out that the other unions which
had percentage per head besides had centralized remittanc
e, where employers would send money directly to
Head Office and locals would receive their plowshare from thyroxine
he National or International Office. As such, she
seemed to be arguing, the two inherently went toget
her, and “the recommendation is that until we have a
centralized account organization whereby all dues ar
e submitted to National Headquarters, percentage per
capita tax can not be instituted. ”
37
Of course, tying these two
changes together doomed the percentage
organization for many years to come, for it involved
more than a mere administrative change. Centralized
remittance would mean a revolutionary fault in power wisconsin
thin the union; it would certainly ease the union’s
fiscal troubles, but, more importantly, locals w
ould no longer have the power to withhold dues as a
political creature to put pressure on the National. In deoxythymidine monophosphate
he culture of local autonomy,
this idea was a non-starter,
which the NEB must have known. It was about as though NEB designed the issue then as to prevent share per caput from being considered by tying it to a radically centralizing geomorphologic exchange. A share per caput system would be unpopular wisconsin
th the traditionally autonomist locals for this
rationality, and besides because, as the affluent locals, it would likely require more money of them in absolute terms. In other words, the alliance struck at deoxythymidine monophosphate
he 1969 Convention was inherently unstable. The supporters
of share per capita were in fact asking the autonomis
t locals to sacrifice more. Hospital worker Vic
Saumure from Ottawa Local 576 had appealed not to the National Officers, but to the boastfully and affluent locals, “ our Brothers and Sisters who are a little more
fortunate – and some of them are a heck of a lot
more fortunate – than most of the hospital workers ”
and asked them to “please give us a hand and help us
390 38
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 69.
39
Bird, 25. As Bird shows, in 1975, municipal government workers made up 11.1% of to
tal employment in the public sector, while
hospital employment was at 17.1 %. parcel this monetary value of unionism and we will all be Br
others and Sisters. We will be a great force.”
38
This, of
course, big autonomist locals would not do without
a fight, preventing any anti-increase coalition from
being able to build a more equitable alternative to the system in space. III.
Feminizing CUPE: Gender Chall
enges to Identity and Structure
expansion into particular parts of the public southeast
ctor meant other kinds of internal demographic
transformation. As has already been shown, by
1973 CUPE was less a union of male, quasi-industrial
blue-collar workers and increasingly a union of female
, white and pink collar, and professionalized service
workers. While CUPE and its predecessors had always
encompassed some of these quantities, it was in
the context of an overall preponderanc
e of unionism’s traditional constituency. By 1973, however, this
dominance was, at least numerically, sternly curtailed, reflecting broader trends in the types of populace use experiencing the most growth.
39
This raised questions about whether and how the union could
accommodate the particular needs and situations of deoxythymidine monophosphate
hese members while also forging solidarity between
old and newly groups. These debates reflect the pressu
re to expand the conception of unionism, including
questions of what unions should do for their mem
bers and what good union citizenship means, beyond that
which was defined by the industrial working class,
and to create an organization capable of representing
the ‘ new working class ’ that had emerged in the post-war earned run average. The tensions around accommodating women, while
collar workers and professionals intertwined in
authoritative and concern ways
in the 1971 Convention debate about
The Status of Women in CUPE
, a
hearty NEB policy wallpaper developed in the wake up of
the federal Royal Commission of the Status of
Women. It must be noted that this was credibly
the first substantial debate on gender issues at
any
post-
391 40
CUPE,
The Status of Women in CUPE
, 1971. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File 17]
war union conventionality in Canada, and reflects both
how substantially the demographic shift had changed
CUPE ’ s agenda and the leadership ’ second desire to accommodat
e the interests of new members. Although
there was significant discussion at the Convention of the miss equitable gender theatrical performance in union leadership roles, the bulk of the policy recommendati
ons were issues that would have to be taken up by
locals themselves. The document listed a fixed of concerns that subsequently formed the congress of racial equality of CUPE ’ randomness equality agenda : pay equity and wage discrimination, occupational segregation and employment equity, paid motherliness leave and child wish.
40
Many of these proposals recognized the way in which women’s
know of ferment was inseparable from their experi
ence of the home, the fam
ily and the discriminatory
practices and ideas which permeate social relations
in general. In that, the union was putting forward an
analysis of why peer outcomes for members had to enta
il differential and remedial policies, as not all
members started out at the same place. This was
a new basis for solidarity that challenged some long-held
ideas about peer treatment in the union. Some participants in the consider articulated why it
was in men’s interest to support women’s
particular interests. As Hartman pointed out, west
age discrimination had a negative impact on men, even
though they besides benefited from higher wages. In thymine
he long run, pay inequities “would hold down the wages
of men. You can ’ t have a big, well-qualified
group of working people who are getting less money than
another group. [ M ] anagement is not going to sit idly by
and pay the high-priced group if they can get the
low-cost group with equal qualifications. ” Remarkably,
however, Ontario Division president Percy Huggett
appealed to the male delegates on a deeper flush. Because “ the male self depends very largely on the subordinate put of women in the male-female relationship ”, Huggett believed it was the personal responsibility of those who benefited from inequality, whet
her by conscious choice or not, to be involved in
392 41
CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 32, 37-8.
42
Ibid., 33.
43
White, 60-62.
44
CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 34.
eliminating it.
41
Truly integrating women into the union woul
d require men to give something up, both
materially and psychologically. other aspects of the argue revealed how complic
ated forging solidarity amongst the diversity of
members would be. It wasn ’ triiodothyronine simply that male, blue-
collar members were resistant to including the union’s
new entrants. Rather, expansion into new jurisdicti
ons had introduced occupational identities with their own
particular cultures, expectations, and consciousness,
which often departed from traditional conceptions of
the “ effective union penis ”. Both male and female sulfur
peakers in the debate talked about the resistance that
existed amongst women themselves to embrace liberation “ because then [ they ] would have to work excessively much. ”
42
Supporting this complaint was the difficulty one hospital local reported in getting women involved
in the run of the local ; while at this point t
here was little analysis of the reasons why women faced so
many barriers to participation in union life, such as their socially defined province for the family,
43
there
was however a perceived gap between women ’ s
“desire for equal rights and accepting equal
responsibility. ” This was exacerbated by what was seen as professional elitism and narrow opportunism on the character of some women workers : in the shell of
one hospital, it had proven impossible to mobilize
Registered Nurses Assistants until bargain, at which ti
me “all they were interested in was that … they got
a dollar more than the [ male ] orderlies. ”
44
In other words, forging solidarity across gender, occupational
and status lines involved socializat
ion of both older and newer members.
ultimately, however, while the agenda set out by
The Status of Women in CUPE
was decidedly progressive for its time, it was primar
ily a collective bargaining agenda and therefore a local
affair. What remained unaddressed at the time
was the way that CUPE’s decentralized structure – and
particular local control over bargaining – could nev
er ensure that progressive policies on gender equity
393 45
Ibid., 36, 45, 33.
would actually be implemented. Cummings ’ comments during the argument revealed the problem : all the National leadership could actually do was remind the del
egates of their “immediate obligation, upon leaving
this Convention, to go back to their local union and impl
ement all the ingredients of
this report.” Hartman,
after all the employment put in on both the composition and the
federal Royal Commission, of which she was a part,
could alone “ hope ” for it to be taken up by local leaders. even little, in responding to questions about why each Convention committee had alone one token woman tungsten
hen the centrepiece of
the meeting concerned
gender equity, explained that the NEB was still more
concerned about represent
ing the key identities
associated with geography and occupation.
45
The Status of Women in CUPE
thus represented the first and
most visible model of the gap between the Nationa
l’s coherent and progressive policy direction and the
miss of policy implementation at t
he local (and, for now, National) level. In that sense, decentralized
structures continued to trump expansive identities. IV.
The Problem of Democracy: Accountabilit
y and Participation in a Growing Union
CUPE ’ randomness increase besides raised the classical one
ues of democratic accountability and membership
participation in mass organizations. Growth m
eant a greater distance
between national and regional
leadership on the one hand, and local anesthetic leaders and members on
the other. As well, the size and diversity of
the union made it increasingly difficult for regionally
-based leaders, let alone rank-and-file members, to
grasp the complexities involved in presidency. As
such, growth was seen by a portion of the leadership,
including the National Officers, as an administrative ra
ther than political problem. Membership needs were
systematically understood in terms of adequate serve,
rather than effective repr
esentation of the various
interests in the union. furthermore, there was littl
e priority placed on the development of membership
capacities : the collective romance with what exper
tise could accomplish fostered instead a psychological
394 46
Ibid., 22.
47
S. Little, Special Report of the National
President to the National Executive Board,
March 2-3, 1968: 2, 3. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 7 ] Emphasis in original. and material dependence on staff. ultimately, for Little, the arrangement ’ s primary problems in this period were sufficient “ technical and specialist development ”
and efficient administration at the National level.
46
He spent no time contemplating how to make union
more responsive to membership, and experiments with
processing argue on a boastfully scale were brief. many of
these efforts at increasing efficiency had the effect,
whether designed or not, of reducing leadership
transparency and accountability to the membership.
While a majority of National Executive Board members resisted the streamlining process advocated by the National Officers, they were unable to place triiodothyronine
he need for greater democratization on the union’s agenda in
a means that produced concrete results. little ’ sulfur preference for dealing with political public relations
oblems with administrative means stretched back to
the factional dispute with Rintoul and other erstwhile
NUPE leaders and staff. Throughout that period, Little
emphasized the problems with what he saw as the significant overlap in the roles of the NEC and NEB. He systematically articulated the topic in terms of thriftlessness rather than the fuss
some constraints of the
NEB ’ s oversight of his activities. immediately field-grade officer
llowing the 1967 Convention, Little moved to consolidate
and more intelligibly define the roles of the National Office
rs, the NEC and the NEB. This was to form a major
project for Little until his retirement in 1975. His
initial post-Convention report to the NEB was harshly
worded and focussed on mark settle. however, he
was also setting out the terms of his presidency,
revealing the political motivations which underwrote hawaii
s administrative concerns. He informed the Board
that he was “ not train to put in metric ton
he next 18 months like the last four years I put in … unless I have every
assurance that I am
not
going to be repaid by the same kind of cut-throat action that took place in the last
Convention. ” As such, Little wanted recognition of his role as “ CEO ” of the union, whose decision-making powers would inescapably include “ fiscal aspects. ”
47
The National Secretary-Treasurer was being told that
395 48
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the National Executive Board, November
22-24, 1968: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG
28, I234, Vol. 13, File 12 ] ; S. Little, National President ’ s
Report to the National Executive
Board, November 29-30, 1969: 1.
CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 14, File 6 ] 49
S. Little, and G. Hartman, “Report to the National Execut
ive Board on the Relationship
between the NEB, NEB and National
Officers ”, February 25, 1971 : 2. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 12 ] ; 50
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the National Executive Board, November
22-24, 1968: 1; S. Little, and G. Hartman,
“ Report to the National Executive Board on the Relationship between the NEB, NEB and National Officers ”, 2. 51
S. Little, and G. Hartman, “Report to the National Execut
ive Board on the Relationship
between the NEB, NEB and National
Officers ”, 4. 52
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the National Executive Board, November 22-
24, 1968: 2; S. Little, National President’
s
report to the National Executive
Board, November 29-30, 1969: 1.
she would not have accomplished control over her sphere of duty, and the NEB that, above all, they owed the National President a sealed amount of commitment. little ’ south late missives on the issue were signific
antly cooler in tone, suggesting Eady’s hand, and
laid out respective other reasons for his dissatisfac
tion with the way the NEC and NEB functioned based on a
shrill distinction between policy
and implementation. The NEB wa
s too consumed with “past happenings
and average administrative problems. ”
48
Both he and Hartman, who had collaborated with him on a joint
report on the topic in early on 1971, argued that it
was understandable that the NEB “was neglecting the
unmanageable character of governing ” because “ adminis
tration is more visible, more tempting.”
49
Instead, the NEB
should be engaged in the “ wide policy development
of CUPE” and concerned with translating the
“ mandate from the [ Convention ] delegates into policy. ”
50
Notably, the NEB’s right of final approval over
technical and field staff appointments, which had been allo
cated to them by the Convention, did not rightly
suit within its ‘ proper ’ policy-oriented officiate.
51
In practical terms, these recommendations would diminish
the NEB ’ mho capacity to assess the political implicati
ons of administrative decisions made by the National
Officers. similarly, the NEC was besides engaged in reviewing “ a
ll the major decisions going to the Board” and
should rather be dealing with matters either “ specifically
allotted to it by the NEB” or put before them by
the National Officers for consultation.
52
Current practices had resulted in “an almost complete duplication of
396 53
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the National Executive Board, November 29-
30, 1969: 1; S. Little, and G. Hartman,
“ Report to the National Executive Board on
the Relationship between the NEB, NEB and Na
tional Officers”, 1. This duplication of
effort is made real by the experience
of reading NEC and NEB minutes, which are almost exactly the same in terms of the
capacity of discussions and outcomes of decision-making. 54
S. Little, and G. Hartman, “Report to the National Execut
ive Board on the Relationship
between the NEB, NEB and National
Officers ”, 6. 55
S. Little, National President’s Report to the Na
tional Executive Board, November 23-24, 1968: 2.
56
S. Little, and G. Hartman, “Report to the National Execut
ive Board on the Relationship
between the NEB, NEB and National
Officers ”, 5. 57
Ibid., 4.
58
Ibid., 5.
make ”, which was undoubtedly incredibly frustrating
for National Officers and General Vice-Presidents.
53
If
they were not able to define a “ lawful role ” for the NEC more precisely, it was not authorize that “ there is any need, in hypothesis or in practice, for the Committee. ”
54
Evidently, the NEC’s traditional role of reviewing and
making recommendations on the issues put before the
Board by the National Officers was no longer seen
as serving any useful purpose. Little was besides now promoting the concept of “ c
abinet responsibility”. He argued that while the NEB
should have a vigorous argument about issues, once united states post office
licies were agreed upon it was their duty “to
jointly support those policies throughout the country, and in especial in the diverse regions. ”
55
Cabinet
province would counter what Little saw as the
excessively regionalist orientation of most NEB
members, which they tended to serve “ with lithium
ttle feeling for the national implications.”
56
Presumably
indicative mood of this minute regionalism was the NEB ’ s december
ision in late 1970 to add a field representative to the
Prairie Region, which Little and Hartman termed “ a clear invasion of the constituent responsibilities of the Officers. ”
57
They argued that “we cannot run a National Ex
ecutive Board on the basis of you scratch my
back and I ’ ll scratch yours, and we can not run a union
when that mutual back-scratching is done at the
expense of the proper authority and respons
ibility of the levels of management.”
58
All of this contradicted the National Officers ’ populace statements to Conventions about the NEB ’ south representational function. At the 1971 Convention, Littl
e proudly claimed it was the Regional Vice-Presidents
that represented “ the grassroots ”
of the union and helped maintain the National Officers’ awareness of and
397 59
CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 22.
60
S.Little, National President’s
Report, CUPE, 1973 Convention Reports
: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File 26]
connection to the issues of the absolute and charge ; this was peculiarly significant becaus
e of the way that growth
was increasing the administrative demands on the Nati
onal Officers and reducing their contact with the
membership.
59
However, “cabinet responsibility” would produc
e the reverse, a situation in which the NEB
would represent National interests to the grassroots.
While this was no doubt a pressing issue, given the
haunting centrifugal forces in the union, there was no
consideration of the more central problem of how to
balance wheel legitimate national and regional needs in a fa
ir and effective way. Instead, Little’s approach was
to praise the grassroots influence in public
, and decry its particularism in private.
The practice of “ cabinet duty ” would besides
have the effect of covering over dissent amongst
the leadership. While this was in separate intended to get
beyond the legacy of leadership factionalism, it would
alone do so in a superficial way. furthermore, w
hen seen in the context of other post-1967 developments
which were insulating home leaders from membership
scrutiny, the implications of this practice for
executive accountability were negative. First, the decisiveness to reduce NEB and NEC minutes to a summary of views without identifying speakers or recording west
ho voted how unless specifically requested, had already
dramatically cut back the testify of disagree or alte
rnative views within the leadership. Second, even had
these views been recorded, they would not have been ava
ilable to the membership. As Little explained to
the 1973 Convention, despite regular requests from all
levels of the union, “[b]ecause of the sensitive
nature of some of the discussions in the Board, mi
nutes cannot be circulated.” Instead, summaries of the
meetings were “ given reasonably wide circulation to sta
ff, district councils, etc.” and locals would have to get
access through these means.
60
In the menstruation that followed Little and Hartm
an’s special report, General and Regional Vice-
Presidents were asked to send in written responses
to the ideas. A minority of the Board, including
General Vice-Presidents Roger Lampron from
Quebec and Lloyd Jacobsen from Saskatchewan, and
398 61
R. Lampron, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman, n.d.: 1; L. Jacobsen, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman, n.d.: 1; E. Phillips, l
etter to
S.Little and G. Hartman, March 31, 1971 : 3. All CUPE Fonds [ N
AC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 2]. This correspondence
provide a much clearer picture of the virginia
rious positions within the National leadersh
ip at this moment than do the minutes.
62
P. Huggett, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman, March 25, 1971:
1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 2]
regional Vice-Presidents Ed Phillips from Manitoba and
Percy Huggett from Ontario, expressed support for
separating government and policy-making and, in parti
cular, for giving the National Officers exclusive
restraint over staff lease.
61
As Huggett put it, he had “never heard of
a company or corporation where the
Board of Directors hires employees. They appoint
people to do the job and allow them the freedom to do a
well job or a poor one. ”
62
However, the vast majority, including GVPs Harry Greene from BC and Kealey
Cummings, and RVPs Robert Bradshaw, Clarence Dungey,
C. Renwick, Les Hewson, Maurice Loyer and
George Newell, rejected both t
he arguments and proposals being made,
and offered up alternative
analyses of and solutions for the union ’ s cardinal puerto rico
oblems. However, the most coherent and thorough
response came from GVP Shirley Carr, who emphasized that the union ’ s main challenge was not administrative efficiency, but democra
tic participation and accountability.
first, the majority of the Board rejected the
distinction between administration and policy, and
alternatively recognized the inherently polit
ical nature of implementation.
As Carr put it, “[a]dministrative
practices have a bad habit of becoming ‘ policy ’, and in this direction a policy is developed over which the Board members have no control. ” Decisions about the rent
and distribution of staff, for instance, were deeply
political in that they affected the level of discontent
with the National and its elected officials. The goals
served in choosing and placing staff were not merely technical : as discussed above, they involved choices about whether to concentrate on already existing
members or new members, whether to serve
discontented and powerful locals, or weaker locals wi
th less power but greater need. Appointments could
besides reward loyalty or punish dissent, exclude or
incorporate into the governing structure, depending upon
the situation. As a result, Carr
argued that “Board members must have an
expanded
role to review all
399 63
S. Carr, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman, April 4, 1971: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 2]. Emphasis
added. 64
R.H. Bradshaw, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman, March 31, 1971:
1; M. Loyer, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman, n.d.: 2; G.H.
Newell, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman, April 26, 1971 : 1-2 ; L. Hewson, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman, n.d. : 2. C.N. Re
nwick,
letter to S.Little and G. Hartman, n.d. : 1. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 2 ] policies and administrative practices to see how they di
rectly affect the members that they are close to.”
63
irregular, most Board members reinforced the absol
ute importance of their oversight role, which
was to be preserved even at the monetary value of inefficiency.
This was an essential ingredient in a democratic
constitution as opposed to a hierarchical bodied stru
cture. The NEB was part of the “system of checks
and balances ”, which the National Officers ’ proposals would significantly erode. Loyer, Newell and Bradshaw all argued that what was being suggested watt
ould result in the Executive Officers having
“ arrant and unrestrained control ”, “ the dispatch freedom to do as they please ”, which none of them were prepared to allow. Hewson linked this to the National Officers ’ attitude at Board meetings : he had observed that they tended “ to take personal diss at
questions of points raised by Board members”, which
signalled the National Officers ’ restlessness with thyroxine
he process of oversight and the desire for greater
autonomy. Renwick ’ s feel was thyroxine
hat “the ‘re-hashing’ referred to would be much more desirable than the
‘ rubber-stamping ’ of bad policy. ”
64
The solution was not to empty out the NEB ’ s respons
ibilities, but to provide greater support to NEB
members to carry out their policy-making, policy evaluation, and oversight roles more effectively. These changes would include longer and more frequent Board
meetings, the distribution of meeting agendas and
associated documents in gain, and monthly reports
from the National Officers between meetings.
These changes would allow Board members to prepar
e, investigate, and make more constructive
contributions to debate, remain more informed
about developments outside their region, and develop a
more National expectation over time. As Hewson argued,
these procedural changes would eliminate some of
400 65
S. Carr, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman, April 4, 1971: 5;
E. Phillips, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman March 31, 1971: 2;
L.
Hewson, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman, n.d. : 1. 66
S. Carr, letter to S.Little and G. Hartman April 4, 1971: 1, 2.
67
Ibid., 2.
the problems of duplicate.
65
ultimately, Carr ’ s unique contribution to the debate washington
s to posit that democratic participation and
accountability – not centralization of exponent masquerade as administrative rationalization – were the pressing issues needing solutions. She called Little and Ha
rtman on their lack of attention to the question of
how size had affected the participatory nature of the union. For her, the function of the leadership “ should be to continually democratize our operations with in
creased rank and file control of our decision-making.”
The result of CUPE ’ s dramatic growth was to widen the break between the membership and the “ decision-making machinery ”. This effect could be
particularly felt at Convention, which rank and file
members increasingly viewed as “ a ritual for passi
ng resolutions which are not acted upon completely.”
66
none of the National Officers ’ proposals would do any
thing to increase membership participation, and
indeed would work to reduce the influence of the rank-and-
file’s only representatives at the National level.
Although Carr ’ s thinking about how to sustain
greater participation was underdeveloped, she did
have clear ideas about how to increase the NEB ’ s
accountability to the membership. As the body
responsible for carrying out the Convention ’ s m
andate, the NEB should concentrate on systematically
carrying out, tracking and assessing the implementation of Convention decisions. Each Board meet would have some time spent on discussing progress on those resolutions implemented and those outstanding, and the membership would receive
a full accounting of what had been done with the
convention bid.
67
however, this procedure was not separate of thymine
he ‘consensus’ which emerged out of the NEB’s
discussion of the National Officers ’ proposals. Nor was it
the majority opinion that the NEB’s role should be
strengthened. rather, it was agreed
that the NEC should assume more responsibility for administration
401 68
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, June 26-27, 1971: 1. CU
PE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 3] This
consensus departs importantly from the opinions expressed in wr
iting by Board members, but gi
ven the minutes policy, there is no record of how this solution was reached. 69
CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 22.
70
G. Hartman, “Report on CUPE National Conventions”, April 5, 1972. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 6]
71
CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 27.
and policy exploitation, to then be considered by the NEB. As well, the NEB would alone be creditworthy for rent of National Department Heads and Regional Direct
ors, while all staff below this rank would be
chosen by the NEC. finally, the NEB would receiv
e meeting materials in advance “whenever possible.”
68
Nor was much action taken on other aspects of
Carr’s critique. Other comments by the National
Officers about the shock of size on the union give a s
ense of how questions of participation were sidelined.
For Little, the greater distance between leaders and mem
bers was not so much a political problem; rather,
it “ affects us in a nostalgic sort of way … We [ lambert
eaders] don’t’ get the opportunity we used to have to spend
time with and fraternize with the versatile
local unions and the various area meetings.”
69
In other words, Little
worried more about no longer being able to mix with
his followers and feel some organic connection to
them than about whether members woul
d be able to represent their interests effectively in the union’s
structures. As such, the alienation between leaders and members was something to get used to in the avail of running a big, professionalize organization. Hartman ’ s take on the impact of the union ’ s size
focussed primarily on the technical aspects of
plan and carrying off a convention, which was depart of her responsibilities.
70
Convention planning was
becoming a constant affair, and the megabyte
eeting itself was more difficult to
manage. More locals meant more
resolutions, and more delegates meant more debate.
As a result, it was becoming impossible for the
conventionality to process all of the issues sent to it
by the membership; large numbers of resolutions were
being referred to the incoming NEB and, as a question
at the 1971 Convention revealed, the practice was
not to inform the delegates of the
outcomes of the Board’s decisions.
71
Indeed, 81 resolutions had been
referred to the Board at the close up of the 1971 C
onvention. Hartman’s solutions were primarily
402 72
G. Hartman, “Report on CUPE Na
tional Conventions”, 3, 4.
73
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, May 12-14, 1972: 9.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 8]
74
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 63.
administrative, designed to make conventionality more vitamin e
fficient: conventions would be lengthened to five days,
conventionality committees could arrive three days befor
e to be able to combine or rewrite overlapping
resolutions, and the count of outside south
peakers would be reduced to one per day.
72
Sensible proposals
all, and approved by the Board,
73
yet they would only support the Convention’s democratic deliberations
indirectly, and would not very ensure that full and sulfur
ubstantial debate would still take place in a Convention
which was nearing the 1000-delegate mark. If anything, and despite Carr ’ s arguments, the N
EB’s Convention practices were moving in the
opposite guidance, with increasing reliance on policy
statements. This evolution can be traced to the
experience at the 1969 Convent
ion, in the debate over
Action 69-71
. Here, the leadership opted to hold a
two-hour Committee of the Whole discussion with about 700 delegates, with the finish of everyone having their read. deoxyadenosine monophosphate well, when pressed by Ron Monkman
of Local 79, who insisted the delegates should be able
to “ choice answers, rectify and change ”, Little agreed that this
“not a case of ‘take it or leave it’ … It so
happens the NEB has a heck of a lot of agency bet
ween the time you leave here and you get back here
adjacent couple of years from now. But today, this is your day, and we can not force anything. ”
74
The result
was in fact a debate that stretched over several
days, and which resulted in certain elements of
Action 69-
71
being removed, at least informally, by the delegates.
true, the process was difficult and chaot
ic, since managing the particular interests and
concerns of that many people is inherently challenging.
However, rather than continue to experiment with
and refine participatory procedures, the leadership ’ s long-te
rm response was to increase their use of policy
statements and NEB stead papers to streamline and frame debates, which were to be adopted as hale or not. This commit was pitched in terms of effi
ciency, and was a way to cope with the negative impact of
403 75
Ibid., 149.
size on the delegates ’ capacity to deliberate effect
ively. However, the result was to manage and shape
debate in particular ways, and to restrict the options
open to delegates. The membership thus increasingly
found itself responding to leadership plans and six
sions, rather than articulating and organizing around
alternatives they defined themselves. furthermore,
the union did not produce any kinds of mediating
structures that might serve to enhance and organize membership input. V.
Financing Militancy: Strike Waves, Fi
ght Backs, and the National Defence Fund
Of course, with local autonomy still intact, mem
bers still had control over the ultimate form of
participation in the behave of the union, namely colle
ctive bargaining and strike action. Indeed, in the
years following the amalgamation, CUPE members, like
their fellow workers in Canada and around the world,
made heavy use of the strike weapon and other forms of combativeness. Unlike early, more established unions, however, CUPE continued to struggle with its fiscal health, and in particular with ensuring the National Defence Fund had sufficient assets. Although no-one
could have anticipated the scale of workplace
conflict between 1972 and 1974, it was comfortable to see CUPE ’ s continue inability to marshal enough resources for the center would make it unmanageable field-grade officer
r the union to sustain militancy of its members. The
contradictions of local autonomy were peculiarly ex-wife
pressed in the disjuncture between local control over
collective bargain and cardinal responsibility for financing strikes. After the 1969 Convention, the NDF was degree fahrenheit
unded by 20 cents per member per month.
75
While this
was an improvement over the Fund ’ s
initial per capita of 10 cents per month, it was unquestionably low,
particularly for such a boastfully union. As well, in order
to smooth the creation of the Fund, much more than
strike benefits was paid for out of the NDF : legal aid,
particularly for locals without the right to strike,
pre-strike preparations, and the cost of advertise
campaigns for strike aversion and support all came out
404 76
CUPE, 1971 Convention
Proceedings: 65, 115-16.
77
Ibid., 66; G. Hartman, “Financial Report to the National Exec
utive Board on the National Def
ense Fund”, September 1972: 1-2.
CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 8 ] ; G. Hartman, National Secretar
y-Treasurer’s Report, CUPE, 1973
convention Reports : 4. CUPE Fonds [ NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 10, File 5]
78
CUPE, National Executive Committee minutes, October 14, 1972: 4.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 10]
79
CUPE, National Executive Committee minutes, June 16-17, 1973: 3.CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 13]
80
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, Oc
tober 15-16, 1972: 9-10. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 10]
of the Fund. Given how difficult it was to extract
the last increase in 1969, the National leadership did not
seek to raise per head in 1971. In any shell, thyroxine
he Fund was, in Hartman’s terms, “the healthiest part of
[ CUPE ’ sulfur ] fiscal operation ” in 1971 ; with closely $ 650,
000, there seemed, at least to the leadership, no
motivation to increase the money flowing into the NDF. A resolution from Kitimat Local 707 to double the NDF ’ s per caput to 40 cents was defeated at this Convention.
76
A mere class late, the National Executive must
have regretted the defeat of this proposal, for the
Defence Fund was in utter crisis. The hit roll which had begun in 1971 only grew in the follow two years. Whereas in 1971, CUPE paid out $ 124,000 in benef
its and other costs, by mid-1972, disbursements
had increased tenfold. While in the former class 31
locals had come close to or went on strike, these
were broadly little locals. In 1972, Locals 43, 301, 1000, 1500 and 2000 all went on hit, with the Ontario Hydro workers alone out for five months in a peculiarly acerb conflict. Hartman ’ s fiscal report to the NEB in September was desperate : the Fund had income
of $430,000, but disbursem
ents of over $1 million.
The union had had to borrow $ 500,000 from creditors and its own locals, and evening so did not have enough to pay the benefits still owed to several locals.
77
A call also went out for voluntary contributions to the Fund,
but this was not peculiarly successful
: less than $20,000 was netted from locals.
78
In September 1972, the NEC took the drastic pace of establishing a moratorium on the use of the NDF until all debts were paid and its poise reached $ 150,000.
79
Endorsed by NEB in January 1973, the
consensus was that the “ National Officers would hav
e to be given authority to place more rigid conditions
regarding requital of benefits in future. ”
80
The Board, at Carr’s initiative, also put in place a $5.00
405 81
G. Hartman, National Secretary-Treasur
er’s Report, CUPE, 1973 Convention Reports: 4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol. 10, File 5 ] 82
S. Little, National President’s Report, CU
PE, 1973 Convention Reports: 13. CUPE Fonds [N
AC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File
26 ] 83
G. Hartman, National Secretary-Treasur
er’s Report, CUPE, 1973 Convention Reports: 4. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234,
Vol. 10, File 5 ] 84
Crean, 143.
85
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
October 15-16, 1972: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 10]
mandate appraisal, to be paid over a 5-month peri
od; those who had already given voluntarily would
have a credit against their compulsory obligations. however, “ compulsory ” is a provocative term in
CUPE, and tended to provoke resistance. Arrears
were soon at an all-time high, with over $ 662,
000 in dues receivable by the end of 1972, and $820,000 by
end of 1973.
81
Only $300,000 of a potential $800,000 from the mandatory assessment was received.
82
As
well, the steps the union had taken to relieve the public relations
essure on striking locals, by granting per capita
dispensations totalling more than $ 100,000, were contri
buting to the negative cash flow. In other words,
the NDF crisis created fiscal problems in the union ’ s general operating budget adenine well.
83
Even with
emergency measures, it took about two years for
the moratorium to eliminate the deficit, and was
maintained until the 1975 Convention.
84
The NDF crisis revealed that local autonomy coul
d produce disastrous results on a collective scale
and besides the limited the National Office ’ second tools to di
scipline members. The National Officers and Board
members all called for an “ in-depth report ” of the motion
of authority in strikes. There were of course
administrative dimensions to the trouble, and the NEC
was to study and report on the use of the Fund, “as
well as to what degree local unions utilize the servic
es available from National Office before proceeding to
take mint legal action. ”
85
No doubt better coordination of national and
local activities would have allowed for
better plan of the Fund. however, Little argued triiodothyronine
hat the key question was more philosophical: CUPE
needed to engage in some soul-searching and even “
have a fundamental discussion of our traditional
406 86
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the National Executive Board, October 15-16, 1972: 1. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28,
I234, Vol. 15, File 9 ] 87
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
June 22-23, 1973: 6-7. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 14]
concept of local autonomy. ”
86
As long as a disjuncture existed between the control over calling strikes and
duty for administering money, the likely for
each local to make rational individual choices that
created irrational collective results remained. The
self-reinforcing cycle of autonomy was again at work:
immunity to per caput increases had led to underf
unding of the NDF, and when the central resource was
no longer available, locals protested by keeping electron volt
en more of their dues at home, widening the problem
and making it even more difficult to resolve. An extreme adaptation of the autonomist logi
c was again represented by Local 1000’s behaviour
during the NDF moratorium. local 1000 was one of a significant numeral of traditionally autonomist locals on hit in this period ; while they had initially resisted the initiation of the
NDF and participated in holding
devour per head levels more generally, local anesthetic 1000 was diamond about receiving what was owed them in strike benefits and legal costs. In 1973, the loca
l was in arrears for $95,000 and was holding back the
money until their claim for $ 700,000 from the NDF was
honoured, as this was the amount that would have
been paid to them had the moratorium not been in seat.
Moreover, the local was signalling that it wouldn’t
go along with the per head increase for 1973 that the NEB was preparing in their new proposal,
Decade
2
.
87
While their protracted strike no doubt placed Local
1000 under severe financial pressure, their strategy
to insist on their ‘ cut ’ of the Defence Fund while all
other locals were foregoing access to it represents the
zenith of autonomist particularism. When breed acro
ss many locals, one sees clearly the price of local
autonomy. VI.
New Members, New Structures, New Identities:
Rethinking the Balance Between Local and Centre
Growth besides raised the interrogate of whether new groups would be well served by the union ’ s
407 88
White, 73-85, 100-107; Deverell, 1982.
decentralized dicker structures and custom of radical local autonomy. Conditions prevailing in those areas being organized after the fusion departed signific
antly from those in CUPE’s traditional sectors; as
such, more centralize forms of collective bargaini
ng would have to be contemplated and supported by the
union ’ mho social organization. however, the petty officer
litical implications of such changes, both for the National leadership as
well as the members within and outside of the new stru
ctures, created a series of obstacles that delayed
the kind of structural initiation CUPE members in
creasingly needed to make progress in their relations
with management. The amalgamation had not equipped the union
with the means to cope with changing employer
structures or practices, making it closely impossible
to overcome the centrifugal pressures of autonomy and
make the structural changes it seemed many agreed were necessity, even when these issues were explicitly on the board. While CUPE finally did create some types of hundred
entral bargaining, these took an inordinately long
time to establish and make effective, even where a majority of members involved desired more centralization. In some cases, as in the occupat
ionally-based Broadcast Division, the experience was very
baffling as a minority resolutely clung to their
‘right’ to local autonomy and blocked the development of
an effective sectoral organization. In others, like
the Ontario hospital sector, the gap between the formally
decentralized structures of contro
l and representation and the increasingly centralized bargaining practices
controlled by regional staff preferably than elect
ed leaders led to major dissatisfaction amongst the
membership, leading to an illegal province-wide strike
in 1981 that was as much against the National union
as hospital employers.
88
Where such structures were implem
ented quickly, it usually occurred as a
reaction to employer or department of state initiatives preferably
than as part of a coherent plan to enhance bargaining power
and coordination. In other words, by failing to arti
culate the means by which more centralized bargaining
structures would be created, the union by default relied
upon employer restructuring to provoke the internal
408 89
A. Bolduc, “The History of Electricity in Quebec,”
Hydro Quebec website
, online at http://www.hydroquebec.com/learning/
history/index.html ( viewed January 25, 2005 ). structural changes it was unable to make on its own.
Finally, the majority of locals continued in their
individual dicker relationships, even where empl
oyer coordination was growing and making it less
possible to play them off against each other. The absence of these intercede structures left untouched the material experiences that reinforced commitm
ents to local autonomy, even by new members with
different identities and interest
s in broader-based bargaining.
provincial governments were key in creati
ng the more centralized employers and bargaining
structures increasingly faced by many CUPE mem
bers. During the 1960s, provinces engaged in a wave of
centralization in a server of sectors. Governments were
of course motivated by the greater efficiency that
consolidation could provide, but the main thread
tying these initiatives together was the promise of
equalizing the choice of and access to what were in
creasingly considered essential public services.
The earliest case of such centralization had been the nationalization of Hydro Quebec by the Lesage government beginning in 1962, part of the Quie
t Revolution to modernize and secularize Quebec
society. In a manner of speaking in February 1962, then Mini
ster of Natural Resources Réné Lévèsque scathingly
criticized the irrationalities, thriftlessness, and soci
al and regional inequities inherent in the fragmented and
private delivery of electricity in Quebec and announced t
he government’s intent to nationalize the sector.
The controversial program – particularly for privat
e electricity providers – provoked a general election on
the offspring. Lesage won, and proceeded to merge 80
companies into Hydro Quebec, standardizing rates
and ensuring consistent access and quality across the province.
89
Another major centralize project took stead
in New Brunswick under the Liberal government of
Louis Robichaud, who sought to eradicate extreme rural
poverty, which continued to prevail in the province
well into the post-war boom, and to take over those public
services that the municipalities simply could no
farseeing administer. The Byrne Royal Commission, es
tablished in 1965, called for a massive reorganization
409 90
Byrne Commission
, Report of the Royal Commission on Finance
and Municipal Taxation in New Brunswick
. E.Byrne, chair.
Fredericton, NB, 1964, on-line at hypertext transfer protocol : //www.lib.unb.ca/T
exts/NBHistory/Commissions/
ES81E/byrne_1E.html; Canadian
Broadcasting Corporation. “ The ‘Other Re
volution’: Louis Robichaud’s New Brunswick.”
CBC Archives
, online at
hypertext transfer protocol : //archives.cbc.ca/IDD-1-73-519/ politics_economy/
robichaud (viewed Februar
y 1, 2005); MacMillan, 140.
91
Ontario Task Force on School Board Reductions
, Final Report
. Toronto, ON: Publications Ontario, 1996. 15.
of public services, with the goal of providing a minimal standard of service for all. The Commission ’ s recommendations generated over 130 pieces of legislation, twelve of which were key in establishing provincial responsibility and presidency over schools,
hospitals, social welfare, courts and corrections.
part of this march involved a major decrease in the number of school boards to 38, and the institution of province-wide bargain in all newly provincialized sect
ors. These changes were seen as so radical as to
be deemed “ the other Revolution. ”
90
A similar but more demarcate program of rati
onalizing school administration had also taken place
in Ontario in 1968. Minister of Education William
Davis moved to reduce the number of school boards from
1446 to 168, with the goal of creating “ educational
jurisdictions capable of extending equal educational
opportunities to the boys and girls of Ontario. ”
91
Similar moves were made at the municipal level, as cities
like Port Arthur and Fort William merged to form
Thunder Bay, and Winnipeg expanded by taking in the
small communities that surrounded it. In all these in
itiatives, efficiency and rationalization were connected
to a relatively progressive social united states virgin islands
sion of redistribution and egalitarianism.
These kinds of transformations produced thr
ee important trends that had an impact on CUPE’s
inner administration. First, the amalgamation of samarium
all employers into one larger employer resulted in
analogous amalgamations of locals into one local,
typically in municipalities and school boards. The
implications of this type of centralization were lea
t disruptive to the CUPE structure and culture, as they
frequently retained the single-employer, single dicker
unit model. In other words, even though the merger
of once autonomous locals would be contentious
and might touch off internal power struggles, the new
structures were still consistent with the union ’ s
local autonomy culture, and per
haps created more entities
which fit the mold of the typical bombastic autonomist local .
410 A irregular character of centralization created large employment
ers with multiple establishments, often across
large geographic distances. Key examples here were
the three province-wide bargaining units created in
the awaken of Hydro Quebec ’ mho nationalization, a well
as the establishment of two national bargaining units
within the CBC. These employer structures required significant amounts of coordination, for local bargaining would plainly be ineffective for worker
s, as the employer’s central human resources
departments could easily play the diverse locals agai
nst each other. These bargaining units tended to be
modelled in separate on the kind of structures set up by local 1000. A third form of centralization enta
iled the creation of sectoral bargai
ning structures at the provincial
level, in which associations of multiple employer
s and councils of unions would face each other at the
dicker postpone. This typify changes in the hospital
sector, where provincial hospital associations were
increasingly engaging in coordination and informal, if not
legally formalized, sectoral bargaining. Legally
constituted sectoral tables were of course separate of
the New Brunswick initiatives, and made it necessary for
CUPE ’ s New Brunswick Division to create field-grade officer
rmal multi-local bargaining structures.
The latter two innovations had more serious implicat
ions for the traditional organization of collective
bargaining and power within CUPE. First, the creati
on of larger, geographically dispersed bargaining units
could multiply those who might adopt and pursue the sa
me autonomist logic as that of Ontario Hydro.
second, the initiation of sectoral organizations brought together autonomous locals, which immediately had to enter in coordinating structures that would have
some binding force on them, to alter their notions of
autonomy, solidarity and identity, and to
rethink the groups to which one had a legitimate duty to submit. In
other words, state transformations meant revisiting thyroxine
he decision not to create occupational structures and to
leave local autonomy unhindered at the time of the thousand
ger. However, it was not a given that the union
would be able to make the kind of morphologic and
cultural changes increasingly needed by the membership
to cope with their collective dicker environment .
411 92
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 6-7, 1965: 7.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 4]
93
CUPE, 1965 Convention Proceedings: 39.
94
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 12, 1967: 19.
CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 1]
95
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes,
October 22-23, 1966: 6. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 12, File 12]
There was a growing recognition at both the Nati
onal leadership level and amongst sections of the
membership of the need and sex appeal for such struct
ures from the merger on. However, leadership
decisions were not always coherent with supporting the
kinds of structures that were actually necessary.
In the 1965 NEB debate on
Setting a Course
, Bill Black, informed by his experiences with provincial
hospital dicker in BC, had criticized the failure to
provide for broader-based structures, as “provincial
bargaining … was likely to become the average in the future.
92
As a result, the NEB submitted a constitutional
amendment to the 1965 Convention giving themselves the baron to create occupationally-based service divisions. however, the provisions in the amendment tied the NEB to a especial kind of structure, which would be national in oscilloscope. indeed, the textbook specifi
ed that “[not] more than one service division shall be
established for any classification of service. ”
93
As such, occupational groups could only form at the national
level, which would be irrelevant for most of CU
PE’s members who were facing provincial forms of
centralization and continued to be covered by provincial
labour laws. The NEB’s structural innovations thus
did not alter things for the majority of the membership. similarly out of synchronize with developments was the
NEB’s attempt to establish a National Hospital
coordinator in 1967 to take charge of thyroxine
he urgent project of organizing hospitals.
94
This was in response to
Rintoul ’ s October 1966 recommendation that the union sulfur
hould create a hospital service division, as the
identical spotty and chaotic organize in the legal power besides
called for a more effective form of coordination.
95
however, the NEB had jumped the gunman without cons
idering what made the most sense. Black
subsequently surveyed Regional Directors to assess whether such a position would address the interests of hospital workers. He concluded that, given the public relations
ovincial nature of hospital administration, what was
needed was not a national but respective peasant hospita
ls coordinators, as national coordination would
412 96
B. Black, “Interim Report re: the Appoi
ntment of a National Hospital Division
Coordinator”, September 1967: 10. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 4 ] ; CUPE, National Ex
ecutive Board minutes, September 30 – October 1, 1967: 1. CUPE
Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 5 ] 97
Committee for Stanley Little, “Think Big,
Vote Little”, pamphlet, 1967. CUPE Fonds [NAC
Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 46, File 11]
never be effective without better carbon
ooperation at the provincial level.
96
At this point, given CUPE’s financial
limits, ten new staff positions were not in the card
s; the National Coordinator’s posting was withdrawn and
‘ replaced ’ by beefing up hospital sector activities
of the Research Department. As well, even though
Black ’ south report implied that provincial-level hospital di
visions or unions were actually required, there was no
constituent provision for such entities. Despite
their instinct that broader structures were needed, the
leadership was unable to sort out how to support them both constitutionally and financially. Although Little ’ s preference for more centraliz
ed structures has been demonstrated, he too was
ambivalent about actually bringing sectoral organizations into being. In his 1967 election speeches, he was putting out the estimate that the coupling should be work
ing towards “area and regional collective bargaining
while maintaining local autonomy ” in an try to
“eliminate regional inequities” and counter the “divide
and conquer ” strategies of management.
97
However, in practice, Little tended to be open only to
centralizing processes under his manipulate. This is parti
cularly evident in his dealings with membership acting
to create broader structures. These membership pressures for structures
to support central bargaining and coordination were
peculiarly apparent amongst Ontario hospital workers,
especially as a method of increasing their otherwise
limit dicker power. Leadership inaction on the
issue forced local leaders to take the lead
themselves, and delegates to the Ontario Hospitals
Conference in 1968 voted to establish a Hospital
council, with a five-cent per caput and an elected antique
ecutive. Rather than finding some way to support this
enterprise, Little opted to quash the new body rather.
He argued that “the formation of this Council raises
problems which go room spinal column to the amalgamation talks.
At that time it was agreed reluctantly by NUPSE to
forego the national industrial division structure which t
hey had, in favour of a geographical structure. It is
413 98
S. Little, National President’s Report to
the National Executive Board to the NEB,
July 6-7, 1968: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc.
MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 9 ] 99
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, July 6-7, 1968: 5. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 12]
100
CUPE, 1969 Convention Proceedings: 19.
101
CUPE, National Executive Board, “Draft Policy Statement
re: Widening the Geographic Sc
ope of Bargaining”, September
1973. CUPE Fonds [ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 14 ] not potential to have the two running side by
side without a great deal of duplication.”
98
On Little’s
recommendation, the NEB decided that the Hospital
Council was unconstitutional, and would have to be
established as part of the Ontario Division structure.
99
As such, when Lakehead District Council’s resolution
calling for the establishment of peasant engage st
ructures through provincial collective bargaining in
hospitals and homes for the aged carried with no debate
at the 1969 Convention, there was no structure
through which this could be carried out.
100
clearly, important barriers existed at both fifty
eadership and membership level which ensured the
NEB ’ south policy would not be implemented. evening deoxythymidine monophosphate
hough the National leadership, particularly Little,
understood the sex appeal of more c
entralized bargaining structures, they failed to put in place any
concrete procedures that would bring such structures
into being. Indicative of this was the NEB’s 1973
policy on regionalizing bargaining.
101
This policy showed that the NEB’s clear analysis of the reasons why
broader-based dicker was needed was not backed up by ei
ther the means or the will to bring it into
universe. Strategic, solidaristic and organizational reasons were given for this denotative policy change. Fragmented, decentralized and uncoordi
nated bargaining in the public se
ctor not only meant too many
strikes, harming the union ’ s populace effigy, it besides di
d not necessarily produce the kinds of gains desired
given employer consolidation processes discussed
above. As public sector employers enhanced their own
coordination, playing them off against each other
was no longer a viable strategy. Regional bargaining
would besides serve to reduce inequalities amongst CUPE ’
s membership, along with the mutual resentment
that such inequities fostered. organizationally
, the union would benefit from reducing the number of
collective agreements to be negotiated,
thereby freeing up staff time for other pressing matters like
414 102
Ibid., 4-5.
organizing or education. however, the NEB recognized how dislocate such changes would be for CUPE locals accustomed to autonomy. These implications were “ ser
ious”, and in effect constituted the main barriers to
implementing the policy. The NEB pointed to that
broader-based bargaining would mean that locals would
have to cooperate in establishing the bargaining goals and in agreeing on tacti
cs in pursuit of them. It also means that locals
will have to make commitments concerning village in
the interests of the larger group even when a
detail local might be dissatisfied. It calls for
a spirit of compromise and a willingness to understand your
boyfriend worker ’ s item of watch and praseodymium
oblems. It means, in a real and not
theoretical or constitutional sense,
that local autonomy may have to be reduced to some degree. It may besides mean that, for a time, locals who have managed to win leading positions in terms of wages
and conditions may have to mark time while those
at the buttocks are brought up to higher levels th
rough the process of wideni
ng the scope of bargaining.
102
Given the major transformation that such a process woul
d require, it is not surprising that the NEB’s policy
statement contained no discussion of how broader-based
structures might work in terms of decision-
making summons, nor was there any plan to implement the recommendations. This inaction was not alone due to the major opposition that would be encountered from locals ; it was rooted in concerns about the actual implications
of such changes for internal power relations. First,
little and the NEB continued to be concerned about how
the establishment of large occupational groups
might introduce more brawny centrifugal forces into
the union. With the disaffiliation of Local 180 and its
solid membership inactive in recent memory, there wa
s a fear that large chunks of the membership could
disaffiliate in one fell pounce if they became discontented. not alone would the mean a significant loss of membership and money, it would besides introduce an well-organized rival in CUPE ’ south legal power. Nor did the CUPE leadership trust that the CLC would help in
such circumstances, particularly given the latter’s
openness to the target affiliation of provincial civil
servants despite their formal inclusion in CUPE’s
jurisdiction. last, the leadership was besides c
oncerned about creating groups with which special deals
would have to be negotiated. such fears could be
seen in Little’s deep ambivalence about the provincial
415 103
S. Little, National President’s Report, CU
PE, 1973 Convention Reports: 13. CUPE Fonds [N
AC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File
26 ] unions, which were both necessary if peasant civil servants were even to join CUPE and a thorn in his side in that they introduced a constant floor of friction and resentment into the union. As a solution, the leadership did not operationalize their courtly conscientious objector
mmitment to more centralized forms of bargaining.
At the membership level, there were objec
tions from members both outside and inside the new
structures. As we have seen, the creation of newfangled
or different structures has always caused political
problems within CUPE, due to very or think differentia
ls in levels of servicing. Given that Locals 1000
and 180 formed the main prototypes for the kind of
structures the union might have to adopt, indications
were that autonomist locals would not well accomm
odate more such groups. New structures would
potentially worsen resentment amongst locals who
would see these entities as relatively privileged in
the union, depending upon their constitution and fund
arrangements with the National. Therefore,
significant elements in the union would always be resentful and act as a barrier to the changes needed to create and sustain broader bargain stru
ctures that, by necessity, would diminish local autonomy to some
degree. As well, resistance emerged from locals who
found themselves within sectoral bargaining
structures but did not want to relinquish any of their
local autonomy. In such instances, it was possible for a
little minority to impede the initiation
of effective broader-based structures desired by the majority in the
sector. A peculiarly extreme point case of this dynam
ic was the conflict between CBC Montreal Local 660 and
the newly-created National Broadcast Division. At deoxythymidine monophosphate
he 1973 Convention, Little characterized the conflict as
“ the ultimate experience of this valid concept
[of local autonomy] being degraded and used in a political
struggle ”, and “ a moral in how … in the name of trade unionism and autonomy, to ignore the members ’ interests. ”
103
As the product of a merger of two entities wi
th different traditions, the Broadcast Division was
itself was a microcosm of the coupling ’ s general
dynamics and demonstrated the enduring difficulties of
416 104
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, March 2-3, 1968. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 13, File 9]
105
F. Eady, “Report to the National Officers on the Current Sit
uation in the Radio-TV Divisi
on”, November 17, 1969. CUPE Fonds
[ NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 14, File 7 ] creating new structures out of preexistent ones. The introduction of closely 4000 new CBC members in 1969,
all working for the same employer but spread
across the entire state, raised the winder struct
ural question of how they would cooperate and be
represented in collective bargain. Anticipating thymine
he need for an appropriate structure to cope with the
CBC management, in March 1968 the NEB empowered the Na
tional Officers to negotiate the creation of a
National Broadcast Division which would conduct centrum
l bargaining for each of the two main sections of
CBC employees.
104
Francis Eady was given practical responsibilit
y for these talks. Strangely, given their
late experiences with merging two disparate entit
ies, no-one anticipated the ex
tent of the difficulties
involved in merging the two CBC units into one Divisi
on. The root of the problem lay in the different
traditions of the two groups. ARTEC, immediately CU
PE Locals 670 to 682, had long had their own national
structure, was accustomed to centralization, and was ve
ry much pushing for the creation of a Division. The
television receiver production unit, nowadays Locals 660 to 668, did not
have any previous coordination, had been directly
organized into CUPE on a local-by-local footing, and were
therefore relatively more attached to the notion of
local autonomy.
105
The main defender of local anesthetic autonomy against the cons
olidation of collective bargaining rights in the
hands of the Broadcast Division was Montreal Local 660, led by Gilles Lortie. He challenged the constitutional basis for the constitution of the Division,
citing that the NEB had only given the National Officers
leave to negotiate the issue with ARTEC, not with
production employees (which, formally speaking, was
true ). Using appeals to the Convention and the NEB angstrom well as court injunctions, local anesthetic 660 attempted to block the Broadcast Division ’ s ability to jointly bar
gain and to set dues levels for its affiliated locals.
The courts threw out these challenges and the NEB rea
ffirmed by fiat the constitutionality of the Broadcast
417 106
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, De
cember 10, 1971: 12. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 7];
CUPE, National Executive Board minutes, Oc
tober 1972. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 10]; S. Little,
National President ’ s Report to t
he National Executive Board, April 1973: 3. CUPE F
onds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 15, File 11]
107
S.Little, National President’s
Report, CUPE, 1975 Convention Reports
: 7. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 10, File
10 ] 108
Locals 667 and 677, “Joint Submission to the Hewson Commission
Hearings”, Toronto, May 10, 1977. CUPE Fonds [NAC Acc.
MG 28, I234, Vol. 183, File 13 ] Division.
106
However, while Local 660’s appeals fell on deaf ear
s, its attachment to local autonomy was not
eliminated by will and the Broadcast Division remained riven by discord. The NEC had to initiate an inquiry into the Broadcast Division ’ s fiscal and inte
rnal difficulties. Triggered by applications for
decertification by Locals 660 and 675 in 1975, the Board
voted to place the Division under administration,
which was to final the adjacent four years.
107
While Local 660 ‘s resistor to the creation of triiodothyronine
he Broadcast Division can be interpreted simply as
selfish short-sightedness ( which Little did ), there were other indications of deep design flaws in the structure itself. While local 660 ‘s non-participati
on did undermine the Division’s finances, cohesion, and
the success of Production Unit negotiations, there were
also problems with the degree of centralization and
the nature of representation.
The two Toronto Locals 667 and 677 complained of cultural disparities
between Quebec and rest of Canada, an imbalance in representation at the Division Executive, with production members outnumbered by professi
onals, financial mismanagement and top-heavy
administration, and excessive centralization of prisoner of war
er in Montreal, where the Division and “two most
knock-down locals in Canada ” shared an office. While
these locals were not arguing for the abandonment of
central dicker wholly ( they wanted to see f
our bargaining units, a French and English unit in each
occupational group ), they did hi
ghlight the fact that the
form
of centralization could have serious negative
consequences.
108
In many respects, even though the Broadcast Division represented the kind of
organization that was increasingly needed to cope with
new employer structures, there was a delicate
symmetry to be struck between central coor
dination, representation of diverse
interests, and local control. It
was discernible that Little, with his preference for effective, top-down control, was not sufficiently sensitive to
418 109
CUPE, 1971 Convention Proceedings: 22.
110
Ibid., 6.
the representational questions raised by more central st
ructures. For him, the main challenge of regional
or sectoral bargain was for CUPE “ to bring into the organization a set of expertness ”,
109
not to set up clear
mechanisms to ensure membership in
volvement in broader structures.
These pressures for and against morphologic change were linked in crucial ways to the newly identities being introduced into the union over its foremost
ten years. As CUPE took in workers who were not
part of its traditional constituency of municipal
and civic workers, school board custodians and hospital
orderlies, and utility workers, it faced the interrogate of fair how they would be integrated. In some respects, the implications of the large num
bers and diversity of the new member
s were potentially positive. With
every new member added to CUPE, the symmetry of people with allegiances to one or the other of the founding unions and their respective factions would shrink. By 1973, over 100,000 people had joined CUPE since the amalgamation, and so about 60 % of the me
mbership had no historical ties or commitments to
either NUPE or NUPSE. As little remarked in his address to the 1971 Convention, there appeared to be “ a new, more serious climate among our older mem
bers and an understandable desire on the part of new
members to consider the past as largely irre
levant to the union that has emerged as a unique
administration. ”
110
In this sense, growth provided the possibility that a specific collective identity centred
around CUPE could be fostered and could challenge
the older identities based on the pre-merger
organizations. however, diaphanous size and the enactment of time would never be enough to amply eliminate particularisms, particularly because the marriage ’ s structur
e reinforced identification with local identities,
whatever they may have been. Most long-standing lo
cal leaders may have put aside their bitterness and
grudges, but both they and those that
succeeded them still clung to local identities. Moreover, bringing in
new people with no memory of the union ’ s factional hawaii
story was really beside the point, as the central
419 111
S. Little, National President’s Report, CU
PE, 1973 Convention Reports: 12. CUPE Fonds [N
AC Acc. MG 28, I234, Vol. 9, File
26 ] dynamic was not these disputes per selenium, but ra
ther the ongoing tension between centralization and
entrenched local identities and the desire for contro
l that accompanied them. While National leaders
fantasized about greater central c
ontrol, the union’s structure and
functioning gave new members the
know of the autonomous local union, in charge of its own dues, corporate dicker and strikes, and the extent of their commitment to and engagement
in the rest of CUPE and the Canadian labour movement.
even those locals with predilections for and intere
sts in greater coordinat
ion had substantial autonomous
control as their daily world. Autonomy was someth
ing perhaps initially fright
ening, then tolerated, then embraced as individuals become invested in control ov
er these structures. In the absence of already-
existing sectoral or coordinating organizations with
a modicum of power and responsibility, new members
and locals were socialized and fit themselves into
the union’s mainstream, even if such arrangements did
not completely serve their material interests. As a result, ten years after the amalgamation, delegat
es were still being lectured by Little about the
problems with their narrow understanding of their opportunism. At the 1973 Convention, he made an impassioned and unusually philosophical supplication for locals to take a broader opinion of their solidarities. A union must involve sharing. There must be recognition of social responsibilities and of the fact that a public employee in a more privilege position
(such as a prosperous city) has interests which are affected by, for
exemplar, wages and working conditions
of public employees in more di
stant and / or less golden areas. A union is not a business ; a coupling must inactive, in our
eyes, be a social and political movement with certain
ideals of generosity. CUPE can nev
er operate on a strict ‘profit and loss’ basis; if we did, we would have
to ask most of our ‘ unprofitable ’ locals to leave.
In short, what we ask is r
enewed dedication to the ideals of
trade unionism and to the rationale that each, in different ways, can and must
help his Brother or Sister in the
trade coupling bowel movement.
111
But how were members expected to develop this expansive identity when their daily experiences reinforced primary designation with their immediate workmate
s in opposition to their immediate employers, and when
the marriage provided few structures where su
ch solidarities would have to be built?
420 VII.
Conclusion: CUPE: Equipped to Face the Future?
By 1975, CUPE had established deeply-set patterns which would continue into the 1980s and 90s, and which would make it unmanageable for the union to
face the major challenges presented to it by ongoing
public sector transformation, feminization of their
membership, growing alienation of members from the
more central levels of decision-making, and the need to engage in militant economic and political struggles. In particular, the self-reinforcing cycle of autonomy w
ould continue to shape how each of these issues were
defined and the options for dealing with them. The tensions between servicing and organizing woul
d only continue to grow as CUPE continued its
expansion. By 1975, it had surpassed the United St
eelworkers of America as Canada’s largest union,
signalling both CUPE ’ s very appeal to public sector
workers and the genuine successes of the Department
of Organization. however, the pressures on staff woul
d only continue to multiply: not only would servicing
demands continue to expand, they would increasingly or
iginate from the smaller and smaller locals being
created as CUPE reached the peripherie
s of its jurisdictions. With the addition of locals bereft of
hearty fiscal or human resources, CUPE staff
reps would find themselves responsible for more
rounds of corporate dicker, more grievanc
es and arbitrations, more collective agreements to
administer. such pressures would far explode with the advent of a major express rape on public sector workers ’ wages in the belated 1970s and early 1980s, not
to mention the threats associated with neoliberal
state restructure in the 1990s. Having never found
a way to sustain union locals without heavy reliance
on central adept service, and never having been able
to sufficiently centralize resources, CUPE would
repeatedly experience major fiscal crises. feminization would besides continue unimpeded as CUPE continued to expand into female-dominated sectors like health care, education, social services
, day care and airlines. Undoubtedly, women members
were influenced heavily by the general milieu of femini
st organizing, and they did place major pressure on
421 CUPE structures to take women ’ second especial needs and
concerns seriously. Formal and informal networks
of support for women would proliferate within CU
PE, particularly after Hartman ascended to the National
presidency in 1975. however, the basic problem articulated in the argue over
The Status of Women in
CUPE
remained: it would always be locals rather than t
he National Office who retained the real power over
whether and how women workers ’ issues would be in
tegrated and fought for in the collective bargaining
march. While the National could create a more
supportive ideological context for women, and provide
those struggling at the local degree with information and
resources to do so, it could not intervene directly in
male-dominated locals which failed to prioritize triiodothyronine
he interests of women members. Local autonomy would
frankincense mean that a major gap between progressive poli
cy statements, particularly on broader social reform
issues, and implementation at the local charge would re
main. In that sense, local autonomy constituted a
barrier to the progress of union feminist movement in CUPE. majority rule as such, whether conceived as leadership accountability or direct membership engagement, would rarely be discussed in CUPE in
any way that departed from the script of local
autonomy. The problem of CUPE ’ s size would always
be examined as an administrative-structural rather
than political-democratic issue. flush when CUPE woul
d later self-consciously examine its own structures
and attempt to redesign them, the primary finish was
effectiveness rather than democratization, and even
then, fundamental alterations in the basis terms of lo
cal autonomy were not in the offing. While increased
effectiveness was decidedly crucial, particularly gastrointestinal
ven the way that decentralization constituted a
veridical barrier to greater coordinati
on in collective bargaining and political campaigns, the equally vital issue of
how to enhance membership engagement in and control over decision-making at higher levels of the coupling structure was rarely contemplated. Where majority rule
would be raised, the basic assumption of the local
as an inherently democratic outer space in which thymine
he members had their say was never problematized.
last, although a major character of CUPE ’ s membership continued to express both economic and
422 political combativeness, the disjunction of a centrally
controlled fund and decentralized control over bargaining
continued to haunt the union well into the 1970s and beyond. While an increase to the NDF in 1973 finally resolved the fiscal crisis, no geomorphologic changes to the balance between locals and the National were made in the region of fall powers.
It must be recognized that the inability of the national
leadership to use the strike fund as a political tool
does reflect a democratic constraint on central power.
however, the unhampered autonomy of locals to strike
combined with their unwillingness to fund sufficiently
the central levels of the coupling raised questions about whether CUPE ’ mho structure and fiscal infrastructure would be capable of sustaining far-flung combativeness. This question would be increasingly important to answer both in the region of collective bargaining and in the ra
sistance to restrictive legislation that came to
characterize the 1980s and 1990s .
423 decision I.
Understanding CUPE
Charting the circumstances under which CUPE was
formed and consolidated in its first ten years
tells us a great distribute about the dynamics which conti
nue to frame the union’s development, internal debates,
and future possibilities. The union produced by the
1963 merger was deeply marked by the set of political
compromises needed to bring it into universe, and placid
struggles with the self-reinforcing cycle of autonomy
that stymies more effective central coordination,
fails to guarantee democratic membership control, and
blocks the development of classify awareness and effective action on that basis. As we have seen, CUPE was the intersection of a amalgamation between two entities with markedly different approaches to union structure, democracy and drawing card
ship. Even though both unions and their leaders
desired similar things, namely the fusion of populace
sector workers, growth in the numbers of unionized
workers, and development of high levels of professi
onal membership servicing, divisions persisted over
precisely how these goals should be accomplished and by whom. In that feel, the organizational integrity achieved in 1963 was very general, and reflected the influence of potent break up pressures on public sector workers. Our examination of the roots of
public sector unionism shows that while pressures for
centralization existed, emanating variously from
a growing and reorganizing Canadian state, the Canadian
Labour Congress, and from particular types of leaders amongst public sector workers themselves, these were countered by centrifugal forces that reinforced
in many quarters identification with the local group and
union. These loyalties reflected thyroxine
he still-fragmented structure
of the Canadian state, as well as the ever-
increasing occupational and regional diverseness within
union ranks, making it more difficult for CUPE than
many early unions to create a common identity. As a consequence of the doggedness of these local identities – and the political and servicing structures to equal – leaders and members of both parent unions we
re divided over how unification of public sector
424 workers should be achieved, both organizationally and in
terms of consciousness. Both parent unions had
pursued different fusion methods within their ow
n ranks, each with contradictory implications.
however, personal and organizational interests had
coalesced around these a
rrangements, and therefore
the adoption of each in the new union was present
ed as an absolute requirement for merger.
ultimately, refer for union get the better of bot
h the personal ambitions of particular leaders and
the desire to create what other leaders believed was triiodothyronine
he structural basis for a cohesive identity, on the
assumption that such things could be satisfied later. NUPE leaders gave up personal exponent in the phase of the top leadership position, while NUPSE leaders reli
nquished their centralist vision in exchange for the
presidency. While both groups assumed that they
would be able to pursue their agendas within the newly
formed CUPE, the particular combination of strong c
entralist leadership with decentralized structures based
on local autonomy freeze into topographic point a self-reinforci
ng cycle of autonomy which limited the possibilities of
future organizational and cultural change. Decentraliz
ation in whatever form was often treated as a
trouble to be overcome at all costs, and the indigence to balance the legitimate claims of especial interests with those of more cosmopolitan identities was frequently
ignored. However, centralizing moves were always
identified with threats to majority rule understand as loca
l control, even if centralization was premised upon a
broader democratic community, aimed at redistributing
power resources to help the most vulnerable, and
could have helped locals satisfy their economic and polit
ical interests more effectively. This dynamic
combined with acute factionalism at the national lambert
eadership level, resulting in a willingness to overcome
the other side at all costs, flush if it meant questionable decision-ma
king practices at both the National
Executive Board and the National Convention. such praseodymium
actices further reinforced distrust of the national
leadership per southeast, vitamin a well as any centralizing efforts they proposed. As a result, CUPE ’ s centralizing leadership faction, desiring both a more expansive identity and ‘ class one ’ for public sector workers a well as great
er administrative and political power for themselves,
425 1
CUPE National Executive Board,
Organizing the Organized
, 1995 National Convention: 4.
2
Graham Lowe, CUPE Staff Workload
Study Report, November 1990, 2-3.
was never able to overcome the self-reinforcing cycle
of autonomy which identified centralization with loss
of local ( democratic ) control. Although these conflicts
were most frequently expressed in terms of financial
resources and where they should rest, the real consider was over the community CUPE represented, what its interests were, and what kind of union structures and practices were needed by this community. however, because of the room that visions of majority rule
were so firmly attached to decentralized structures,
there was little effective space to explore how this ever-expanding community could combine particularity and universality in the context of structures that
both permitted participation and accountability and exerted
a very moral claim over locals ’ self-discipline in the
service of collective aims. As a result, CUPE continues
to struggle with the contradictory implications of growth, service, in
tegrating new identities, elaborating
new structures, deepening democratic decision-
making practices and sustaining militancy.
CUPE has continued in its phenomenal growth sinc
e 1975, absorbing large and important units of
membership in the 1980s and 90s, including the Canadi
an Airline Flight Attendants Association, the
Canadian Union of Educational Workers, and the rejoinder
of the BC Hospital Employees Union. Moreover,
CUPE has since 1993 encouraged the amalgamation of alabama
ready-existing locals where feasible and the
consolidation of newly organized groups
of members into established locals. Moreover, since 1995, the union
has besides been encouraging greater levels of membership
involvement in local union administration in order
to increase union power and conduct with
the problem of staff burn-out.
1
This is clearly a response to the
burdens placed on staff in the servicing boastfully num
bers of bargaining units: a CUPE Staff Workload Study
conducted by Graham Lowe in 1990 showed eminent levels of tension, illness, and lower levels of job satisfaction amongst staff.
2
however, the contradictory dynam
ics of organizing and servicing in the context of a growing yet
decentralized marriage have besides persisted. indeed, the tr
end within the union towards the proliferation of
426 3
G. McGuire, National Secretary-Tr
easurer’s Report on the General Fund,
CUPE 1999 Convention Documents: 19.
4
This figure is gleaned from repor
t of the five Regional Directors to CUPE’s
1999 Convention; however, some reports are more
complete and detailed than others, making it
difficult to ensure this data’s exactitude.
smaller and smaller locals has continued. Although by 1999, 62 % of CUPE ’ s membership belonged to locals of 500 members or greater, thorium
is represented only 8% of the total
number of locals. In other words, 92 % of CUPE ’ s more than 4000 locals have 500 me
mbers or less, indicating a very fragmented
representational social organization.
3
Moreover, recent data about the organi
zation of new bargaining units indicates
that the average size of modern dicker uni
ts organized between 1995 and 1997 was 74 members.
4
In
other words, the marriage continues to organize precisely the kind of locals which benefit least from local autonomy : those with few of their own fiscal and hum
an resources, a weaker bargaining position relative
to their employer, greater addiction on national servici
ng but also greater difficulties in participating in
the union ’ s broader decision-making structures. Desp
ite the creation of a per
manent National Convention
aid fund in 1991, these locals continue to be
the least capable of getting to convention, let alone
organizing the kind of political deepen that could fo
ster new structures, develop broader identities and
democratic communities, and enhance collective bargaining power. As a result of these problems, there has
been since 1975 an ongoing debate over the kinds of
home structures which can best represent the inte
rests of CUPE’s various occupational identities. This
topic has become more press with time, as the sectors which CUPE has since moved into continue to be characterised by a disjunction between decen
tralized management (by community agencies or boards
of directors ) and centralized sources of
funding framed by provincial public policy. As the locus of political
and fiscal control condition in CUPE-dominated sectors has
continued to shift from local to provincial
governments, authoritative levers of united states post office
litical power are further beyond the reach of the autonomous local. The
underdevelopment of both sectoral cobalt
llective bargaining structures and pr
ovincial divisions with strong
political capacities for coordination and mobilizati
on has been due to the continuing power of the local
427 5
The NDP government in BC had established the possibility of se
ctoral bargaining, which has been reversed since the election of
the Liberals in 2001. autonomy acculturation in the union. In widening quarters in the union, the efficacy of
these local structures continues to be questioned.
As a leave, CUPE has since 1981 promoted the dev
elopment of coordinated
or broader-based bargaining
structures. There have been some major successes on this front, peculiarly in the hospital sector in all provinces, equally well as in early sectors in
Quebec, New Brunswick, and British Columbia.
5
However, these
successes have been made possible not by home shifts over which level of the union should be responsible for collective dicker, but rather by
a ‘supportive’ legislative context which mandates such
bargaining structures. In the absence of these legal
supports, there is real and continuing resistance,
particularly from big and relatively more successful locals, to voluntarily tying local memberships to a broad structure that would require some let go of
ing of absolute local sovereignty over collective
bargain. Without strategically
important locals participating in
meaningful ways, coordinated bargaining
structures are unfunded and without a lot pull.
Nowhere has this been more marked than in the
municipal sector, where the traditions of local
autonomy were spawned. Regional coordinated bargaining
efforts were largely ineffective until governments t
hemselves amalgamated and forced the rationalization of
CUPE ’ s bargaining units. Some within CUPE have
admitted that, even though the Ontario government’s
force amalgamations of municipalities and school boar
ds in the late 1990s were deeply problematic, they
achieved in one fell swoop the kind of rationalization and
forging of broader collective identities that CUPE
itself had been trying but ineffective to achieve for 30 years. The diversity of CUPE ’ sulfur membership has besides in
creased in demographic terms as well, with issues
of race and ethnicity and intimate orientation joining gender
as the major forms of equity politics within the
union. CUPE has been rightly recognized as a drawing card in advancing equity issues and politics, both within the canadian british labour party bowel movement and canadian society more generally. As a resultant role, CUPE has been
428 6
Robinson, 21; Moody, 58; Gindin,
The Canadian Auto Workers
, 266
7
Johnson, 31, 40-1; Robinson, 32.
8
On the issue of the concentration of gay and lesbian workers in
the public sector, see Gerald Hunt, “Sexual Orientation and the
canadian Labour Movement, ” in
Relations Industrielles / Industrial Relations
52, no. 4 (1997): 806.
deemed one of the most authoritative
sources of ‘social unionism’ on the Canadian labour scene, which
defines the goals of the labor movement in terms of
broader working-class interests, rather than the
contiguous and sometimes narrow-minded economic interests of union members.
6
Indeed, since the 1960s, social
unionism has become peculiarly associated with populace
sector unions like CUPE, as their “economistic”
collective dicker interests are inherently tied to public policy debates and consequently require political mobilization and coalition-building around visions of west
hat the state should do for the public, in ways that
those of private sector unions do not.
7
Added to this is the much higher number of women, racialized and heathen minorities, and gays and lesbians in the ranks of
public sector workers, whose experience of work is
powerfully shaped by forms of discrimi
nation in the broader social context.
8
Insofar as CUPE ’ s official policies reflect the particular interests of these gr
oups, the union has at some level been able to integrate
new identities into the union ’ s
self-definition and priorities.
however, CUPE continues to experience serious
internal problems with how these issues are
represented and acted upon, and social trade unionist cobalt
mmitments have had mixed effects on locals. In
finical, CUPE ’ mho entrenched decentralization has
been an important constraint on the effective
execution of its progressive
equity policies, in the realms of collective bargaining and internal
representation of a diverse membership. The conver
gence of the problems of decentralization, local size
and the impact of the gender division of parturiency in public
sector employment illustrates this point most
potently. First, the sectors where women are concen
trated are those predominantly characterized by the
disjunction between local administration and peasant
political and financial control, and are therefore
precisely those which would benefit most from red brigades
oader-based bargaining structur
es. Second, women are
besides more likely located in sectors where small loca
ls are concentrated, such as social service agencies,
429 child care centres, and homes for the aged, while
men tend to find themselves in the large locals
characterizing hydro and municipal make. In other words, the problems of humble locals – lack of resources, lack of access to union decision-making structures,
relative vulnerability and weakness in collective
bargaining – are the problems of
CUPE women primarily, and the negativ
e effects of decentralization on
humble locals are predominantly experienced in gendered ways. Third, and most significant for the practice of sol
cial unionism by union locals (and not merely parent
unions ), local autonomy has much been used to shield
locals from implementing provincial or national
policies, particularly with respect to equity measures
that might disturb local relations and distributions of
exponent. Given that no local anesthetic is compelled to parti
cipate in campaigns or alter collective bargaining agendas
that would foster greater equity, it is possible for metric ton
hem to ‘support’ such policies at convention without being
committed to the unmanageable work implied by them.
While national leaders consistently make moral appeals to
the membership to interpret local autonomy as
involving broader obligations rather than mere
independence from the center, the gap between policy
statements and policy im
plementation continues
( although the very polish of local anesthetic autonomy makes it
difficult to gather data which would make an exact
evaluation of this trouble possible ). even though, since 1975, CUPE has had two major inte
rnal examinations of union structures, it
has been unable to alter those structures in a fundamental way and to develop new approaches to the practice of majority rule in its decision-making structures. In both 1977 and 1993, CUPE set up commissions charged with conducting a exhaustive survey of the union,
receiving submissions from people located at all
levels of the union ’ mho structures, and developing
recommendations for constitutional changes to be
presented at a subsequent convention. Both commissi
ons were also struck to see whether a different
libra between local autonomy and broader
identities, structures and
obligations could be reached.
Although the union must be commended for engaging in such a populace and open-ended introspection ,
430 something which most other unions would never c
ontemplate, the results of these processes were
disappointing to say the least. At the conventions
of 1977 and 1993, no substantive structural changes to
the entrench mean and exercise of local aut
onomy were made. Indeed, the 1977 Convention
approved the regionalization of national services, and rejected all recommendations aiming at increasing home coordinating and disciplinary capacities. furthermore, very short attention has been given to
the way national conventions now make the
meaningful engagement of delegates very unmanageable. As a resultant role, conventions are rarely places where delegates themselves work on constructing a consens
us around policy positions; instead, they respond to
pre-packaged side papers developed and submitted by
the National Executive Board and not subject to
change. This is the legitimate outgrowth of the administrative set about adopted after the National Executive Board debates in the early 1970s, in whic
h streamlining and efficiency was prioritized over
deepening meaningful participation in the context of a large and growing convention. Though some conventions, like the one in 1979, have been noteworthy for the
extent of ‘rank-and-file
’ anger expressed at the
leadership, demands for greater milit
ancy from the National Union have not translated into structural
changes which would allow for those demands to be acted upon effectively. ultimately, the main way to carry enemy within CUPE remains exit : delegates and local leaders who are able threaten disaffiliation and bring to block leadership plans. In
that sense, CUPE’s ultimate democratic sanction
consists of saying no, rather than developing e
ffective control of the union’s agenda and placing real
option directions – not to mention inner st
ructural changes that would enhance participation – in front
of the membership. furthermore, the way in which the union ’ s size
presents barriers to democratic accountability and
access to leadership positions is by and large ignored in t
he union. It is notable in a union which prides itself
on internal majority rule that all national office incu
mbents – save one – have left their positions through
431 9
Little, Rintoul, Hartman, as well as Jeff Rose, Jean-Claude Laniel, Judy Darcy and Geraldine Maguire all retired out of their
positions. Kealey Cummings has been the only incumbent national officer ever defeated,
when Laniel won the National
Secretary Treasurer side in 1985. retirement or resignation quite than via the passing of an election.
9
Moreover, national leadership is generally
the latest in a sequence of elective positions at
the national level – almost all of CUPE’s National
Presidents have either been members of the National Ex
ecutive Board before ascending to the Presidency.
In that sense, local leaders – let alone members – can ’ t
really contest national elections in an effective way,
as one already needs to be separate of the exceed leadersh
ip group to have both the profile and the kind of
experience thought to be needed, by which clock one is already socialized into the status quo. The size of the union makes the prospect of engaging in national elec
toral contests even more daunting, but there are
no policies which address the imbalance that
exists between incumbents and challengers.
As well, about no attention was given – until ve
ry recently – to the way CUPE’s adoption of a
modified servicing model worked to reduce membership engagement. Until 1995, most CUPE members and leaders were actively creating bureaucratized relationships in which addiction on experts was being continually fostered. Although, as we have seen,
the appeal of experts reflected members’ lack of
confidence that they themselves could lead their locals
effectively, there was also a real identification of
expert servicing with professional and effectiv
e unionism. Even though a model of member-led and
serve locals, in line with Lenihan ’ s original visi
on, might have been more democratic, this would have
required a different approach to coupling education,
which only appeared on the Union’s agenda in 1995 with
its
Organizing the Organized
policy statement. Such an approach may have also deepened decentralist
tendencies, and there is no guarantee that it would have cost less, even though this is a key premise in Organizing the Organized
.
ultimately, local autonomy continues to place major constraints on the finance of combativeness in CUPE. again, it must be said that the local autonomy cult
ure does militate against the National Office using its
432 administrative exponent over the National Defence Fund to
restrain local memberships in their collective
dicker struggles and enforce norms of ‘ responsible union leadership ’. furthermore, since 1975, with the advent of the Anti-Inflation Programme
and other forms of direct state inte
rvention in public sector collective
bargaining, CUPE has opened itself to the use of st
rikes and protests as both political and economic
weapons. The exercise of using the National Defenc
e Fund to support “fight back” campaigns which defend
public sector jobs against denationalization and contracti
ng out, for instance, has stretched the idea of the NDF
well beyond the traditional come to fund linked pur
ely to collective bargaining processes.
however, local anesthetic autonomy continues to place massachusetts
jor barriers to funding militancy. The NDF has
endured two subsequent major fiscal crises, in 1982 when another moratorium was established, and again in 1997, when a major special assessment had to be levied to increase resources. In other words, despite the National Office ’ s inability to place organizational interests ahead of local combativeness, which might be considered a democratic profit, the NDF has not constantly been there when locals needed it most. furthermore, even if CUPE could create larger entities engaged in sectoral stripe
gaining, it isn’t clear that the
union could sustain sector-wide strike actions that
would be needed to back these structures up. Indeed,
the latest NDF crisis was created specifically by
the convergence of collective bargaining struggles by
larger locals established by government-mandat
ed amalgamations and increased spending on campaigns
resisting neoliberal restructure of government selenium
rvices. CUPE’s NDF falls far short of the kind of
resources needed to sustain combativeness in an ongoing way, and
the ever-present threat of financial instability
of the Fund – and the union more by and large – farther c
ontributes to the self-reinforcing cycle of autonomy
which produces crises in the foremost place. II.
Understanding Union Democracy, Uni
on Structure, and Class Formation
This has been more than a objective history,
although CUPE was certainly in need of such a
433 discussion. This examination of CUPE ’ second development besides requires us to reflect on the mean of – and necessity conditions for – union majority rule, a well as its
relationship to the process of class formation. In
particular, this sketch of CUPE highlights theoretical
insights about the relationship between structure and
majority rule, leaders ’ and members ’ relationship to dem
ocracy, the impact of union functions on democracy,
and the democratic implications of mergers. first, rather than there being a simple relationship between majority rule and structure, with centralization clearly undemocratic and unaccountable, if
more effective, and decentralization less effective
but more participatory and accountable, CUPE paints a mu
ch more complex picture. Centralization was
not pursued plainly for reasons of self-aggrandizem
ent or central oligarchical control, nor was
decentralization constantly about preserving the direct parti
cipatory control of membership. While there may
have been individuals who espoused a detail struct
ural arrangement for those reasons, others had
early motivations which disturb this comfortable correlation.
Centralized structures were instead seen as the
appropriate containers for a broader one hundred fifty
ass identity that could articulate and further the general interests of
populace sector workers as a whole. such structures
made alternative moral claims on members’ allegiance
and solidarity, asserting the democratic value of mu
tual aid and self-discipline in the name of a more
classless redistribution of power
and resources. On the flip side,
decentralization could mean democracy
for a particularistic identity, but one from which moment
st others were excluded even when their interests were
directly affected by the decisions of another group. In
that sense, our evaluations of the (un)democratic
character of union structures are in important
ways bound up with assumptions about who should be
included in the democratic community. second, leaders ’ and members ’ kinship to
democracy is also much more complicated than
either Trotsky or Michels would have us believe. Al
though the project of centralization was often tied to
some leaders ’ personal prerogatives in the Michelsian s
ense, it was never straightforwardly so. Rather,
434 centralizers, though their practices were often problemat
ic in democratic terms, were aiming at creating a
broader community, an across-the-board class identity
for Canadian public sector workers. As such,
centralization was not clearly about removing contro
l from the membership, but rather about widening the
boundaries of reciprocal obligation amongst members and asse
rting that the legitimate scope of democratic
decision-making extended beyond the immediate work
group. In this context, decentralizing forces
amongst the membership were sometimes less ‘ democratic ’ than centralizers in their attempts to insulate themselves from the demands of
the broader community and maintain inequalities of condition in which
they remained relatively privileged. In that sens
e, CUPE shows that Michels was right to question the
inherently democratic nature of decentralization and of
the mass membership, even if he was incorrect in
his absolute pessimism about both leaders and mem
bers. However, both Michels and Trotsky were
overstating the case that all lambert
eaders were oligarchs in waiting.
As a consequence, one can not make claims about the
‘essential’ relationship that leaders and members
have to coupling democracy. CUPE leaders and member
s were on both sides of the centralizing /
decentralizing debate, which, as we ’ ve already seen, can not be unproblematically linked to oligarchy and democracy respectively. Leaders and members both were
aligned with different notions of democratic
community, and both experienced pressures towards bot
h democracy and oligarchy, in different moments
and context. furthermore, the sheath of CUPE shows this to be a active and mutually determining relationship : it was the interaction of centralizer
s and decentralizers, and not the linear playing out of an
elite project or membership insurgency, which determi
ned CUPE’s structure and internal practices. In that
sense, insofar as CUPE ’ s home leaders sometime
s pursued their own personal power interests, and
increasingly understand those interests as inseparable
from those of the organization as a whole, they
were never able to create a union that would actually
displace locally-defined goals. Again, whether those
local goals were democratically or oligarchically determined varied widely across the union .
435 Third, while the laterality of the post-war thousand
odel of effective unionism does have an important
role in shaping the home administration, the
appropriate role of (elected and appointed) leaders and
members, and decision-making practices, it does
not produce exactly the same structural and
( united nations ) democratic outcomes in all unions. The institut
ionalization of the collective bargaining system, along
with the norms of ‘ creditworthy unionism ’ and professi
onalized servicing of union membership within the
broader labor motion, did foster and reinforce a desire for technical leadership. As well, the ‘ servicing model ’ was never strictly a leadership project ; in fac
t, it was something actively pursued by both leaders
and members. however, this particular vision of
union function did not create a traditionally centralized
commercial enterprise union. alternatively, there was a argue over
how this union function should be carried out, a debate
which interacted with preexisting identities and stru
ctures in such a way as to produce a rather
decentralized translation of the service model.
Even though the National Office designed and delivered
services, this was never to give them the kind of
power to intervene and shape local union affairs that other
unions had developed via centralize service. This had much to do with the way the shape of the canadian submit allowed place and francium
agmented identities – and the collect
ive bargaining structures which
represented them – to persist and provi
de a structural and legal basis for retaining local control. As such,
neither the pressures for greater oneness and coordination,
nor the pursuit of membership growth, resulted in
centralize oligarchic control, as would be predicted
by much of the institut
ionalist literature. CUPE ’ sulfur home leaders were never able to become ‘ managers of discontented ’ in the manner that Mills described, for they could neither mobilize nor restrain the membership in the absence of any real power of approve. alternatively, whether efforts from the kernel were str
ong or weak, democratic and participatory or top-down and
bureaucratic, National Office services supplemented rat
her than replaced local union initiative. If there are
‘ managers of discontented ’ in CUPE, they
remain at the heads of its locals.
however, growth and size did present CUPE with major democratic challenges, as predicted by
436 both Michelsian and institutionalist analyses. As CU
PE added new types of members and industries to its
fold and multiplied the legal and regulative conditions
under the union functioned, individual members have
faced greater challenges in understanding the overall
union, its structures, policies, and practices.
furthermore, central spaces for collective decision-making did become less subject to
active
democratic
control of delegates, in that it was difficult to
work out differences across regions and occupations to
construct alternatives to the national leadership and it
s initiatives. Even though CUPE’s size was seen as a
problem, it was understood by most national leaders in
administrative rather than political terms, as a
challenge to efficiency preferably than democracy. As
well, national leaders did pursue strategies aimed at
managing convention argument, and failed to develop st
ructures or spaces which enhanced membership
participation at more central levels. That said, these developments did not mean the
complete elimination of democracy in CUPE.
There constantly remained the
negative
democratic sanction, the possibility of saying no, which delegates and
locals continue to exercise. In other words, the
membership is not always completely disabled in the
context of large, complex organizations ; rather, it can
retain come capacity to place ‘democratic’ limits on
the leadership should that be necessary. Though one nautical mile
ght not think this is the height of democratic
expression, it does provide a correction to the idea that
increased size eliminates the possibility of any type
of membership control. As well, the convention ’ mho policy decisions were
rarely seen as problematic except when they had
fiscal ramifications. Given the across-the-board telescope that c
ontinued to rest with the membership in terms of
implementation of national policies,
the extent to which members retained control over the convention
process seemed irrelevant to locals. even if convention voted to adopt a policy supporting a controversial social policy, membership could inactive determine if it w
ould be implemented at the local level. This points to
the importance of understanding how union st
ructures are internally differentiated in terms of what kinds of
437 control rests where. not all centralized structur
es always shut down the possibility for membership
treatment and control, nor do all decentralized struct
ures provide for a robust experience of democracy.
III.
Understanding the Political Implications
finally, studying CUPE raises several authoritative
questions about the political possibilities of labour
movements increasingly dominated by populace sector uni
ons, both numerically and politically. In particular,
we need to explore what CUPE says about the state of
working class identities, the possibilities for union
renewal via the practice of social unionism, and the polit
ical implications of mergers for the strength of the
north american parturiency campaign. First, even though CUPE created far more organizati
onal unity in the Canadian public sector than
existed at any time previous, the message and durabilit
y of this unity is in question. As we have seen,
CUPE opted for organizational union over substantiv
e unity in order to reap immediate instrumental
benefits from rationalization and greater
size and it has continued in this approach to unification since 1963.
The given has always been that meaty uni
ty would be more easily created subsequent to the
courtly creation of the union. however, CUPE s
hows us that pre-existing identities can easily be
internalized into more expansive structures and
create major barriers to creating new collective
identifications. In that sense, even though class field-grade officer
rmation involves creating organizational expressions of
collective interests, there is no
guarantee that class identities and con
sciousness, let alone effective class
action, will emerge. In other words, structures
in which identities and decision-making processes are
adjacent are necessity for the build of a classify
actor rooted in a legitimate democratic community, and
yet are fabulously unmanageable to construct. second, insofar as public sector unionism has been cl
osely identified with social unionism in North
America, one needs to ask whether the organizations
seen as the bearers of this approach can actually
438 ‘ deliver the goods ’, so to speak. While public sector unions do have a predilection towards social unionism and a broader vision of the union ’ sulfur purposes, there is no
reason to believe that the structures created by
public sector workers will be capable of efficaciously fi
ghting for that expanded social vision. Indeed, the in-
depth examen of CUPE reveals an administration
with an underdeveloped capacity to arbitrate between
differences of identity and interest, to make collect
ive decisions that share power and resources in ways
accepted as legitimate and bind, and to inculcate t
he norms of self-discipline and sacrifice for others in
one ’ randomness community who are less well off. All of these capacities are substantive to the drill of social unionism, particularly insofar as it involves deoxycytidine monophosphate
ooperation with non-union organizations whose interests
overlap but are not identical, and aims at def
ending class interests beyond those of immediate
membership. alternatively, the case of CUPE shows that electron volt
en within a union with social unionist politics, there
is a real unwillingness to place immediate member
ship interests behind the interests of the broader
community. This is exacerbated by CUPE ’ s decentraliz
ed structure, which makes it possible for leadership
to espouse progressive political positions and advocate for social policies which meaning sections of the membership neither supports nor can be made to go aluminum
ong with since the more central levels of policy-
making can not require local anesthetic union participation in thes
e policies in any case. In other words, social
unionism does raise core issues about union functions, but
at least for one of its major champions, there is
no free burning consider over how to drill social unionism at all levels of the union, last, CUPE raises good questions about the
ramifications of mergers for creating both
effective and democratic unions. While CUPE ’ mho social organization was not distinctly less democratic than those of its parent unions, it did permit the morphologic reproducti
on of centrifugal forces which have blocked the
exploitation of richer forms of democracy, more effe
ctive forms of coordination, and more substantive
oneness in class terms. While canadian public sector wo
rkers are certainly better off for the creation of the
union, they are not unproblematically so. Four declination
ades later, CUPE continues to live with the unforeseen
439 consequences of its amalgamation talks, its potential contained by the political compromises structured into the union ’ s own administration which were necessary to se
cure its formation. CUPE was the product of a
fusion aimed at fostering greater class oneness and chromium
eating a more powerful union to represent public sector
workers ’ immediate economic and political interests.
The same motivation drives the current wave of
mergers in the north american english parturiency movement. Howeve
r, little time is taken to consider whether these
new mega-unions will be both effective and democrati
c. CUPE is at the same time a beacon and a
cautionary narrative .
440 bibliography chief Sources Manuscript Collections Canadian Union of Public Employees,
Fonds
, National Archives of Canada. MG 28, I234.
The CUPE Fonds includes documents from its
predecessor unions, its locals and provincial
divisions, and the National Office. The major groups of documents from this Fonds used in this dissertation are as follows : Barnetson, A.M.
An Early Brief History of the CETU Formation
. 1965.
Canadian Union of Public Employees conventionality Proceedings and Documents, 1963-1975. National Executive Board Minutes, 1963-1975. National Executive Committee Minutes, 1963-1975. National President, General Correspondence, 1963-1975. National Organization of Civic, Utility and Electrical Workers National Executive Board Meeting Minutes, 1950-1952. National Union of Public Employees convention Proceedings, 1956-1963. Merger symmetry, 1957-1963. fusion Documents, 1955-1963. National Director, Circulars and Reports, 1955-58. National Executive Board Meeting Minutes, 1958-1963. National Union of Public Service Employees Director of Organization, Reports to
the NUPSE National Executive Board, 1955-1959.
convention Proceedings, 1958-1963. parallelism, 1957-1963. National Executive Board Meeting Minutes, 1952-1963. National Executive Committee Meeting Minutes, 1960-1963. National President, Reports to the NUPSE National Executive Board, 1961-62. amalgamation Documents, 1956-1963. Ontario Hydro Employees Union commensurateness, 1957-1959. Executive Board Minutes, 1957-1958. amalgamation Documents, 1955-1963. government of Canada Documents Department of Labour.
Labour Gazette
, 1914-1924 (published monthly).
Human Resources and Development Canada. Revi
ew of Canada Labour Code, Part I. 1996. Online at
hypertext transfer protocol : //www110.hrdc-drhc.gc.ca/sf
mc_fmcs/lcctr_tclcr/toc.html
Government of New Brunswick Documents reputation of the Royal Commission on Finance and Municipal Taxation in New Brunswick
. E.Byrne, chair.
Fredericton, NB, 1964 .
441 politics of Ontario Documents Task Force on School Board Reductions Final Report
. Toronto, ON: Publications Ontario, 1996.
early Documents CUPE, Public Relations Department, “ 25
th
Anniversary Special Issue”,
The Public Employee
9, no.3 (Fall
1988 ). CUPE, National Executive Board,
Organizing the Organized
, 1995 National Convention CUPE, 1999 Convention Proceedings Lowe. G.
CUPE Staff Workload Study Report
, November 1990.
baron Workers ’ Union,
The Power Workers’ Union 50
th
Anniversary: A pictorial history of the union of
workers behind the construction, operation and master of arts
intenance of one of the world’s great power
systems
. Toronto: Power Workers’ Union, 1996.
Interviews Cummings, Kealey. Interview by writer, 17 December 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON. Levine, Gilbert. Interview by Susan Crean,
December 1995, tape recording, Ottawa, ON.
Levine, Gilbert. Interview by generator, 16 December 1999, personal, Ottawa, ON. secondary Sources Abella, I.M.
Nationalism, Communism, and Canadian Labour
. Toronto and Buffalo: University of
Toronto Press, 1995. Anderson, P. “ The Limits and Possibilities of Trade Union Action. ” In
Trade Unions Under Capitalism
, eds.
T.Clarke and L.Clements, 333-
350. London: Fontana Collins, 1977.
Allen, V.L.
Power in Trade Unions
. London: Longmans, Green, 1954.
Armstrong, C., & Nelles, H.V.
Monopoly’s Moment: The Organization and Regulation of Canadian Utilities,
1830-1930.
Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1986.
Artibise, Alan.
Winnipeg: A Social History of Urban Growth 1874-1914
. Montreal and London: McGill
University Press, 1975. Artibise, Alan. “ Boosterism and the Development of Prairie Cities, 1871-1913. ” in
Town and City: Aspects of
western canadian Urban Development
, ed. A. Artibise, 209-235. Regina: University of Regina /
canadian Plains Research Centre, 1981. Ashworth, E.M.
Toronto Hydro Recollections
. Toronto: University of Toronto Press,1955.
Avery, D.
‘Dangerous Foreigners’: European Immigrant
Workers and Labour Radicalism in Canada, 1896-
1932.
Toronto: McClelland and Stewart,1979.
442 Babcock, R.
Gompers in Canada: A Study in American Continentalism Before the First World War
. Toronto
and Buffalo : University of Toronto Press, 1974. Baines, C. “ The Professions and an Ethic of Care. ” In
Women’s Caring: Feminist Perspectives on Social
Welfare
, eds. C.Baines et al., 36-72. Toronto: McClelland and Stewart, 1991.
Barbash, J.
The Practice of Unionism
. New York: Harper, 1956.
Beetham, D. “ Michels and his Critics. ”
European Journal of Sociology
22 ( 1981 ) : 81-99. Beetham, D. “ Michels, Roberto. ” In
The Blackwell Encyclopaedia of Political Science
, ed V. Bogdanor, ed.,
364-5. London : Blackwell, 1991. Bercuson, D. “ The Winnipeg General Strike. ” In
On Strike: Six Key Labour Struggles in Canada, 1919-
1949
, ed. I. Abella, 1-32. Toronto: James Lorimer and Co., 1975.
Bercuson, D.
Confrontation at Winnipeg: Labour, Industr
ial Relations, and the General Strike
. Rev. ed.
Montreal / Kingston : McGill-
Queen’s University Press, 1990.
Bird, R.M. “ The Growth of the Public Sector in Canada. ” In
Public Employment and Compensation in
Canada : Myths and Realities
, ed. D.K. Foot, 19-44. Scarborough, ON: Butterworths and Co.,1978.
Bok, D., & Dunlop, J.
Labor and the American Community
. New York: Simon and Schuster, 1970.
Bolduc, A. “ The History of Electricity in Quebec. ”
Hydro Quebec website
, online at
hypertext transfer protocol : //www.hydroquebec.com/learning/ histor
y/index.html (viewed January 25, 2005).
Braverman, H.
Labor and Monopoly Capital: the Degradation
of Work in the Twentieth Century
. New York:
Monthly Review Press, 1974. Bright, D.
The Limits of Labour: Class Formati
on and the Labour Movement in Calgary
. Vancouver: UBC
press, 1998. canadian Association of Social Workers. “ CASW
Represents Canadian Professional Social Workers.”
CASW website
, online at http://www.casw-acts.ca/ (viewed January 14, 2005).
canadian Broadcasting Corporation. “ The ‘Other
Revolution’: Louis Robichaud’s New Brunswick.”
CBC
Archives
, online at http://archives.cbc.ca/IDD-1-
73-519/ politics_economy/robichaud (viewed
February 1, 2005 ) Chaison, G.
Union Mergers in Hard Times: The View from Five Countries
. Ithaca / London: ILR Press /
Cornell University Press, 1996. Cockburn, C.
Brothers: Male Dominance and Technological Change
, 2
nd
ed. Concord, Mass:
Pluto Press, 1984 .
443 Coleman, J.R. “ The Compulsive Pressures of Democracy. ” In
Labor and Trade Unionism: An
interdisciplinary Reader
, eds. W.Galenson and S.M Lipset, 207-215. New York: John Wiley and
Sons, 1960. Commons, J.
Industrial Government
. New York: Macmillan, 1921.
Conley, J.R. “ Frontier Labourers, Crafts in Cr
isis, and the Western Labour Revolt: the Case of
vancouver 1900-1919. ”
Labour / Le Travail
23,( Spring 1989): 9-27.
Cook, A..
Union Democracy: Practice and Ideal
. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1963.
Crawford, K.G.
Canadian Municipal Government
. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1954.
Crean, S.
Grace Hartman : A Woman for Her Time
. Vancouver: New Star Books, 1995.
kris, G. “ Exclusion or Solidarity ? Vancouver
Workers Confront the ‘Oriental Problem’.” In
Canadian
Working Class History
, eds. L.S MacDowell and I.Radforth,
311-327. Toronto: Canadian Scholars
press, 1992. Crispo, J.
International Unionism: a Study in Canadian-American Relations
. Toronto: McGraw Hill, 1967.
Crozier, M., Huntington, S.P., and Watanuki, J.
The Crisis of Democracy: Report on the Governability of
Democracies to the Trilateral Commission
. New York: New York University Press, 1975.
Dagenais, M. “ Discipliner les fonctionnaires de l ’ admin
istration municipale de Montréal dans les premières
décennies du XXe siècle : en théorie … et en
pratique.” Canadian Historical Association
Historical
Papers
(1990): 71-90.
Davis, M.
Prisoners of the American Dream
. New York: Verso, 1986.
Deverell, J. “ The Ontario Hospital Dispute 1980-1981. ”
Studies in Political Economy
9 (1982): 179-190.
Dewar, K, C. “ Private Electrical Utilities and Municipal Ownership in Ontario, 1891-1900. ”
Urban History
Review
12, no.1 (June 1983): 29-38.
DiGiacomo, G.
Federalism and Labour Policy in Canada
. Working paper, Institute of Intergovernmental Relations at Queen ’ sulfur University, Kingston, ON, 2001. Downey, D. “ CUPE Boss Tripled Union ’ s Membership
: Founding President Took His Workers ‘From an Era
of Collective Begging to Collective Bargaining ’. ”
Globe and Mail
, 19 May 2000: R6.
Drache, D., & Glasbeek, H.
The Changing Workplace: Reshaping Canada’s Industrial Relations
System
. Toronto: James Lorimer & Company Publishers, 1992.
444 Dubovoj, S. “ Ontario Hydro. ”
Canadian Company Histories
(June 1997): 1.
Edelstein, J., & Warner, M.
Comparative Union Democracy: Or
ganization and Opposition in British and
american Unions
, 2
nd
ed. New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Books,1979.
Eldridge, J.E.T. “ Trade Unions
and Bureaucratic Control.” In
Trade Unions Under Capitalism
, eds. T.Clarke
and L.Clements, 175-183. London :
Fontana Collins, 1977.
Ewen, G. “ Quebec : class and ethnicity. ” In
The Workers’ Revolt in Canada, 1917-1925
, ed. C.Heron, 87-
143. Toronto : University of Toronto, 1998. Fernbach, D. “ Introduction. ” In
The First International and After: Political Writings Vol. 3
, K. Marx, ed. D.
Fernbach, 9-27. London : Pelican / New Left Review, 1974. Finkel, A. “ Origins of the Welfare State in Canada. ” In
The Canadian State: Political Economy and Political
Power
, ed. L. Panitch, 344-370. Toront
o: University of Toronto, 1977.
Frankel, S.
Staff Relations in the Civil Service: The Canadian Experience
. Montreal: McGill University
imperativeness, 1962. Frankel, S., & Pratt, C.
Municipal Labour Relations in Canada
. Montreal: McGill Industrial Relations Centre
/ canadian Federation of Mayors and Municipalities, 1954. Friedman, S.
Teamster Rank and File: Power, Bureaucracy and Rebellion at Work and in a Union.
New
York : Columbia University Press, 1982. Fudge, J. “ The Gendered Dimensions of Labour jurisprudence :
Why Women Need Inclusive Unionism and Broader-
based Bargaining. ” In
Women Challenging Unions: Feminism, Democracy, and Militancy,
eds. L.
Briskin & P. McDermott, 231-248. Tor
onto: University of Toronto,1993.
Fudge, J., & Tucker, E.
Labour Before the Law: The Regulation of Workers’ Collective Action in
Canada, 1900-1948.
Don Mills, ON: Oxford University Press, 2001.
Gaskell, J. “ What Counts as Skill ? Reflections on Pay Equity. ” In
Just Wages: a Feminist Perspective on
Pay Equity
, eds. J.Fudge and P.McDermott, 141-159. Toront
o: University of Toronto Press, 1991.
Gauvin, M. “ The Reformer and the machine : Montr
eal Civic Politics from Ra
ymond Préfontaine to Médéric
Martin. ”
Journal of Canadian Studies
13, no. 2 ( Summer 1978): 16-26.
Geras, N.
Literature of Revolution: Essays on Marxism
. London: Verso, 1986.
Gindin, S.
The Canadian Auto Workers: The Birth and Transformation of a Union
. Toronto: James
Lorimer & Company Publishers, 1995. Gindin, S. “ Socialism with Sober Senses
: Developing Workers’ Capacities.” In
The Socialist Register 1998:
445 The Communist Manifesto now
, eds. L.Panitch and C. Leys, 75-101. New York: Monthly Review
press, 1998. Gompers, S. “ The Philosophy of Trade Unionism. ” In
Unions, Management and the Public
, eds. E. Wight
Bakke and C. Kerr, 30-31. New York : Harcourt Brace and Co., 1948. Hagopian, J.S. “ Debunking the Public Health Myth :
Municipal Politics and Class Conflict During the Galt,
Ontario Waterworks Campaigns, 1888-1890. ”
Labour/Le Travail
39 ( give 1997 ) : 39-68. Hardman, J.B.S.
American Labor Dynamics
. New York: Harcourt Brace & Co., 1928.
Hartman, G. “ Organizing Public Serv
ice Workers in the Sixties.” In
We Stood Together: First Hand
Accounts of dramatic Events in Canada ’ s Labour Past
, ed. G. Montero, 183-203. Toronto: James
Lorimer and Co., 1979. Harvey, D.
The Limits to Capital
. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1989.
Harvey, D. “ The Geography of the Manifesto. ” In
The Socialist Register 1998: The Communist Manifesto
now
, eds. L.Panitch and C. Leys, 49-74. Ne
w York: Monthly Review Press, 1998.
Held, D.
Models of Democracy
, 2
nd
ed. Stanford: Stanford
University Press, 1996. Hemingway, J.
Conflict and Democracy: Studies in Trade Union Government
. London : Clarendon, 1978. Herberg, W. “ Bureaucracy and Democracy in Labor Unions. ”
Antioch Review
3 (Fall 1943): 405-17.
Heron, C. “ The Crisis of the Craftsman :
Hamilton’s Metal Workers in the Early 20
th
Century.”
Labour / Le
Travail
6 (Autumn 1980): 7-48.
Heron, C.
The Canadian Labour Movement: A Short History
. Toronto: James Lorimer and Co., 1996.
Heron, C. “ National Contours :
Solidarity and Fragmentation.” In
The Workers’ Revolt in Canada, 1917-
1925
, ed. C.Heron, 268-304. Toronto:
University of Toronto, 1998.
Heron, C., and M. Siemiatycki. “ The Great Wa
r, the State, and Working-Class Canada.” In
The Workers’
Revolt in Canada, 1917-1925
, ed. C.Heron, 11-42 Toronto:
University of Toronto, 1998.
Heron, C., and R. Storey, eds.
On the Job: Confronting the Labour Process in Canada
. Kingston &
montreal : McGill-Queen ’ randomness University Press, 1986. high, S. “ Planting the municipal Ow
nership Idea in Port Arthur, 1875-1914.”
Urban History Review
26, no.1
( October 1997 ) : 3-17. Hoxie, R.F.
Trade Unionism in the United States
. New York: Russell and Russell, 1966.
446 Huberman, M., & Young, D.
Hope Against Hope: Persistent Canadian Unions in the Interwar Years
.
Scientific Series, no. 28. montreal : Centre
interuniversitaire de recherche en analise des
organisations, 2000. Hunt, Gerald. “ sexual Orientation
and the Canadian Labour Movement.” In
Relations Industrielles /
Industrial Relations
52, no. 4 (1997): 787-809.
Hurd, R. “ Professional Employees and Uni
on Democracy: from Control to Chaos.”
Journal of Labor
research
21, no. 1 (Winter 2000): 103-115.
Hyman, R.
Marxism and the Sociology of Trade Unionism
. London: Pluto Press, 1971.
Hyman, R.
Industrial Relations: A Marxist Introduction
. London: MacMillan, 1975.
Hyman, R. “ The Politics of Workplace Trade Un
ionism: Recent Tendencies and Some Problems for
Theory. ” In
The Political Economy of Industrial Relations
: Theory and Practice in a Cold Climate
,
149-165. London : MacMillan, 1989. Hyman, R., & Fryer, R.H. “ Trade Uni
ons: Sociology and Political Economy.” In
Trade Unions Under
capitalism
, eds. T.Clarke and L.Clements,
152-174. London: Fontana Collins, 1977.
International Brotherhood of electrical Workers. “ History Local 353 Toronto. ” n.d. Online at hypertext transfer protocol : //www.ibew353.org/our
profile/history353.htm.
Ions, E. “ Oligarchy. ” In
The Blackwell Encyclopaedia of Political Science
, ed. V. Bogdanor, 391. London:
Blackwell, 1991. Johnston, P.
Success While Others Fail : Social Movement Unionism and the Public Workplace
. Ithaca,
new york : ILR Press, 1994. Kaufman, B. “ The early Institutionalists
on Industrial Democracy and Union Democracy.”
Journal of Labor
research
21, no.2 (Spring 2000): 189-209.
Kealey, G. “ 1919 : the Canadian Labour Revolt. ”
Labour/Le Travail
13 (Spring 1984): 215-220.
Kealey, G. “ State Repression of Labour and the Left
in Canada, 1914-1920: The Impact of the First World
War. ”
Canadian Historical Review
73 no. 3 (1992): 281-314.
Kealey, G. “ The Honest Workingman and Workers ’ Con
trol: The Experience of Toronto Skilled Workers,
1860-1892. ” In
Canadian Working Class History
, eds. L.S MacDowell and I.Radforth, 159-185.
Toronto : canadian Scholars Press, 1992. Kelly, J.
Trade Unions and Socialist Politics
. London : Verso, 1988. LaBotz, D.
Rank-and-File Rebellion: Teamsters for a Democratic Union
. New York: Verso, 1990.
447 Langford, T. “ Strikes and Class Consciousness. ”
Labour / Le Travail
34 (Fall 1994): 107-137.
Laxer, R.
Canada’s Unions
. Toronto: James Lorimer and Company, 1976.
Lee, J.A.
Love’s Gay Fool: Autobiography of John Alan Lee
, online at http://www.johnalanlee.ca/chapters/
( viewed January 28, 2005 ). Leier, M.
Where the Fraser River Flows: The Industrial
Workers of the World in British Columbia
.
vancouver : New Star Books, 1990. Leier, M.
Red Flags and Red Tape: The Making of a Labour Bureaucracy
. Toronto: University of Toronto
press, 1995. Leiserson, W.M.
American Trade Union Democracy
. New York: Columbia University Press, 1959.
Lenihan, P.
Patrick Lenihan: From Irish Rebel to Founder
of Canadian Public Sector Unionism,
ed.
G.Levine. St John ’ sulfur : canadian Committee on
Labour History / Memorial University, 1998.
Lenin, V. I. “ What Is to Be Done ? ” In
The Lenin Anthology
, ed. R. Tucker, 12-114. New York: W.W Norton
& Co, 1975. Lester, R.A.
As Unions Mature: An Analysis of the Evolution of American Unionism
. Princeton, N.J:
Princeton University Press, 1958. Lipset, S. M. “ The Political Process in
Trade Unions: a Theoretical Statement.” In
Labor and Trade
unionism : An interdisciplinary subscriber
, eds. W.Galenson and S.M Lipset, 216-242. New York: John
Wiley and Sons, 1960. Lipset, S.M. “ Michels ’ Theory of Political Parties ”, Introduction to
Political Parties: A Sociological Study of
the Emergence of Leadership, the Psychology of
Power, and the Oligarchic Tendencies of
Organization
, R. Michels, 15-39. New York: Free Press, 1962.
Lipset, S.M., Trow, M.A., and J.S. Coleman
. Union Democracy: The Internal Politics of the International
Typographical Union
. New York: The Free Press, 1956.
Lipton, C.
The Trade Union Movement of Canada, 1827-1959.
Toronto: NC Press, 1966.
Logan, H.A.
Trade Unions in Canada: Their Development and Functioning.
Toronto: University of
Toronto Press, 1948. Lowe, G.
Women in the Administrative Revoluti
on: the Feminization of Clerical Work
. Toronto and Buffalo:
University of Toronto Press, 1987. Luxemburg, R.
The Mass Strike
. In
Rosa Luxemburg Speaks
, ed. M-A. Waters. New York: Pathfinder
imperativeness, 1970 .
448 Luxemburg, R.
The Russian Revolution
. In
Rosa Luxemburg Speaks
, ed. M-A. Waters. New York:
Pathfinder Press, 1970. MacDowell, L. “ The Formation of the canadian Industrial Relations System During World War Two. ” Labour/Le Travailleur
3 (Spring 1977): 175-196.
MacMillan, J.
The Boy from Port Hood: The Autobiogr
aphy of John Francis “Lofty” MacMillan
, with E.
Hyslop and P. McGahan. Frederict
on, NB: New Ireland Press, 1996.
Macpherson, C.B.
The Life and Times of Liberal Democracy
. Oxford, England: Oxford University
press, 1977. Magnusson, W. “ Introduction : The Devel
opment of Canadian Urban Government.” In
City Politics in
Canada
, eds. W. Magnusson and A. Sancton, 3-57. To
ronto: University of Toronto Press, 1983.
Magri, L. “ Problems of the Marxis
t Theory of the Revolutionary Party.”
New Left Review
60 (1970): 97-128.
Marx, K. “ Thesis III. ”
Theses on Feuerbach
(1845), Online at Marxist Internet Archive,
hypertext transfer protocol : //www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1845/ theses/index.htm. Marx, K. to J. von Schweitzer, 13 February 1865. In
The First International and After: Political Writings Vol.
3
, K. Marx, ed. D. Fernbach, 146-148. London: Pelican / New Left Review, 1974.
Marx, K. to L. Kugelmann, 23 February 1865. In
The First International and After: Political Writings Vol. 3
,
K. Marx, erectile dysfunction. D. Fernbach, 148-153. London : Pelican / New Left Review, 1974. Marx, K. to Johann von Schweitzer, 13 October 1868. In
The First International and After: Political Writings
Vol. 3
, K. Marx, ed. D. Fernbach, 153-157. London: Pelican / New Left Review, 1974.
Marx, K. Letter to K. Liebknecht, February
11, 1878. Online at Marxist Internet Archive,
hypertext transfer protocol : //www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/ 1878/letters/ 78_02_11.htm Marx, K. and F. Engels, Circular Letter to Bebel,
Liebknecht, Bracke, et.al., 17-18 September 1879. In
The
First International and After : political Writings Vol. 3
, K. Marx, ed. D. Fernbach, 360-375. London:
Pelican / New Left Review, 1974. McCallum, M. “ Corporate We
lfarism in Canada, 1919-1939.”
Canadian Historical Review
71, no. 1 (1990):
46-77. Michels, R.
Political Parties: A Sociological Study of
the Emergence of Leadership, the Psychology of
world power, and the Oligarchic Tendencies of Organization
. New York: Free Press, 1962.
Mills, C.W.
The New Men of Power: America’s Labor Leaders
. New York: Harcourt Brace, 1948.
Mills, C.W.
White Collar: The American Middle Classes
. New York: Oxford University Press, 1951.
449 Mitchell, T., and J. Naylor. “ The Prairies : In the Eye of the Storm. ” In
The Workers’ Revolt in Canada, 1917-
1925
, ed. C.Heron, 176-230. Toronto: Un
iversity of Toronto Press, 1998.
Moody, K.
An Injury to All: The Decline of American Unionism
. New York: Verso, 1988
Moody, K.
Workers in a Lean World: Unions in the International Economy
. New York: Verso, 1997.
Moore, B.
The Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy
. New York: Penguin, 1966.
Morton, D.
Working People: An Illustrated Hi
story of the Canadian Labour Movement
, rev. ed. Montreal:
McGill-Queen ’ second University Press, 1998. Murray, G. “ Steeling for Change : organization and Or
ganizing in Two USWA Districts in Canada.” In
Organizing to Win : New Research on Union Strategies
, eds. K. Bronfenbrenner, et.al., 320-338.
Ithaca, NY / London : Cornell University Press, 1998. Muste, A.J. “ Army and Town Meeting. ” In
Unions, Management and the Public
, eds. E. Wight Bakke and
C. Kerr, 187-192. New York : Harcourt Brace and Co., 1948. Naylor, J. “ southerly Ontario : strike at the Ballot Box. ” In
The Workers’ Revolt in Canada, 1917-1925
, ed.
C.Heron, 144-175. Toronto : University of Toronto, 1998. Naylor, J.
The New Democracy: Challenging the Social
Order in Industrial Ontario, 1914-1925.
Toronto:
University of Toronto Press, 1991. Naylor, J. “ Toronto 1919. ” Canadian Historical Association
Historical Papers
, 1986: 33-55.
Nelles, H.V.
The Politics of Development: Forests, Mines and Hydro-electric Power in Ontario, 1849-1941.
Toronto : Macmillian Press,1974. Nelles, H.V. and C. Armstrong. “ The
Great Fight for Clean Government.”
Urban History Review
2 (October
1976 ) : 50-66. Nissen, B. “ alternative Strategic Directions fo
r the U.S. Labor Movement: Recent Scholarship.”
Labor
Studies Journal
28, no. 1 (Spring 2003): 133-155.
Palladino, G.
Dreams of Dignity, Workers of Vision: a History of the International Brotherhood of Electrical
Workers
. Washington, D.C: International Br
otherhood of Electrical Workers, 1991.
Palmer, B.
Working-Class Experience: Rethinking the History of Canadian Labour, 1800-1991.
Toronto:
McLelland and Stewart, 1992. Panitch, L.
Working Class Politics in Crisis: Essays on Labour and the State
. London: Verso, 1986.
Panitch, L. “ Elites, Classes, and Power in Canada. ” In
Canadian Politics in the 1990s
, eds. M. Whittington
450 and G. Williams, 182-207. Toronto : Nelson Canada,1990. Pateman, C.
Participation and Democratic Theory
. London: Cambridge University Press, 1970.
Pearlin, L., and H. Richards. “ fairness : A Study of Union Democracy. ” In
Labor and Trade Unionism: An
interdisciplinary Reader
, eds. W.Galenson and S.M Lipset, 265-281. New York: John Wiley and
Sons, 1960. Pentland, H.
Labour and Capital in Canada, 1650-1860.
Toronto : James Lorimer & Co., 1981. Perlman, S.
A Theory of the Labour Movement
. New York: Augustus M. Kelley Inc.,1950.
Piven, F.F. and R. Cloward.
Poor People’s Movements: How They Succeed, Why They Fail
. New York : vintage, 1979. Plewman, W.R.
Adam Beck and the Ontario Hydro
. Toronto: Ryerson University Press, 1947.
Pringle, J.
United We Stand: A History of Winnipeg’s Civic Workers
. Winnipeg: Manitoba Labour
department of education Centre, 1991. Robinson, I. “ Economistic unionism in crisis : The
Origins, Consequences, and Prospects of Divergence in
Labour-Movement Characteristics. ” In
The Challenge of Restructuring: North American Labor
Movements Respond
, eds. J. Jenson and R. Mahon, 19-47. Philadelphia: Temple U P, 1993.
Ross, G. and J. Jenson. “ Post-War Class St
ruggle and the Crisis of Left Politics.” In
Socialist Register
1985/86 : Social Democracy and After,
eds. R. Miliband et.al., 23-49. London, Merlin, 1986.
Rowett, J. “ Labour Movement. ” In
The Blackwell Encyclopedia of Political Science
, ed. V. Bogdanor, 315-
16. London : Blackwell, 1991. Rouillard, J.
Histoire du syndicalism au Quebec: des origines à nos jours
. Montreal: Boréal, 1989.
Sassoon, A.S.
Gramsci’s Politics
, 2
nd
ed. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1987.
Seidman, J.
Union Rights and Union Duties
. New York: Harcourt Brace and Co., 1943.
Smith, G. “ Iron Law of Oligarchy. ” In
The Blackwell Encyclopaedia of Political Science
, ed. V. Bogdanor,
298-9. London : Blackwell, 1991. 298-9. Stepan-Norris, J. “ The Making of Union Democracy. ”
Social Forces
76, no.2 (1997): 475-510.
Stepan-Norris, J. and M. Zeitlin. “ Union Democracy,
Radical Leadership, and the Hegemony of Capital.”
sociological Review
60 (1995): 829–850.
Storey, R. “ Unionization Versus Corporate wellbeing : The Dofasco Way. ”
Labour/Le Travailleur
12 (Fall
451 1983 ) : 8-42. Struthers, J.
No Fault of Their Own: Unemploym
ent and the Canadian Welfare State, 1914-1941.
Toronto:
University of Toronto Press, 1983. Swartz, D. “ Democracy in canadian Unions. ” C
onference paper. Presented 2 September 1990 at the
democracy in the Workplace
conference, Centre for Research on Work and Society, York
University, Toronto. Swartz, D. “ United We Fall : Solidar
ity v. Democracy in Canadian Unions.”
Our Times
11, no. 4 / 5
( September 1992 ) : 37-41. taft, P.
The Structure and Government of Labor Unions
. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press,
1962. Therborn, G.
Science, Class, and Society: On the Format
ion of Sociology and Historical Materialism
.
London : Verso, 1976. Thomas, E.
The Crest of the Mountain: The Ri
se of CUPE Local Five in Hamilton
. Hamilton: CUPE Local
5, n.d. Thompson, E.P.
The Making of the English Working Class
. London: Penguin, 1963.
Trotsky, L. “ Marxism and Trade Unionism. ” In
Trade Unions Under Capitalism
, eds. T. Clarke and L.
Clements, 77-92. London : Fontana Collins, 1977. Tufts, S. “ Community Unionism in
Canada and Labor’s (Re)Organization of Space.”
Antipode
30, no. 3
( 1998 ) : 227-250. Wainwright, H.
Arguments for a New Left: Answering the Free Market Right
. oxford : Blackwell, 1994. Weaver, J.C.
Shaping the Canadian City: Essays on Urban Politics and Policy, 1890-1920.
Ottawa:
Institute of Public Administration of Canada, 1977. Weaver, J.C. “ The Modern City Realized : Toronto Civic Affairs, 1880-1915. ” In
The Usable Urban Past:
Planning and Politics in the Modern Canadian City
, eds. A. Artibise and G. Stelter, 39-72. Toronto /
ottawa : Macmillan / Institute of Canadian Studies, Carleton University, 1979. Weir, S. “ The Conflict in American Unions and the Resi
stance to Alternative Ideas from the Rank and File.”
In
Workers’ Struggles, Past, Present: A ‘Radical America’ Reader
, ed. J.Green. Philadelphia:
Temple University Press, 1983. Wells, D. “ The Origins of Canada ’ s Wagner Model of
Industrial Relations: The United Auto Workers in
Canada and the suppression of Rank and File Unionism, 1936-1953. ”
Canadian Journal of
Sociology
20, no. 2 (1995): 192-224.
452 White, J.
Hospital Strike: Women, Unions, and Public Sector Conflict
. Toronto: Thompson Educational
publication, 1990. Wichern, P.H. “ diachronic Influences on Cont
emporary Local Politics: The Case of Winnipeg.”
Urban
History Review
12, no. 1 (June 1983): 39-43.
Williams, J.
The Story of Unions in Canada
. Toronto: J.M. Dent and Sons, Ltd., 1975.
Yates, C. “ Unity and Diversity : Challenges
to an Expanding Canadian Autoworkers’ Union.”
Canadian
Review of Sociology and Anthropology
35, no.1 (February 1998): 93-118.
Zeitlin, J. “ ‘ Rank and Filism ’ in Br
itish Labour History: A Critique.”
International Review of Social History
34
( 1989 ) : 42-61. Zeitlin, M., and J. Stepan-Norris. “ The In
surgent Origins of Democracy.” in
Reexamining Democracy:
Read more: Ex on the Beach (British series 6)
Essays in Honor of S.M. Lipset
, eds. G.Marks and L. Diamond, 250-273. London: Sage, 1992.